Title: Part A-III (continued) Microeconomic Theory Review (continued)
1Part A-III (continued) Microeconomic Theory
Review (continued)
2Economics One-on-Onecontinued
- Cooperation/Non-cooperation
- Bargaining Theory
- Transaction Costs
3- Co-operation/Non-cooperation
- We saw that the outcome of a game of strategy can
be very different if the players cooperate or
dont cooperate. - Recall Mary and John
- PAYOFF MATRIX
- Marys decision
- SELL DONT SELL
- Johns decision
- SELL (-2, -2) ( 1, 0)
- DONT SELL ( 0, 1) ( 0, 0)
4- We saw that if Mary and John decide to
co-operative they can each do better (and society
as whole will be better off in the sense that a
Pareto Improvement will result - market failures
sometimes we dont want them to co-operate??) - This simple game represents a very common
situation. So why dont agents always cooperate? - They often do but they sometimes dont
- We are very interested in why cooperation might
not occur and whether or not POLICY can foster
more cooperation among agents
5Recall, if Mary and John decide that one of them
will sell and one will not sell, together they
will make 1 in profit. BUT, they must also
decide how to split the profit (0.01/0.99 or
0.99/0.01 or 0.50/0.50 or whatever). Sounds
simple enough but it generally isnt.
- PAYOFF MATRIX
- Marys decision
-
- SELL DONT SELL
- Johns decision
- SELL (-2, -2) ( 1, 0)
-
- DONT SELL ( 0, 1) ( 0, 0)
6- Remember Mary does not know Johns profit
function (his payoffs under the various
strategies) and John does not know Marys
payoffs. - Maybe a 50/50 split is fair but maybe not.
- What if John tells Mary that even if she sells he
can still make a profit of 0.50 so if she wants
him to cooperate she must give him 0.75 and
accept only 0.25 for herself?
7Or what if John is a slightly more profitable
firm. Now the optimal cooperative outcome is for
John to sell and Mary to not sell. (Note that
the non-cooperative solution remains (0,
0)) Together they will make 1.50 in profit.
Why should John agree to a 50/50 split? But why
should Mary reveal that she only stands to make
1.00 profit? She could tell John that if he
sits idle and she sells she could make 1.45.
- PAYOFF MATRIX
- Marys decision
-
- SELL DONT SELL
- Johns decision
- SELL (-2, -2) ( 1.50, 0)
-
- DONT SELL ( 0, 1) ( 0, 0)
8The primary reason why players find it difficult
to cooperate is that each has a different
information set
- Mary knows
- Marys decision
- SELL DONT SELL
- Johns decision
- SELL (?, -2) (?, 0)
- DONT SELL (?, 1) (?, 0)
- John knows
- Marys decision
- SELL DONT SELL
- Johns decision
- SELL (-2, ?) (1, ?)
- DONT SELL ( 1, ?) (0, ?)
9Think of union/employer, investor/firm,
buyer/seller
- The first step towards cooperation is sharing
information, for example - Trade association generally questionable
motives - Union representation on company boards
- Russian military observers at NATO exercises
-
10Bargaining Theory
- We need a framework (theory) which will allow us
to understand the structure of the process
through which agents negotiate a cooperative
solution. The process itself is somewhat
mysterious. - Elements of Bargaining theory
- Cooperative surplus (whats at stake)
- Reservation prices of each agent
11An example
- Jones has a cottage for sale. She values it at
100,000. She offers it for sale. - Smith has 200,000. He decides that he is
interested in buying the Jones cottage. Smith
decides that it is worth 110,000 to him. - What will happen? Will a sale go through? What
will the price be?
12We know
- the cottage is worth 10,000 more to Smith than
it is to Jones - the lowest price acceptable to the potential
seller, Jones, is 100,000. - the highest price acceptable to the potential
buyer is 110,000. - the problem is that they must agree on a price,
and this agreement determines who gets what share
of the increased well-being that results from the
sale (the gains from the Pareto improving trade
of cottage for money).
13- Cooperative Surplus - difference between the
maximum buying price and the minimum selling
price - the value created by reallocating
resources between the agents (10,000 in our
example) - Reservation Price of the Buyer - the price above
which the buyer will not buy (110,000 in our
example) the walk-away price for the buyer - Reservation Price of the Seller the price below
which the seller will not sell (100,000 in our
example) the walk-away price for the seller - Reservation Prices are also known as Threat Values
14- The transaction price the price at which the
trade takes place - The transaction price determines the share of the
cooperative surplus that each party will get - If the agreed price is 105,000, then each will
share equally (5,000) in the cooperative surplus
- If the agreed price is 102,000, then Jones gets
20 (2,000/10,000) of the surplus and Smith
gets 80 (8,000/10,000)
15Purpose of bargaining
- To allow the seller to try to determine the
buyers true reservation price, while trying to
convince the buyer that her reservation price is
quite high. - To allow the buyer to try to determine the
sellers true reservation price while trying to
convince the seller that he has a very low
reservation price. - The process of bargaining is intended to help
each side develop a notion of the other sides
reservation price. At the start, the buyer
and/or seller might not even know if a trade is
possible. The cooperative surplus might be zero.
16- Information revealed in the course of bargaining
must be viewed as credible by the other side - - prices of other cottages in the area
- - the physical state of the cottage
- - the fact that the buyers spouse would rather
move to Florida - - the fact that the buyer is having trouble
arranging a mortgage - - the fact that the cottage represents a lifetime
of memories to the seller and she is having
second thoughts about selling - - etc., etc.
17- Bargaining makes it a cooperative game, as
opposed to a non-cooperative game - No guarantee that the bargainers will be able to
agree on a price (a sharing of the surplus). - Negotiations might break down and no trade
result. - (The Pareto improving transaction might not take
place.) - Negotiations might be impossible
18- Returning to Jones and Smith and the cottage
- Lets look at some possible outcomes and see how
far bargaining theory can actually get us. - Can we predict the selling price of the cottage?
- Cab we predict that a trade will take place?
19 Jones dominates the bargaining process
- Player Non-cooperative Cooperative Cooperative
- solution solution surplus
- payoff payoff (Threat Values) (Jones
dominates) - Jones 100,000 cottage 109,999 money 9,999
- Smith 110,000 money 110,000 cottage
- for cottage
- 90,000 money 90,001 money 1
- Total
- wellbeing
- in society 300,000 310,000 10,000
20 Smith dominates the bargaining process
- Player Non-cooperative Cooperative Cooperative
- solution solution surplus
- payoff payoff (Threat Values) (Smith
dominates) - Jones 100,000 cottage 100,001 money 1
- Smith 110,000 money 110,000 cottage
- for cottage
- 90,000 money 99,999 money 9,999
- Total
- wellbeing
- in society 300,000 310,000 10,000
21Reasonable Solution bargaining outcome 50/50
split warning this is a purely theoretical
concept
- Player Non-cooperative Cooperative Cooperative
- solution solution surplus
- payoff payoff (Threat Values) (Jones
dominates) - Jones 100,000 cottage 105,000 money 5,000
- Smith 110,000 money 110,000 cottage
- for cottage
- 90,000 money 95,000 money 5,000
- Total
- wellbeing
- in society 300,000 310,000 10,000
22- If a cooperative solution results (they agree on
a price and a voluntary trade takes place) the
total value of the cooperative solution will
always be 310,000 - Bargaining is simply a process to determine if a
cooperative solution is possible and who will get
what share of the surplus - If bargaining is successful (a trade is made)
then an efficient Pareto improving trade occurs
- - who gets what is a matter of distribution of
wellbeing
23This bargaining game can tell us the value of the
cooperative surplus - it cannot tell us how the
surplus will actually be divided between the two
parties, or even if a trade will actually
occur. Rational self-interested behaviour on
the part of each agent is not enough to determine
what the price might end up being in such a model
Often we cannot even predict whether or not
bargaining will be successful
24When we face such situations in economic
modelling. We generally assume that a
reasonable as opposed to a rational price
results if bargaining is successful. The
reasonable solution will be the one for which
the buyer and seller divide the surplus evenly.
Economic theory provides no basis for assuming
that the reasonable distribution rule will
actually apply. The reasonable solution has
nothing to do with fairness (or rationality). It
is just a convenient assumption.
25Some variations on the cottage sale
- QUESTION Suppose Jones neighbour offers an
identical cottage for sale at a price of
103,000, while Jones is still bargaining with
Smith. How would this change the threat values,
the surplus from cooperation and the reasonable
solution? - ANSWER
- Jones threat value remains 100,000
- Smiths threat value falls to 103,000 since he
now has an alternative offer of sale at that
price - Cooperative surplus (from a trade taking place
between Jones and Smith) now falls to 3,000,
since 103,000 is the most the Jones cottage is
worth to Smith - Reasonable solution is now a price of 101,500.
26Interpretation
- Parts of this response might appear
counter-intuitive. - We started with Smith valuing a cottage such as
that offered for sale by Jones at 110,000. - Presumably he still values such a cottage it at
110,000. - But Jones neighbour offered such a cottage for
sale at 103,000 and thereby established a
maximum price that Smith would be required to pay
Jones. - The action of Jones neighbour granted Smith
7,000 in guaranteed consumers surplus,
something he no longer has to bargain over or
share with anyone. - What remains for him is to bargain (with either
Jones or her neighbour) over the remaining 3,000
which represents the new lower cooperative
surplus although we do not know the neighbours
reservation price.
27- QUESTION Suppose Jones neighbour does not
offer his cottage for sale but Jones receives an
offer to purchase at a price of 105,000 from
Wilson, while still negotiating with Smith. How
would this change the threat values, the surplus
from cooperation and the reasonable solution? -
- QUESTION Suppose that Smith begins to feel that
purchasing a mobile home might also be enjoyable
and as a result, lowers his valuation of the
cottage to 95,000. Jones still believes that
the cottage is worth a minimum of 100,000. How
would this change the threat values, the surplus
from cooperation and the reasonable solution? - QUESTION What if the government imposes a 10
buyers fee on all cottage purchase? How would
this change the original threat values, the
surplus from cooperation and the reasonable
solution? (Land Transfer Tax)
28Bargaining model - summary
- The bargaining model reduces the bargaining
process to three basic elements - 1 The threat values (reservation prices) of the
buyer and seller. - 2 The cooperative surplus.
- 3 Agreement on terms for distributing the
surplus between the agents. - But why does actual bargaining sometimes fail?
- Transaction Costs
29Transaction Costs
- Is bargaining free (does it have zero costs)?
- No, in the simplest setting the agents must take
the time to meet and haggle. - In more complicated settings, they might need to
spend time carefully assessing each others
threat value (hire accountants, engineers, etc.)
hire bargaining agents (lawyers), etc. - Bargaining can at times be very costly. These
costs are referred to as transaction costs
30- Transaction costs are the costs of carrying out
trade the resources required to bring about
Pareto improving voluntary exchange. - In well organized markets, these costs can be
very low e.g. trading securities on the
internet. - At times they can be high relative to the value
of what is being trade fine art and collectible
auctions 30 or more. - Sales and other trading taxes are also part of
transaction costs.
31- Whatever they are, transaction costs cut into
(detract from) the cooperative surplus. - Consider Jones and Smith, if there is a 15 land
transfer tax on the sale of cottages can a
trade go through under any conditions? - Individuals trade net of transactions costs and
the general rule is - The greater are the transaction costs
- the less trading will occur.
- (transaction costs are not a gain to either the
buyer of seller) - We need to understand the nature of transaction
costs
32The elements of transaction costs
- Three components of transaction costs
- 1 search costs
- 2 bargaining costs
- 3 enforcement costs
33- Search costs
- Costs associated with locating a buyer or seller.
- These costs tend to be relatively high when
trading in unique goods or services (a spare part
for an vintage automobile) and low for
standardized goods (most consumer goods).
34- Bargaining costs
- Costs associated with carrying out the
negotiations. - If each partys threat value and the cooperative
surplus is known to all parties then bargaining
costs will be relatively low. - In general the more information concerning all
aspects of the trade that is public to the
parties, the easier it will be to reach a bargain
- otherwise the bargaining process will have to
make that information known. - Bargaining will be more difficult (more costly)
the greater is the number of parties the greater
is the amount of primary uncertainty associated
with the transaction (requiring agreement on
contingencies) the greater is the extent of
hostility between the bargainers the extent to
which there is overreaching, on the part of one
or both parties.
35- Enforcement costs
- Costs associated with monitoring the behaviour of
the parties and punishing failure to fulfil
agreements. - If there is no time lag between the bargain being
reached and being fulfilled, then there will be
no enforcement costs. - If there is a lapse of time between bargaining
and fulfilment of the bargain conditions, then
monitoring and enforcement costs will arise. - Note that many apparently instantaneous
transactions carry warranties or guarantees of
one sort or another and therefore monitoring and
enforcement costs exist.
36- Consider the purchase of illicit drugs versus
alcohol - All three components of transaction costs are
likely to be higher for illicit drugs search
costs, bargaining costs and enforcement costs. - This results mostly from the fact that
recreational drugs are illegal. - Would legalizing the sale of recreational drugs
increase their use? It would certainly make the
transaction costs fall, implying more successful
bargaining.
37To summarize
- At times the cooperative solution to a potential
conflict of interest will yield a Pareto
improvement over the non cooperative solution
there is a cooperative surplus, or gain from
trade) - However, the agents must cooperate successfully
agree to bargain and eventually come to some
agreement on the division of gains - Since neither agent generally has perfect
information this bargaining is costly (the
information must be developed) - This gives rise to transaction costs
- Bargaining will breakdown (fail) if the
transaction costs exceed the cooperative surplus
- We are interested in situations in which the law
can facilitate successful cooperation.