ANALYZING THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

ANALYZING THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE

Description:

William H. Riker, 'The First Power Index.' Social Choice and Welfare, 1986. ... 1888 233 [Harrison (R)] 168 [Cleveland (D)] 49.59% 1876 185 [Hayes (R)] 184 ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:141
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 107
Provided by: nmil9
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: ANALYZING THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE


1
ANALYZING THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE
  • Nicholas R. Miller
  • Political Science, UMBC
  • INFORMS Meeting
  • October 14, 2008
  • http//userpages.umbc.edu/nmiller/ELECTCOLLEGE.ht
    ml

2
Preface
  • Polsbys Law Whats bad for the political system
    is good for political science, and vice versa.
  • George C. Edwards, WHY THE ELECTORAL COLLEGE IS
    BAD FOR AMERICA (Yale, 2004)
  • Deduction The Electoral College is good for
    Political Science.

3
Problematic Features of the Electoral College
  • The Voting Power Problem. Does the Electoral
    College system (as it presently operates) give
    voters in different states unequal voting power?
  • If so, voters in which states are favored and
    which disfavored and by how much?
  • The Election Reversal Problem. The candidate who
    wins the most popular votes nationwide may fail
    to be elected.
  • The election 2000 provides an example (provided
    we take the official popular vote in FL at face
    value).
  • The Electoral College Deadlock Problem, i.e., the
    House contingent procedure.
  • Here I present some analytic results pertaining
    to the first and second problems of the existing
    Electoral College as well as variants of the EC.

4
The Voting Power Problem
  • As a first step, we need to distinguish between
  • voting weight and
  • voting power.
  • We also need to distinguish between two distinct
    issues
  • how electoral votes are apportioned among the
    states (which determines voting weight), and
  • how electoral votes are cast within states
    (which, in conjunction with the apportionment of
    voting weight, determines voting power).

5
The Apportionment of Electoral Votes
  • The apportionment of electoral votes is fixed in
    the Constitution,
  • except that Congress can by law change the size
    of the House of Representatives, and Congress can
    therefore also change
  • the number of electoral votes, and
  • the ratio
  • Senatorial electoral votes
  • Total electoral votes
  • which reflects the magnitude of the small-state
    advantage in apportionment.

6
Chart 1. The Small-State EV Apportionment
Advantage
7
The Casting of Electoral Votes
  • How electoral votes are cast within states is
    determined by state law.
  • But, with few exceptions, since about 1836 states
    have cast their electoral votes on a
    winner-take-all basis.
  • By standard voting power calculations,
  • the winner-take-all practice produces a
    large-state advantage
  • that more than balances out the small-state
    advantage in electoral vote apportionment.

8
A Priori Voting Power
  • A measure of a priori voting power is a measure
    that
  • takes account of the structure of the voting
    rules
  • but of nothing else (e.g., demographics, historic
    voting patterns, ideology, poll results, etc.).
  • The standard measure of a priori voting power is
    the Absolute Banzhaf (or Penrose) Measure.
  • Dan Felsenthal and Moshe Machover, The Measure of
    Voting Power Theory and Practice, Problems and
    Paradoxes, 1998
  • A voters absolute Banzhaf voting power is
  • the probability that the voters vote is decisive
    (i.e., determines the outcome the election),
  • given that all other voters vote by independently
    flipping fair coins (i.e., given a Bernoulli
    probability space producing a Bernoulli election).

9
A Priori Individual Voting Power
  • In a simple one person, one vote majority rule
    election with n voters,
  • the a priori voting power of an individual voter
    is the probability that his vote is decisive,
    i.e.,
  • the probability that the vote is otherwise tied
    (if n is odd), or
  • one half the probability the vote is otherwise
    within one vote of a tie (if n is even).
  • Provided n is larger than about 25, this
    probability is very well approximated by v (2 /
    pn),
  • Which implies that that individual voting power
    is inversely proportional to the square root of
    the number of voters.

10
Calculating Power Index Values
  • There are other mathematical formulas and
    algorithms that for calculating or approximating
    voting power in weighted voting games, i.e.,
  • in which voters cast (unequal) blocs of votes.
  • Various website make these algorithms readily
    available.
  • One of the best of these is the website created
    by Dennis Leech (University of Warwick and
    another VPP Board member) Computer Algorithms
    for Voting Power Analysis,
  • http//www.warwick.ac.uk/ecaae/Progam_L
    ist
  • which was used in making most of the
    calculations that follow.

11
A Priori State Voting Power in the Electoral
College (with Winner-Take-All)
  • A states a priori voting power is
  • the probability that the states block of
    electoral votes is decisive (i.e., determines the
    outcome the election),
  • given that all other states cast their blocs of
    electoral votes by independently flipping fair
    coins.
  • For example (using Leechs website), the a priori
    voting power of CA (with 55 EV out of 583) .475
    .
  • This means if every other states vote is
    determined by a flip of a coin,
  • 52.5 of the time one or other candidate will
    have at least 270 electoral votes before CA casts
    its 55 votes, but
  • 47.5 of the time CAs 55 votes will determine
    the outcome.

12
Chart 2. Share of Voting Power by Share of
Electoral Votes
13
Chart 3. Share of Voting Power by Share of
Population
14
Individual Voting Power in the Electoral College
System
  • The a priori voting power of an individual voter
    in the Electoral College system (as it works in
    practice) is
  • the probability that the
    individual voter is
    decisive in his state
  • multiplied by
  • the probability that the bloc of votes cast
    by the voters
  • state is decisive in the Electoral
    College
  • or
    equivalently
  • individual voting power in
    the state
  • multiplied
    by
  • state voting power in the Electoral
    College

15
The Banzhaf Effect
  • (1) Individual voting power within each state is
    (almost exactly) inversely proportional to the
    square root to the number of voters in the state.
  • (2) As shown in Chart 2, state voting power in
    the Electoral College is approximately
    proportional to its voting weight (number of
    electoral votes).
  • (3) As shown in Chart 1, the voting weight of
    states in turn is approximately (apart from the
    small-state apportionment advantage) proportional
    to population (and number voters).
  • (4) As shown in Chart 3, putting together (2)
    and (3), state voting power is approximately
    proportional to population.
  • (5) So putting together (1) and (4), individual
    a priori voting power is approximately
    proportional to the square root of the number of
    voters in a state.
  • However this large-state advantage is
    counterbalanced in some degree by the small-state
    apportionment advantage, as shown in the Chart 4.

16
Banzhaf Effect in Bernoulli Elections
17
Individual Voting Power Under the Existing EC
  • The following Chart 4 shows how a priori
    individual voting power under the existing
    Electoral College varies by state population.
  • It also shows
  • mean individual voting power nationwide, and
  • individual voting power under direct popular vote
    (calculated in the same manner as individual
    voting power within a state).
  • Note that it is substantially greater than mean
    individual voting power under the Electoral
    College.
  • Indeed, it is greater than individual voting
    power in every state except California.
  • By the criterion of a priori voting power, only
    voters in California would be hurt if the
    existing Electoral College were replaced by a
    direct popular vote.
  • Methodological note in most of the following
    charts, individual voting power is scaled so that
    the voters in the least favored state have a
    value of 1.000, so
  • numerical values are not comparable from chart to
    chart, and
  • the scaled value of individual voting power under
    direct popular vote changes from chart to chart.
  • The number of voters in each state is
    assumed to be a constant fraction (.4337) of
    state population.

18
Individual Voting Power By State Population
Existing Electoral College
19
The Interpretation of a Priori Voting Power
  • Remember that Chart 4 displays individual a
    priori voting power in states with different
    populations,
  • which takes account of the Electoral College
    voting rules but nothing else.
  • A priori, a voter in California has about three
    times the probability of casting a decisive vote
    than one in New Hampshire.
  • But if we take account of recent voting patterns,
    current poll results, and other information, a
    voter in New Hampshire may have a greater
    empirical (or a posteriori) probability of
    decisiveness in the upcoming election, and
    accordingly get more attention from the
    candidates and party organizations, than one in
    California.
  • But if California and New Hampshire had equal
    battleground status, the Californias a priori
    advantage would be reflected in its a posteriori
    voting power as well.

20
Winners Margin by State Size
21
Interpretation of A Priori Voting Power (cont.)
  • If it is only weakly related to empirical voting
    power in any particular election, the question
    arises of whether a priori voting power and the
    Banzhaf effect should be of concern to political
    science and practice.
  • Constitution-makers arguably should and to some
    extent must design political institutions from
    behind a veil of ignorance concerning future
    political trends.
  • Accordingly they should and to some extent must
    be concerned with how the institutions they are
    designing allocate a priori, rather than
    empirical, voting power.
  • The framers of the U.S. Constitution did not
    require or expect electoral votes to be cast en
    bloc by states.
  • However, at least one delegate Luther Martin
    expected that state delegations in the House of
    Representatives would vote en bloc, which he
    thought would give large states a Banzhaf-like
    advantage.
  • William H. Riker, The First Power Index. Social
    Choice and Welfare, 1986.

22
Alternative EV Apportionment Rules
  • Keep the winner-take all practice in 2000, Bush
    271, Gore 267 in 2004, Bush 286, Kerry, 252 but
    use a different formula for apportioning
    electoral votes among states.
  • Apportion electoral votes in whole numbers on
    basis of population only House electoral votes
    only Bush 211, Gore 225 Bush 224, Kerry 212
  • Apportion electoral votes fractionally to be
    precisely proportional to population Bush
    268.96092, Gore 269.03908 Bush 275.67188, Kerry
    262.32812
  • Apportion electoral votes fractionally to be
    precisely proportional to population but then add
    back the constant two Bush 277.968, Gore
    260.032 Bush 285.40695, Kerry 252.59305
  • Apportion electoral votes equally among the
    states in the manner of the House contingent
    procedure Bush 30, Gore 21 Bush 31, Kerry 20

23
Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationHouse Electoral Votes Only
24
Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Precisely
Proportional to Population
25
Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Proportional
Population, plus Two
26
Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Apportioned Equally
Among States
27
Can Electoral Votes Be Apportioned So As To
Equalize Individual Voting Power?
  • The question arises of whether electoral votes
    can be apportioned so that (even while retaining
    the winner-take-all practice) the voting power of
    individuals is equalized across states?
  • One obvious (but constitutionally impermissible)
    possibility is to redraw state boundaries so that
    all states have the same number of voters (and
    electoral votes).
  • This creates a system of uniform representation.
  • Methodological Note since the following chart
    compares voting power under different
    apportionments, voting power must be expressed in
    absolute (rather than rescaled) terms.

28
Individual Voting Power when States Have Equal
Population (Versus Apportionment Proportional to
Actual Population)
29
Uniform Representation
  • Note that equalizing state populations not only
  • equalizes individual voting power across states,
    but also
  • raises mean individual voting power, relative to
    that under apportionment based on the actual
    unequal populations.
  • While this pattern appears to be typically true,
    it is not invariably true,
  • e.g., if state populations are uniformly
    distributed over a wide range.
  • However, individual voting power still falls
    below that under direct popular vote.
  • So the fact that mean individual voting power
    under the Electoral College falls below that
    under direct popular vote is
  • not due to the fact that states are unequal in
    population and electoral votes, and
  • is evidently intrinsic to a two-tier system.
  • Van Kolpin, Voting Power Under Uniform
    Representation, Economics Bulletin, 2003.

30
Electoral Vote Apportionment to Equalize
Individual Voting Power (cont.)
  • Given that state boundaries are immutable, can we
    apportion electoral votes so that (without
    changing state populations and with the
    winner-take-all practice preserved) the voting
    power of individuals is equalized across states?
  • Yes, individual voting power can be equalized by
    apportioning electoral votes so that state voting
    power is proportional to the square root of state
    population.
  • But such apportionment is tricky, because what
    must be made proportional to population is
  • not electoral votes (which is what we directly
    apportion) but
  • state voting power (which is a consequence of the
    apportionment of electoral votes).

31
(Almost) Equalized Individual Voting Power
32
Electoral Vote Apportionment to Equalize
Individual Voting Power (cont.)
  • Under such square-root apportionment rules, the
    outcome of the 2004 Presidential election would
    be
  • Fractional Apportionment Bush 307.688, Kerry
    230.312.
  • Whole-Number Apportionment Bush 307, Kerry 231
  • Actual Apportionment Bush 286, Kerry 252
  • Electoral Votes proportional to popular vote
    Bush 275.695, Kerry 262.305
  • Clearly equalizing individual voting power is not
    the same thing as making the electoral vote
    (more) proportional to the popular vote.

33
Alternative Rules for Casting Electoral Votes
  • Apportion electoral votes as at present but use
    something other than winner-take-all for casting
    state electoral votes.
  • (Pure) Proportional Plan electoral votes are
    cast fractionally in precise proportion to
    state popular vote. Bush 259.2868, Gore
    258.3364, Nader 14.8100, Buchanan 2.4563, Other
    3.1105 Bush 277.857, Kerry 260.143
  • Whole Number Proportional Plan e.g., Colorado
    Prop. 36 electoral votes are cast in whole
    numbers on basis of some apportionment formula
    applied to state popular vote. Bush 263, Gore
    269, Nader 6, or Bush 269, Gore 269 Bush 280,
    Kerry 258
  • Pure District Plan electoral votes cast by
    single-vote districts.
  • Modified District Plan two electoral votes cast
    for statewide winner, others by district
    present NE and ME practice. Bush 289, Gore
    249, if CDs are used no data for 2004
  • National Bonus Plan 538 electoral votes are
    apportioned and cast as at present but an
    additional 100 electoral votes are awarded on a
    winner-take-all basis to the national popular
    vote winner. Bush 271, Gore 367 Bush 386,
    Kerry 252

34
Individual Voting Power under Alternative Rules
for Casting Electoral Votes
  • Calculations for the Pure District Plan, Pure
    Proportional Plan, and the Whole-Number
    Proportional Plan are straightforward.
  • Under the Modified District Plan and the National
    Bonus Plan, each voter casts a single vote that
    counts two ways
  • within the district (or state) and
  • at-large (i.e., within the state or nation).
  • Calculating individual voting power in such
    systems is far from straightforward.
  • I am in the process of working out approximations
    based on very large samples of Bernoulli
    elections.

35
Pure District System
36
Modified District System (Approximate)
37
District System Is Out of Equilibrium
  • Given a district system, any state can gain power
    by unilaterally switching to winner-take-all.
  • Madison to Monroe (1800) All agree that an
    election by districts would be best if it could
    be general, but while ten states choose either by
    their legislatures or by a general ticket i.e.,
    winner-take-all, it is folly or worse for the
    other six not to follow.
  • Virginia switched from districts to
    winner-take-all in 1800.
  • If it had not, the Jeffersonian Republicans would
    almost certainly lost the 1800 election.
  • Madisons strategic advice is powerfully
    confirmed in terms of individual voting power,
  • though the voting-power rationale for
    winner-take-all is logically distinct from the
    party-advantage rationale.

38
(No Transcript)
39
Winner-Take-All Is In Equilibrium
  • In the mid-1990s, the Florida state legislature
    seriously considered switching to the Modified
    District Plan.
  • The effect of such a switch on the individual
    voting power is shown in the following chart.
  • However, I assume a switch to the Pure District
    Plan, because this can be directly calculated.
  • Considering mechanical effects only, if Florida
    had made the switch, Gore would have been elected
    President (regardless of the statewide vote in
    Florida).
  • Although small states are penalizing by the
    winner-take-all system, they are further
    penalized if the unilaterally switch to
    districts.
  • So even if a district system is universally
    agreed to be socially superior (as Madison
    considered it to be), states will not voluntary
    choose to move that direction.
  • States are caught in a Prisoners Dilemma.

40
(No Transcript)
41
(Pure) Pure Proportional System
42
Whole-Number Proportional Plan
  • Similar calculations and chart were
    produced, independently and earlier, by Claus
    Beisbart and Luc Bovens, A Power Analysis of the
    Amend-ment 36 in Colorado, University of
    Konstanz, May 2005, and Public Choice, March 2008.

43
National Bonus Plan(s)
44
Individual Voting Power Summary Chart
45
The Probability of Election Reversals
  • Any districted electoral system can produce an
    election reversal.
  • That is, the candidate or party that wins the
    most popular votes nationwide may fail to win the
    most districts (e.g., parliamentary seats or
    electoral votes) and thereby lose the election).
  • Such outcomes are actually more common in some
    parliamentary systems than in U.S. Presidential
    elections.
  • First, lets examine the probability that a
    two-tier Bernoulli election (i.e., given the
    probability model used in voting power
    calculations) results in an election reversal,
    i.e.,
  • that a majority of individuals voters vote
    heads but the winner based on electoral votes
    is tails or vice versa?
  • Based on very large-scale (n 1,000,000)
    simulations, if the number of equally populated
    districts/states is modestly large (e.g., k gt
    20), about 20.5 of such elections produce
    reversals.
  • Feix, Lepelley, Merlin, and Rouet, The
    Probability of Conflicts in a U.S. Presidential
    Type Election, Economic Theory, 2004

46
  • 30,000 Bernoulli elections with 45 districts
    each with 2223 voters (n 100,035)
  • In a more inclusive sample of 120,000 such
    elections, 20.36 were reversals.

47
Probability of Election Reversals (cont.)
  • If the districts are non-uniform (as in the
    Electoral College), the probability of an
    election reversal is evidently slightly greater.
  • Simulations of 32,000 Bernoulli elections for
    each of three EC variants

48
The Election Reversal Problem
  • The U.S. Electoral College has produced three
    manifest election reversals (though all were very
    close),
  • plus one massive election reversal that is not
    usually recognized as such.
  • Election Winner Runner-up
    Winners 2-P PV
  • 2000 271 Bush (R) 267 Gore
    (D) 49.73
  • 1888 233 Harrison (R) 168
    Cleveland (D) 49.59
  • 1876 185 Hayes (R) 184 Tilden
    (D) 48.47
  • The 1876 election was decided (on inauguration
    eve) by a Electoral Commission that, by a bare
    majority and on a straight party line vote,
    awarded all of 20 disputed electoral votes to
    Hayes.
  • Unlike Gore and Cleveland, Tilden won an absolute
    majority (51) of the total popular vote.

49
The 1860 Election
  • Candidate Party Pop. Vote EV
  • Lincoln Republican 39.82 180
  • Douglas Northern Democrat 29.46 12
  • Breckinridge Southern Democrat 18.09 72
  • Bell Constitutional Union 12.61 39
  • Total Democratic Popular Vote 47.55
  • Total anti-Lincoln Popular Vote 60.16
  • Two inconsequential reversals (between Douglas
    and Breckinridge and between Douglas and Bell)
    are manifest.
  • It may appear that Douglas and Breckinridge were
    spoilers against each other.
  • Under a direct popular vote system, this would
    have been true.
  • But under the Electoral College system, Douglas
    and Breckinridge were not spoilers against each
    other.

50
A Counterfactual 1860 Election
  • Suppose the Democrats could have held their
    Northern and Southern wings together and won all
    the votes captured by each wing separately.
  • Suppose further that it had been a Democratic vs.
    Republican straight fight and that the Democrats
    had also won all the votes that went to
    Constitutional Union party.
  • And, for good measure, suppose that the Democrats
    had won all NJ electoral votes (which for
    peculiar reasons were actually split between
    Lincoln and Douglas).
  • Here is the outcome of the counterfactual 1860
    election
  • Party Pop. Vote EV
  • Republican 39.82 169
  • Democratic 60.16 134

51
An Empirical Approach to the Analysis of Election
Reversals
  • In the 1988, the Democratic ticket of Dukakis
    and Bentsen received 46.10 of the two-party
    national popular vote and won 112 electoral votes
    (though one of these was lost to a faithless
    elector).

52
Uniform Swing Analysis
  • Of all the states that Dukakis carried, he
    carried Washington (10 EV) by the smallest margin
    of 50.81.
  • If the Dukakis popular vote of 46.10 were
    (hypothetically) to decline by 0.81 uniformly
    across all states (to 45.29), WA would tip out
    of his column (reducing his EV to 102).
  • Of all the states that Dukakis failed carry, he
    came closest to carrying Illinois (24 EV) with
    48.95.
  • If the Dukakis popular vote of 46.10 were
    (hypothetically) to increase by 1.05 uniformly
    across all states (to 47.15), IL would tip into
    his column (increasing his EV to 136).

53
The PVEV Step Function for 1988
54
Zoom In on the Reversal Interval
55
2000 vs. 1988
  • The key difference between the 2000 and 1988 (or
    2004 and other recent) elections is that 2000 was
    much closer.
  • The election reversal interval was (in absolute
    terms) hardly larger in 2000 than in 1988
  • DPV 50.00 to 50.08 in 1988
  • DPV 50.00 to 50.27 in 2000
  • But the actual DPV was 50.267, i.e., (just)
    within the reversal interval.

56
The PVEV Step Function for 2000
57
The 2000 Reversal Interval
58
Magnitude and Direction of Election Reversal
Intervals
59
Distribution of Reversal Intervals
60
Distribution of Reversal Intervals1952-2004
61
Distribution of Reversal IntervalsAll Scenarios
62
Two Distinct Sources of Possible Election
Reversals
  • The PVEV step-function defines a particular
    electoral landscape, i.e., an interval scale on
    which all states are placed with respect to the
    relative partisan composition of their
    electorates,
  • for example, in 1988 WA was 1.86 more Democratic
    than Illinois.
  • The PVEV visualization makes it evident that
    there are two distinct ways in which election
    reversals may occur.

63
First Source of Possible Election Reversals
  • The first source of possible election reversals
    is invariably present.
  • An election reversal may occur as a result of the
    (non-systematic) rounding error (so to speak)
    necessarily entailed by the fact that the PVEV
    function moves up in discrete steps.
  • In any event, a given electoral landscape allows
    (in a sufficiently close election) a wrong
    winner of one party only.
  • But small perturbations of such a landscape allow
    a wrong winner of the other party.
  • The 1988 chart (and similar charts for all recent
    elections including 2000) provide a clear
    illustration of election reversals due to
    rounding error only.
  • So if the election had been much closer (in
    popular votes) and the electoral landscape
    slightly perturbed, Dukakis might have been a
    wrong winner instead of Bush.

64
(No Transcript)
65
(No Transcript)
66
A Sample of 32,000 Simulated Elections Based on
Perturbations of 2004 Electoral Landscape
67
Estimated (Symmetric) Probability of Election
Reversals By Popular Vote (Based on 2004
Landscape)
68
Estimated (Symmetric) Probability of Electoral
Vote Tie By Popular Vote (Based on 2004
Landscape)
69
Another Sample of 32,000 Simulated Elections
Based on Perturbations of 2004 Electoral
Landscape
70
Second Source of Possible Election Reversals
  • Second, an election reversal may occur as result
    of (systematic) asymmetry or bias in the general
    character of the PVEV function.
  • In this event, small perturbations of the
    electoral landscape will not change the partisan
    identity of potential wrong winners.
  • In times past (e.g., in the New Deal era and
    earlier), there was a clear asymmetry in the PVEV
    function that resulted largely from the electoral
    peculiarities of the old Solid South, in
    particular,
  • its overwhelmingly Democratic popular vote
    percentages, combined with
  • its strikingly low voting turnout.

71
(No Transcript)
72
(No Transcript)
73
Highly Asymmetric PVEV Function in 1940
74
(No Transcript)
75
1860 Election
76
Even More Asymmetric PVEV Function in 1860
77
Two Distinct Sources of Bias in the PVEV
  • Asymmetry or bias in the PVEV function can result
    either or both from two distinct phenomena
  • distribution effects.
  • apportionment effects and
  • Either effect alone can produce a reversal of
    winners, and
  • they can either reinforce or counterbalance each
    other.

78
Apportionment Effects
  • A perfectly apportioned districted electoral
    system is one in which each states electoral
    vote is precisely proportional to its popular
    vote in every election (and apportionment effects
    are thereby eliminated).
  • It follows that, in a perfectly apportioned
    system, a party (or candidate) wins X of the
    electoral vote if and only if it wins states with
    X of the total popular vote.
  • Note that this says nothing about the popular
    vote margin by which the party/candidate wins (or
    loses) states.
  • Therefore this does not say that the party wins
    X (or any other specific ) of the popular vote.
  • An electoral system cannot be perfectly
    apportioned in advance of the election (in
    advance of knowing the popular vote in each
    state).

79
Apportionment Effects (cont.)
  • In highly abstract analysis of its workings, Alan
    Natapoff (an MIT physicist) largely endorsed the
    workings Electoral College (particularly its
    within-state winner-take-all feature) as a vote
    counting mechanism but proposed that each states
    electoral vote be made precisely proportional to
    its share of the national popular vote.
  • This implies that
  • electoral votes would not be apportioned until
    after the election, and
  • would not be apportioned in whole numbers.
  • Actually Natapoff proposes perfect apportionment
    of House electoral votes while retaining
    Senatorial electoral effects
  • in order to counteract the Lion Banzhaf
    Effect.
  • Such a system would eliminate apportionment
    effects from the Electoral College system (while
    fully retaining its distribution effects).
  • Reversal of winners can still occur under
    Natapoffs perfectly apportioned system (due to
    distribution effects).
  • Natapoffs perfectly apportioned EC system would
    create seemingly perverse turnout incentives in
    non-battleground states,
  • though he views this as a further advantage of
    his proposed.
  • Alan Natapoff, A Mathematical One-Man One-Vote
    Rationale for Madisonian Presidential Voting
    Based on Maximum Individual Voting Power, Public
    Choice, 88/3-4 (1996).

80
Imperfect Apportionment
  • The U.S. Electoral College system is
    (substantially) imperfectly apportioned, for many
    reasons.
  • House (and electoral vote) apportionments are
    anywhere from two (e.g., in 1992) to ten years
    (e.g., in 2000) out of date.
  • House seats (and electoral votes) are apportioned
    on the basis of total population, not on the
    basis of
  • the voting age population, or
  • the voting eligible population, or
  • registered voters, or
  • actual voters in a given election.
  • All these factors vary considerably from state to
    state (and district to district).
  • House seats (and electoral votes) must be
    apportioned in whole numbers and therefore cant
    be precisely proportional to anything.
  • Small states are guaranteed a minimum of three
    electoral votes.

81
Imperfect Apportionment (cont.)
  • Similar imperfections apply (in lesser or greater
    degree) in all districted systems.
  • Imperfect apportionment may or may not bring
    about bias in the PVEV function.
  • This depends on the extent to which states
    (districts) having greater or lesser weight than
    they would have under perfect apportionment is
    correlated with their support for one or other
    candidate or party.

82
1988 PVEV Based on Perfect vs. Imperfect
Apportionment
83
1940 PVEV Based on Perfect vs. Imperfect
Apportionment
84
1860 PVEV Based on Perfect vs. Imperfect
Apportionment
85
Distribution Effects
  • Distribution effects in districted electoral
    system result from the winner-take-all at the
    district/state level character of these systems.
  • Such effects can be powerful even in
  • simple districted (one district-one
    seat/electoral vote) systems, and
  • perfectly apportioned systems.
  • One candidates or partys vote may be more
    efficiently distributed than the others,
    causing an election reversal independent of
    apportionment effects.

86
Distribution Effects (cont.)
  • Here is the simplest possible example of
    distribution effects producing a reversal of
    winners in a simple and perfectly apportioned
    district system.
  • There are 9 voters partitioned into 3 districts,
    and candidates D and R win popular votes as
    follows (R,R,D) (R,R,D) (D,D,D)
  • Popular Votes Electoral Votes
  • D 5 1
  • R 4 2
  • Rs votes are more efficiently distributed, so R
    wins a majority of electoral votes with a
    minority of popular votes.

87
The 25-75 Rule
  • The most extreme logically possible example of an
    election reversal in perfectly apportioned system
    results when
  • one candidate or party wins just over 50 of the
    popular votes in just over 50 of the (uniform)
    districts or in non-uniform districts that
    collectively have just over 50 of the electoral
    votes.
  • These districts also have just over 50 of the
    popular vote (because apportionment is perfect).
  • The winning candidate or party therefore wins
    just over 50 of the electoral votes with just
    over 25 (50 x 50) of the popular vote and
    the other candidate with almost 75 of the
    popular vote loses the election.
  • The election reversal interval is (just short of)
    25 percentage points wide.
  • If the candidate or party with the favorable vote
    distribution is also favored by imperfect
    apportionment, the reversal interval could be
    winners could be even more extreme.

88
The 25-75 Rule in 1860 (cont.)
  • In the 1860 Lincoln vs. anti-Lincoln scenario,
    the popular vote distribution approximated the
    25-75 pattern quite well.
  • Lincoln would have carried all the northern
    states except NJ, CA, and OR
  • which held a bit more than half the electoral
    votes (and a larger majority of the free
    population),
  • generally by modest popular vote margins.
  • The anti-Lincoln opposition would have
  • carried all southern states with a bit less than
    half of the electoral votes (and substantially
    less than half of the free population)
  • by essentially 100 margins and
  • lost all other states other than NJ, CA, and OR
    by relatively narrow margins.

89
Distribution Effects (cont.)
  • The Pure Proportional Plan for casting electoral
    votes eliminates distribution effects entirely.
  • The Whole Number Proportional and Districts Plans
    do not eliminate distribution effects, and so
  • they permit election reversals (even with perfect
    apportionment) indeed
  • the District Plans permit election reversals at
    the state as well as national levels.
  • But election reversals could still occur under
    the Pure Proportional Plan due to apportionment
    effects.
  • The reversals would favor candidates who do
    exceptionally well in small and/or low turnout
    states).
  • However, the Pure Proportional Plan combined with
    perfect apportionment would be equivalent to
    direct national popular vote,
  • so election reversals could not occur, and
  • individual voting power would be equalized (and
    maximized).

90
Apportionment vs. Distribution Effects in 1860
  • The 1860 election was based on highly imperfect
    apportionment.
  • The southern states (for the last time) benefited
    from the 3/5 compromise pertaining to
    apportionment.
  • The southern states had on average smaller
    popula-tions than the northern states and
    therefore benefited disproportionately from the
    small-state guarantee.
  • Even within the free population, suffrage was
    more restricted in the south than in the north.
  • Turnout among eligible voters was lower in the
    south than the north.

91
Apportionment vs. Distribution Effects in 1860
(cont.)
  • But all these apportionment effects favored the
    south and therefore the Democrats.
  • Thus the pro-Republican reversal of winners was
    entirely due to distribution effects.
  • The magnitude of the reversal of winners in 1860
    would have been even greater in the absence of
    the countervailing apportionment effects.
  • If the most salient characteristic of the
    Electoral College is that it may produce election
    reversals, ones evaluation of the EC may depend
    on whether one thinks Lincoln should have been
    elected President in 1860.

92
Sterling Diagrams Visualizing Apportionment and
Distribution Effects Together
  • First, we construct a bar graph of state-by-state
    popular and electoral vote totals, set up in the
    following manner.
  • The horizontal axis represents all states
  • ranked from the strongest to weakest for the
    winning party where
  • the thickness of each bar is proportional to the
    states electoral vote and
  • the height of each bar is proportional to the
    winning partys percent of the popular vote in
    that state.
  • Note this isnt yet a proper Sterling diagram.
  • Carleton W. Sterling, Electoral College
    Misrepresentation A Geometric Analysis, Polity,
    Spring 1981.

93
(No Transcript)
94
Sterling Diagrams (cont.)
  • It is tempting to think that the shaded and
    unshaded areas of the diagram represent the
    proportions of the popular vote won by the
    winning and losing parties respectively.
  • But this isnt true until we make one adjustment
    and thereby create a Sterling diagram.
  • Adjust the width of each bar so it is
    proportional,
  • not to the states share of electoral votes, but
  • to the states share of the popular national
    popular vote.
  • If electoral votes were perfectly apportioned, no
    adjustment would be required.
  • Draw a vertical line at the point on the
    horizontal axis where a cumulative electoral vote
    majority is achieved.
  • In a perfectly apportioned system, this would be
    at just above the 50 mark.
  • If there is no systematic apportionment bias in
    the particular election, this will also be just
    about at the 50 mark.

95
Sterling Diagrams Apportionment Effects
96
Sterling Diagram for 1848
97
Sterling Diagrams The 25-75 Rule (with Perfect
Apportionment)
98
Sterling Diagrams The 25-75 Rule Approximated
99
Sterling Diagram 1860
100
Sterling Diagram 1860
101
Typical Sterling Diagram (50-50 Election)
102
Sterling Diagram1988
103
Sterling Diagram1936
104
Sterling Diagram 2000
105
Sterling Diagram 2000 under Pure District Plan
106
Sterling Diagram 2000 House Seats
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com