Education and Wages

1 / 33
About This Presentation
Title:

Education and Wages

Description:

Universidade da Madeira. 2. The paradigm of the two islands Pereira and ... da Madeira. 3 ... Universidade da Madeira. 5. There is a value of r, rc, such ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:153
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 34
Provided by: Fern181

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Education and Wages


1
Education and Wages
  • Pedro Telhado Pereira
  • May 2004
  • Part 4

2
The paradigm of the two islands Pereira and
Martins (2004)
  • two islands
  • (I1) with a productivity per capita of P
  • (I2) with a productivity per capita of Q
  • PltQ.
  • The inhabitants of the islands live an eternal
    life (all are born at the same moment) and
    maximize the present value of their production.

3
  • The inhabitants of I1 can move to I2 if they
    spend one period learning how to swim.
  • The only cost is the product they forgo during
    that period.
  • The discount rate is uniformly distributed
    between (r1, r2) f(r)1/(r2-r1).

4
The decision of learning to swim is made by
comparing (E1)
and (E2)

5
  • There is a value of r, rc, such that E1E2.
  • Let us assume that r1 lt rc lt r2.
  • If r lt rc then E1 lt E2 and the individual decides
    to learn to swim and thereafter swims from I1 to
    I2.
  • If r gt rc then E1 gt E2 and the individual does
    not learn to swim and stays on I1.

6
Therefore, there will be S1 proportion of
swimmers, where
  • We end up with three groups of individuals
  • living on island one,
  • living on island two and born there, and
  • living on island two and born on island one.

7
  • The labour economists want to explain the
    differences in productivity and therefore they
    can do so by examining the place where the
    person is living (the wage equation approach).
  • But suppose that we are interested in studying
    the returns to education (learning to swim). We
    must then look at the persons born on island one
    and see the differentials in their productivities
    as the return we are looking for. This is what
    education economists look for.
  • We could never find this return if we considered
    the place of residence as one of the explanatory
    variables of the productivity differential, the
    reason being that this covariate is a result of
    learning to swim for people born on island one.

8
This example illustrates
  • the difference between wage equations - where
    education is one of the explanatory variables -
    and returns to education - where all the indirect
    effects should be accounted for.

9
When an individual (or his family) decides the
amount of education he wants to have
  • he knows that education is going to bring him a
    better paid job,
  • but at the same time gives him more opportunities
    in choosing other characteristics as, for
    instance, the sector and firm where he ends up
    working in.
  • Part of the private return from education to the
    individual is going to be through the return he
    will get from the posterior choices he can make.

10
In econometric terms
Let us assume that wages depend on education (S)
and other covariates, represented by an indicator
(C). To make it as simple as possible and
following the Mincer specification we have
where b1gt0 and b2gt0 or b2lt0
11
  • If b2gt0, people with more education will choose
    the largest C and therefore there is a positive
    relation between S and C.
  • If b2lt0, people with more education will choose
    the smallest C and therefore there is a negative
    relation between S and C.

12
If we assume this relation to be linear, we have
and
13
The rate of return of Education
14
Main conclusions
  • To obtain the full effect of the education on
    wages we should only regress the ln(wage) in
    education and/or not consider the covariates that
    depend on schooling
  • If we include covariates that depend on education
    on the regression the coefficient of schooling
    decreases (at least in the expected value of the
    estimators).

15
What has been considered in the wage equation
  • The efficiency wages hypothesis (see, inter alia,
    Krueger and Summers, 1988) warrants the inclusion
    of sectors of activity, firm size and firm age.
  • Hartog, Pereira, Vieira (2000)

16
  • Following the seminal work of Krueger and Summers
    (1988), several studies have been carried out in
    a large number of countries and shown the
    existence of inter industry wage differentials
    for apparently equally skilled workers. Although
    part of these differentials can be explained by
    unobserved heterogeneity, this does not explain
    all the variation
  • These findings pose a challenge to textbook
    competitive models of the labour market and
    alternative explanations based on efficiency wage
    mechanisms or rent sharing have been put forward
  • Nevertheless, the existence of such differentials
    has not been clearly understood and remains an
    intricate and unresolved puzzle.

17
  • The data were drawn from Quadros de Pessoal for
    the years of 1982, 1986 and 1992.
  • Conclusion
  • The study shows Portugal has a high
    inter-industry wage inequality. The size of the
    inter-industry wage dispersion in Portugal seems
    similar to that of countries rated as having a
    decentralised wage setting.
  • Nevertheless, the dispersion decreased during
    the1980s.
  • We argue that shifts towards a more centralised
    and co-ordinated wage setting may have played a
    role here.

18
  • The existence of rents and trade unions or
    agency models (see Freeman and Medoff (1986),
    Pencavel (1991), Hart and Holmstrom (1987), among
    others) justify the inclusion of the bargaining
    regimes.
  • Hartog, Pereira and Vieira (2002)

19
  • labour economists have increasingly realised that
    wage structures and labour contracts may also be
    instruments to the firm.
  • Moreover, the influence of the institutional
    environment of the labour market has led to
    greater interest in the role of bargaining
    between trade unions and management.

20
  • The data used - Quadros de Pessoal for 1986 and
    1992
  • Conclusions
  • The results show that after controlling for a
    large set of individual and job related
    characteristics, the firm bargaining regime
    coverage apparently is important in explaining
    the variability of wages.
  • The main results reveal that wage differentials
    between the bargaining regimes are in some cases
    sizeable.

21
  • that multi-firm contracts tend to generate higher
    wages
  • sectoral contracts tend to generate the lowest
    wages.
  • Compulsory regimes and single-firm contracts
    align at an intermediate level in the ranking.

22
  • Internal wage structures (see Lazear (1998), for
    instance) justify the inclusion of seniority
    (tenure).
  • Lima, F. and P. T. Pereira (2003)

23
  • The relationship between employers and employees
    is rather complex and subject to different
    dimensions of analysis.
  • One such dimension is the wage growth associated
    with the employees career progression inside the
    firm.
  • The real world is replete with examples of job
    ladders that individuals climb during their
    working lives and of the major pay changes that
    accompany those steps.

24
The main questions
  • What is the effect of promotion on the wage
    growth?
  • How does the wage growth depend on the
    hierarchical position held by the employee?
  • To what extent are human capital accumulation and
    learning about individual abilities reflected in
    wage paths?
  • What is the effect of demotions?

25
Data used
  • The data set used is a sample of firms drawn from
    the survey Quadros de Pessoal collected annually
    by the Ministry of Employment.
  • A random sample of firms was drawn, stratified
    according to economic activity, location, firms
    legal form, and number of employees.
  • The sample is a longitudinal matched
    employer-employee
  • panel of 74 large firms from the manufacturing
    sector, with more than 500 workers each year and
    followed between 1991 and 1995. T
  • he employment history of all workers in the firm
    and several firms characteristics are available.
  • The original sample has 391,618 observations.

26
Conclusions
  • Promotions and/or transitions to upper job levels
    imply a positive and important wage premium.
  • Demotions are associated with negative wage
    premiums.
  • The negative wage premiums are more important at
    the bottom job levels, probably as a result of
    the (negative) learning effect.
  • The wage premiums for promotions are higher at
    the tails of the hierarchy, generating a U-shaped
    relationship between the workers career path and
    wage growth.
  • In the context of the model discussed, it
    suggests a stronger learning and/or human capital
    accumulation effect at the bottom of the
    hierarchy and a stronger job assignment effect at
    the top.

27
The influence of covariates on returns to
education
  • Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2004), Returns
    to Education and Wage Equations, Applied
    Economics, forthcoming.
  • We a meta-analysis - is a regression that takes
    as dependent variable the outcomes from different
    studies that focus on the same topic and employ
    the same general methodology. The regressors
    describe the characteristics (in terms of
    equation specification, in sample size, in year
    of estimation, and so on) underlying those
    different results and/or studies. A meta-analysis
    is therefore a useful tool for summarizing
    several results on a given topic, allowing a
    researcher to have a global and quantifiable view
    on the link between the structure of a research
    project and its results. In the present study,
    we examine the influence of covariates in the
    return to education.

28
Data used
  • A meta-analysis uses two kinds of data, which we
    label here as foreground and background data.
  • The former is the directly-used information,
    which includes the coefficients of education that
    were obtained in different studies, and the
    presumably relevant characteristics of those
    studies. By such characteristics, we mean the
    regressors used, sample size, and so on.
  • Background data, on the other hand, is simply the
    primary sources (data sets) used for computing
    the returns to education (or better, a
    coefficient to education).

29
Wage equations in Portugal
  • Have used between two ( experience and experience
    squared) to a maximum was 37 explanatory
    variables.
  • The number of explanatory variables - in the
    background regressions - corresponds to the
    number of regressors used besides education and a
    constant.

30
Conclusions
  • The use of the Mincer equation in its simpler
    form (education, experience and experience
    squared) seems to give an approximate value for
    the total return to education.
  • If more covariates are used in this equation and
    these covariates are choice variables that depend
    on education, then the coefficient of the
    education should fall.
  • This result is supported by the meta-analysis we
    performed using data for Portugal.
  • The coefficient decreases with all combinations
    of variables used and can drop to half of its
    size, especially when the sector of activity is
    one of the covariates used.
  • The education-related choice of sector is an
    aspect that should reflect itself in
    over-education in the better paying sectors.

31
  • Sample size, the use of monthly wages instead of
    hourly wages, the interaction between education
    and experience and tenure do not seem to
    influence the coefficient, which shows its
    robustness to sample size, specification of the
    simple Mincer equation and variables that are
    independent of education.
  • The increase of the return to education when
    regions is used as one of the covariates needs
    further research, as it seems to show that in the
    Portuguese case the mobility due to job
    opportunities is rare.

32
Final Remark
  • Returns to education and changes in productivity
    can be very distinct realities.
  • Both are worth studying but one should
    distinguish between them.

33
  • References
  • Freeman, R. B. and J. L. Medoff, (1986). The Two
    Faces of Unionism. In L. G. Reynolds, S.H.
    Masters and C. H. Moser, eds,. Readings in labor
    economics and labor relations, Fourth edition,
    Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Prentice Hall.
  • Hart, O. and B. Holmstrom (1987). A theory of
    contracts. In T. F. Bewley, Advances in Economic
    Theory, Fifth World Congress, Cambridge
    Cambridge University Press.
  • Hartog, H., P.T. Pereira and J. C. Vieira, (2000)
    'Inter-Industry Wage Dispersion in Portugal High
    But Falling', Empirica, 27/4, 353-364.
  • Hartog, H., P.T. Pereira and J. C. Vieira, (2002)
    "Bargaining Regimes and Wages in Portugal",
    Portuguese Economic Journal, vol.1, n. 3,
    237-268.
  • Krueger, A. and L. Summers (1988). Efficient
    wages and the inter-industry wage structure.
    Econometrica 56(2), 259-293.
  • Lazear, E. P (1998). Personnel Economics for
    Managers, New York John Wiley and Sons.
  • Lima, F. And P. T. Pereira (2003), Careers and
    Wage Growth within Large Firms ", International
    Journal of Manpower No 7, Volume 24, 2003.
  • Pencavel, J. (1991). Higher Education,
    Productivity, and Earnings A Review. Journal of
    Economic Education 224, 331-359.
  • Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2004), Returns
    to Education and Wage Equations, Applied
    Economics, forthcoming.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)