Title: Education and Wages
1Education and Wages
- Pedro Telhado Pereira
- May 2004
- Part 4
2The paradigm of the two islands Pereira and
Martins (2004)
- two islands
- (I1) with a productivity per capita of P
- (I2) with a productivity per capita of Q
- PltQ.
- The inhabitants of the islands live an eternal
life (all are born at the same moment) and
maximize the present value of their production.
3- The inhabitants of I1 can move to I2 if they
spend one period learning how to swim. - The only cost is the product they forgo during
that period. - The discount rate is uniformly distributed
between (r1, r2) f(r)1/(r2-r1).
4The decision of learning to swim is made by
comparing (E1)
and (E2)
5- There is a value of r, rc, such that E1E2.
- Let us assume that r1 lt rc lt r2.
- If r lt rc then E1 lt E2 and the individual decides
to learn to swim and thereafter swims from I1 to
I2. - If r gt rc then E1 gt E2 and the individual does
not learn to swim and stays on I1.
6Therefore, there will be S1 proportion of
swimmers, where
- We end up with three groups of individuals
- living on island one,
- living on island two and born there, and
- living on island two and born on island one.
7- The labour economists want to explain the
differences in productivity and therefore they
can do so by examining the place where the
person is living (the wage equation approach). - But suppose that we are interested in studying
the returns to education (learning to swim). We
must then look at the persons born on island one
and see the differentials in their productivities
as the return we are looking for. This is what
education economists look for. - We could never find this return if we considered
the place of residence as one of the explanatory
variables of the productivity differential, the
reason being that this covariate is a result of
learning to swim for people born on island one.
8This example illustrates
- the difference between wage equations - where
education is one of the explanatory variables -
and returns to education - where all the indirect
effects should be accounted for.
9When an individual (or his family) decides the
amount of education he wants to have
- he knows that education is going to bring him a
better paid job, - but at the same time gives him more opportunities
in choosing other characteristics as, for
instance, the sector and firm where he ends up
working in. - Part of the private return from education to the
individual is going to be through the return he
will get from the posterior choices he can make.
10In econometric terms
Let us assume that wages depend on education (S)
and other covariates, represented by an indicator
(C). To make it as simple as possible and
following the Mincer specification we have
where b1gt0 and b2gt0 or b2lt0
11- If b2gt0, people with more education will choose
the largest C and therefore there is a positive
relation between S and C. - If b2lt0, people with more education will choose
the smallest C and therefore there is a negative
relation between S and C.
12If we assume this relation to be linear, we have
and
13The rate of return of Education
14Main conclusions
- To obtain the full effect of the education on
wages we should only regress the ln(wage) in
education and/or not consider the covariates that
depend on schooling - If we include covariates that depend on education
on the regression the coefficient of schooling
decreases (at least in the expected value of the
estimators).
15What has been considered in the wage equation
- The efficiency wages hypothesis (see, inter alia,
Krueger and Summers, 1988) warrants the inclusion
of sectors of activity, firm size and firm age. - Hartog, Pereira, Vieira (2000)
16- Following the seminal work of Krueger and Summers
(1988), several studies have been carried out in
a large number of countries and shown the
existence of inter industry wage differentials
for apparently equally skilled workers. Although
part of these differentials can be explained by
unobserved heterogeneity, this does not explain
all the variation - These findings pose a challenge to textbook
competitive models of the labour market and
alternative explanations based on efficiency wage
mechanisms or rent sharing have been put forward - Nevertheless, the existence of such differentials
has not been clearly understood and remains an
intricate and unresolved puzzle.
17- The data were drawn from Quadros de Pessoal for
the years of 1982, 1986 and 1992. - Conclusion
- The study shows Portugal has a high
inter-industry wage inequality. The size of the
inter-industry wage dispersion in Portugal seems
similar to that of countries rated as having a
decentralised wage setting. - Nevertheless, the dispersion decreased during
the1980s. - We argue that shifts towards a more centralised
and co-ordinated wage setting may have played a
role here.
18- The existence of rents and trade unions or
agency models (see Freeman and Medoff (1986),
Pencavel (1991), Hart and Holmstrom (1987), among
others) justify the inclusion of the bargaining
regimes. - Hartog, Pereira and Vieira (2002)
19- labour economists have increasingly realised that
wage structures and labour contracts may also be
instruments to the firm. - Moreover, the influence of the institutional
environment of the labour market has led to
greater interest in the role of bargaining
between trade unions and management.
20- The data used - Quadros de Pessoal for 1986 and
1992 - Conclusions
- The results show that after controlling for a
large set of individual and job related
characteristics, the firm bargaining regime
coverage apparently is important in explaining
the variability of wages. - The main results reveal that wage differentials
between the bargaining regimes are in some cases
sizeable.
21- that multi-firm contracts tend to generate higher
wages - sectoral contracts tend to generate the lowest
wages. - Compulsory regimes and single-firm contracts
align at an intermediate level in the ranking.
22- Internal wage structures (see Lazear (1998), for
instance) justify the inclusion of seniority
(tenure). - Lima, F. and P. T. Pereira (2003)
23- The relationship between employers and employees
is rather complex and subject to different
dimensions of analysis. - One such dimension is the wage growth associated
with the employees career progression inside the
firm. - The real world is replete with examples of job
ladders that individuals climb during their
working lives and of the major pay changes that
accompany those steps.
24The main questions
- What is the effect of promotion on the wage
growth? - How does the wage growth depend on the
hierarchical position held by the employee? - To what extent are human capital accumulation and
learning about individual abilities reflected in
wage paths? - What is the effect of demotions?
25Data used
- The data set used is a sample of firms drawn from
the survey Quadros de Pessoal collected annually
by the Ministry of Employment. - A random sample of firms was drawn, stratified
according to economic activity, location, firms
legal form, and number of employees. - The sample is a longitudinal matched
employer-employee - panel of 74 large firms from the manufacturing
sector, with more than 500 workers each year and
followed between 1991 and 1995. T - he employment history of all workers in the firm
and several firms characteristics are available.
- The original sample has 391,618 observations.
26Conclusions
- Promotions and/or transitions to upper job levels
imply a positive and important wage premium. - Demotions are associated with negative wage
premiums. - The negative wage premiums are more important at
the bottom job levels, probably as a result of
the (negative) learning effect. - The wage premiums for promotions are higher at
the tails of the hierarchy, generating a U-shaped
relationship between the workers career path and
wage growth. - In the context of the model discussed, it
suggests a stronger learning and/or human capital
accumulation effect at the bottom of the
hierarchy and a stronger job assignment effect at
the top.
27The influence of covariates on returns to
education
- Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2004), Returns
to Education and Wage Equations, Applied
Economics, forthcoming. - We a meta-analysis - is a regression that takes
as dependent variable the outcomes from different
studies that focus on the same topic and employ
the same general methodology. The regressors
describe the characteristics (in terms of
equation specification, in sample size, in year
of estimation, and so on) underlying those
different results and/or studies. A meta-analysis
is therefore a useful tool for summarizing
several results on a given topic, allowing a
researcher to have a global and quantifiable view
on the link between the structure of a research
project and its results. In the present study,
we examine the influence of covariates in the
return to education.
28Data used
- A meta-analysis uses two kinds of data, which we
label here as foreground and background data. - The former is the directly-used information,
which includes the coefficients of education that
were obtained in different studies, and the
presumably relevant characteristics of those
studies. By such characteristics, we mean the
regressors used, sample size, and so on. - Background data, on the other hand, is simply the
primary sources (data sets) used for computing
the returns to education (or better, a
coefficient to education).
29Wage equations in Portugal
- Have used between two ( experience and experience
squared) to a maximum was 37 explanatory
variables. - The number of explanatory variables - in the
background regressions - corresponds to the
number of regressors used besides education and a
constant.
30Conclusions
- The use of the Mincer equation in its simpler
form (education, experience and experience
squared) seems to give an approximate value for
the total return to education. - If more covariates are used in this equation and
these covariates are choice variables that depend
on education, then the coefficient of the
education should fall. - This result is supported by the meta-analysis we
performed using data for Portugal. - The coefficient decreases with all combinations
of variables used and can drop to half of its
size, especially when the sector of activity is
one of the covariates used. - The education-related choice of sector is an
aspect that should reflect itself in
over-education in the better paying sectors.
31- Sample size, the use of monthly wages instead of
hourly wages, the interaction between education
and experience and tenure do not seem to
influence the coefficient, which shows its
robustness to sample size, specification of the
simple Mincer equation and variables that are
independent of education. - The increase of the return to education when
regions is used as one of the covariates needs
further research, as it seems to show that in the
Portuguese case the mobility due to job
opportunities is rare.
32Final Remark
- Returns to education and changes in productivity
can be very distinct realities. - Both are worth studying but one should
distinguish between them.
33- References
- Freeman, R. B. and J. L. Medoff, (1986). The Two
Faces of Unionism. In L. G. Reynolds, S.H.
Masters and C. H. Moser, eds,. Readings in labor
economics and labor relations, Fourth edition,
Englewood Cliffs, N.J. Prentice Hall. - Hart, O. and B. Holmstrom (1987). A theory of
contracts. In T. F. Bewley, Advances in Economic
Theory, Fifth World Congress, Cambridge
Cambridge University Press. - Hartog, H., P.T. Pereira and J. C. Vieira, (2000)
'Inter-Industry Wage Dispersion in Portugal High
But Falling', Empirica, 27/4, 353-364. - Hartog, H., P.T. Pereira and J. C. Vieira, (2002)
"Bargaining Regimes and Wages in Portugal",
Portuguese Economic Journal, vol.1, n. 3,
237-268. - Krueger, A. and L. Summers (1988). Efficient
wages and the inter-industry wage structure.
Econometrica 56(2), 259-293. - Lazear, E. P (1998). Personnel Economics for
Managers, New York John Wiley and Sons. - Lima, F. And P. T. Pereira (2003), Careers and
Wage Growth within Large Firms ", International
Journal of Manpower No 7, Volume 24, 2003. - Pencavel, J. (1991). Higher Education,
Productivity, and Earnings A Review. Journal of
Economic Education 224, 331-359. - Pereira, P. T. and P. S. Martins (2004), Returns
to Education and Wage Equations, Applied
Economics, forthcoming.