Title: Investments in Human Capital
1Investments in Human Capital
- Three major labor market investments -
- (1) education and training (2) migration and (3)
search for new jobs - Investments in human capital - rented out to
employers - Initial outlay which will pay-off in the long run
2Investments in Human Capital
- Human capital includes accumulated investments in
education, job training etc. - Total wealth in U.S around 421,000/person in
1990 of which 59 or 248,000 was in the form of
human capital - Canada 155,000
- Germany 315,000
- Japan 458,000
3Investments in Human Capital
- Investments in human capital takes place in three
stages - Childhood - parental decisions
- Teenagers and young adults decide themselves
- Finally on the job training after entering labor
force
4Investments in Human Capital
- In this chapter we focus on the second of the
three stages. The third is dealt in Chap. 10 - Example 9.1 (page 288)
- People faces with the same set of options make
widely different choices - Cognitive skills, parental wealth etc. impact
attitudes towards learning and work
5Investments in Human Capital
- Three types of costs
- Out of pocket or direct expenses
- Opportunity costs
- Psychic costs
- Present value of a stream of yearly benefits (B1,
B2,) over time (T) can be calculated as - NPVB1/(1r) B2/(1r)2 B3/(1r)3...
6Investments in Human Capital
- Where r is the interest rate (discount rate)
- As long as r is positive benefits into the future
will be discounted - for instance if r0.06, benefits payable in 30
years will receive a weight which is 17 of the
weight placed on immediate benefits - 1/(10.06)30 1/(1.06)301/5.74 and
1/5.740.17
7Investments in Human Capital
- If the net present value of the investment
exceeds the cost of the investment then the
investment is undertaken - B1/(1r) B2/(1r)2BT/(1r)TgtC
8Example
- Suppose cost of project is 12000
- Benefits accrue over three years, 3000 in year
1, 7000 in year 2 and 10,000 in year 3 - interest rate 3
- Undertake project?
9NPV
- NPV of project is
- 3000/(10.03) 7000/(10.03)2
10000/(10.03)3 18662.20 - So undertake project since NPV exceeds Cost
10Optimum acquisition of HC
MC, MB
MC,MB
MC
MC
MC
MB
MB
MB
HC
HC
11Demand for College Education
- For males enrollment went from 55.2 in 1970 to
46.7 in 1980 and back up to 59.7 in 1993 - For women enrollment started lower at 48.5 in
1970, rose continuously to a high of 65.3 by
1993 - as measured by the percentage of graduating high
school seniors who enroll in college
12Demand for College Education
- Figure 9.2 (page 293)
- Choice between two income streams - going into
workforce after high school - stream A or going
to college and then joining the workforce -
stream B
13Alternative Earnings Streams
Figure 9.2
14Demand for College Education
- Four predictions
- 1. Present oriented people are less likely to go
to college than forward looking people (all else
equal) - 2. Most college students will be young
- 3. Attendance decreases with costs of college
- 4. Attendance increases with an increasing premium
15Demand for College Education
- 1. Present oriented people would discount future
incomes very heavily would need very high returns
on investment - 2. Future benefits are higher for younger people
- 3. Law of demand
- 4. Table 9.1 (page 297)
16Demand for College Education
- However the problem is quite complicated
- Increased college attendance may lower future
earnings if job growth does not keep pace -
excess supply - See Example 9.2 (page 299)
17Post-schooling Investments in Human Capital
- Decision to acquire training later in life
- Figures 9.3 and 9.4 (pages 301-303)
- Four notable features (1) average incomes rise
with the level of education (2) most rapid
increases occur early in ones life (3)
Age/earnings profile fan out - so that
differences are sharper in later years than early
on (4) age/earnings profile for men fan out more
18Figure 9.3
Money Earnings (Mean), for Full-Time,
Year-Round Male Workers, 1997
19Money Earnings (Mean), for Full-Time, Year-Round
Female Workers, 1997
Figure 9.4
20Post-schooling Investments in Human Capital
- The increase in earnings with age can be
attributed to on-the-job training - learning by doing
- specific training - during training workers MP
is less than wage while after training workers
MP is greater than wage - so costs shared by
employer and employee - general training - costs borne by employee by
accepting trading off current earnings for future
ones
21Post-schooling Investments in Human Capital
- Figure 9.5 (page 304)
- As a result of investing in training initially
earnings may be lower but over time they become
larger and increase rapidly - Why do age/earnings fan out?
- Investments in human capital tend to be greater
(1) when the expected earnings are greater (2)
when the initial investment costs are lower and
(3) when the investor has longer time to recoup
the investment
22Investment in On-the-Job Training over the Life
Cycle
Figure 9.5
23Post-schooling Investments in Human Capital
- People with the ability to learn quickly are more
likely to seek out and be presented by employers
with learning opportunities - But who are these fast learners?
- They are usually people who because of their
abilities were best able to reap the benefits of
formal schooling. So those who invested more in
schooling are likely to invest more in
post-school training - This explains why their earnings profile start
low but rise quickly and keep rising while that
of their less-educated counterparts have leveled
off
24Women and the acquisition of human capital
- Earnings of women who work full-time year around
are lower than that for men of equivalent age
(See Figures 9.3 and 9.4) - What does human capital theory have to say about
this? We will discuss other factors in Chapter 12 - Major difference - the length of work-life over
which the investment can be recouped - Table 9.2 (page 307) shows that overall women can
expect to work fewer years and within each
occupation they work fewer hours
25Women and the acquisition of human capital
- Shorter work-life caused primarily by womens
historic role in child bearing and household
production - This traditional role, while undergoing
significant changes, has caused many women to
drop out of the labor market during childbearing
years - Thus female workers often lack the continuity
that male workers have From historic experience
and expecting this discontinuity women often do
not invest in occupation where skills depreciate
during discontinuity
26Women and the acquisition of human capital
- Also historic experience can cause employers to
avoid hiring women for jobs requiring much
on-the-job training - a practice that will itself
affect the returns women can expect from a human
capital investment - Recent changes in the labor market conditions and
laws are causing dramatic changes in the
acquisition of human capital by women
27Women and job training
- Little doubt that women receive less job training
than men - A study of formal company given to workers in
their 20s found that between 1986 and 1991 a
lower percentage of women received on-the-job
training and those who did get training received
fewer hours of training
28Women and job training
- Flatter age-earnings profile may be explained
partly by this - But does it arise from employer or employee is
debatable - We said things are changing
- Take a look at Figure 9.6 (page 309)
- In 1977 a 32 year old female college grad earned
26 more than 21 year college-grad, in 1992 it
was 59 more
29The Increased Concavity of Womens Age/Earnings
Profiles
Figure 9.6
30Women and formal schooling
- Table 9.3 (page 310)
- 54 of B.S. women in 1991 47.2 business majors
large increase in law and medicine 6.3 to 39
31Is Education a good investment?
- Is there evidence that the investment in
education pays for the typical student? - Several studies have tried to answer this
question by calculating the internal rates of
return to educational investments - These studies normally estimate benefits by
calculating earnings differentials at each age
from age/earnings profiles such as those in
Figures 9.3 and 9.4
32Is Education a good investment?
- The rates of return typically estimated for the
Unites States generally fall in 5-15 range
(after adjusting for inflation). These findings
are interesting because most other investments
generate returns in the same range. Thus, it
appears that an investment in education is about
as good as an investment in stocks, bonds or real
estate. - We do need to keep in mind though that there are
some biases at work in these estimates
33Is Education a good investment?
- Upward Bias
- The typical estimates of the rate of return on
further schooling may overstate the gain an
individual student could obtain by investing in
education because they are unable to separate the
contribution of ability and schooling. - The problem is that (a) people who are smarter,
harder working and more dynamic are likely to
obtain more schooling and (b) such people may be
more productive and earn higher wages
34Is Education a good investment?
- Upward Bias
- Recent studies have attempted to control for the
ability bias by looking separately at the
impact of schooling and aptitude tests in
earnings. - Others look at what happens when a random event
and not ability affects years of schooling - Others look at family members or even identical
twins - The consensus is that ability bias is usually
small
35Is Education a good investment?
- Downward Bias
- (1) some benefits of college attendance do not
show up in higher productivity/earnings but
contribute to a persons way of thinking - (2) studies measure earnings and not benefits
but better jobs may have not only better earnings
but better job security and other ancillary
benefits which are not accounted for - (3) Psychic of non-monetary benefits - more
pleasant working conditions at better jobs
36Is Education a good investment?
- Selection bias
- There is a selectivity problem. Going to college
is a choice made by some and not by others - Usual studies look at the internal rates of
return for what someone makes with a college
degree and what the same person would have made
in the absence of a college degree - But this may understate returns to college
education and overstate the returns of those who
did not attend college. But again this bias is
small
37Is Education a good social investment?
- (1) product markets have become more global
increasing the elasticities of both product and
labor demand. As a result American workers are
facing more competition from foreign workers. - (2) Growing availability of high-tech capital
requires workers to have greater cognitive skills
and to be adaptable, efficient learners. Recent
studies indicate that returns to workers with
greater quantitative skills have risen in recent
years.
38Is Education a good social investment?
- (3) U.S. elementary and secondary school students
score poorly relative to students elsewhere in
language proficiency, scientific knowledge and
especially mathematical skills. See Table 9.4.
This causes concern about the productivity of the
future workforce - Increased educational investments increase worker
productivity and such investments enhance the
earnings potential
39Is Education a good social investment?
- It is also believed the education serves as a
signal of worker productivity - An employer seeking workers is never completely
sure of the actual productivity of the applicant
and an learn about it only after a certain period
of time has elapsed - Some indicators such as age are immutable
- Others like education are acquired
40 The signaling model
- There are two types of applicants - one a high
type with productivity 2 (with wage 2) and a low
type with productivity 1 (with wage 1) and
these productivity levels are given - Employers cannot readily distinguish between the
two types but they know that the two types exist - If the employers are unable to distinguish
between the two types then they would be forced
to assume that all applicants are average that
is of type 1.5 and would offer wage 1.5
41 The signaling model
- With wages 1.5 low type workers are getting
paid more than they are worth. Firms could
increase profit if they could distinguish the two
types of workers - It turns out that using educational attainments
as a hiring standard - even if education does not
enhance productivity - is profitable to the
employer if it so happens that there is a
positive correlation between educational
attainment and worker productivity or a negative
one between the cost of education and worker
productivity
42 The signaling model
wage
2
1
e
Years of education beyond high school
43 The signaling model
- Suppose employers believe that workers with at
least e years of schooling beyond high school
are the ones with productivity of 2 while the
others have productivity of 1. - So any worker with less-then-e years of
schooling would be rejected for a job paying
greater than 1 - While workers with more-than-e would find
competition among employers driving wages upto 2
44 The signaling model
- If additional schooling does not enhance
productivity then is there any point in attaining
the cut-off level of education e ? - Yes, if the costs of acquiring additional
schooling is negatively related to productivity - If workers with education gt e earn 2 while those
with education lt e earn 1 then everyone would
get e education if it were costless to do so
45 The signaling model
- Schooling costs are different for different
individuals - in particular the psychic costs of
schooling are related inversely to ones ability - Those who learn more easily can acquire the
educational signal more cheaply - If those who have lower costs of acquiring
education are also those who have higher
productivity then requiring educational signals
can be useful for employers
46 The signaling model
C (Educational cost of less prod worker)
PV of earnings
B
PV2
D
C/2 (Educational cost of more prod worker
A
PV1
F
e
O
Years of education beyond high school
47 The signaling model
- Figure 9.8 is similar to 9.7 except we have
replaced wage with Present Value of Lifetime
Earnings - For a low type worker each year of education
costs C while for the high type it costs 0.5C - Workers will now choose the level of education to
maximize the difference between lifetime earnings
and costs
48 The signaling model
- For low productivity workers with cost C. the
difference is maximized at 0 years of schooling
beyond high school - For these workers the net benefit of e years of
schooling beyond high school (given by distance
BD on the graph) is less than the benefit of
zero years of schooling beyond high school (shown
by the distance AO on the graph)
49 The signaling model
- For high productivity workers with cost of C/2
however the extra years of schooling beyond high
school makes sense - Their benefit from e years of schooling is given
by BF on the graph and that is greater than AO
which is the benefit from zero years of extra
schooling - Therefore only those with costs C/2 - workers of
productivity 2 - find it beneficial to invest in
the extra schooling
50Appendix 9A Cobweb model
S
wage
w1
W
w0
D1
D0
Number of engineers