Chapter Three - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 80
About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter Three

Description:

For example, suppose there are only two consumption goods Apples and Oranges, A might refer to 2 apples and 3 oranges. B might refer to 3 apples and 2 oranges. 5 ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:177
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 81
Provided by: LSAMediaS153
Category:
Tags: apples | chapter | three

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter Three


1
Chapter Three
  • Preferences

2
Preferences
  • Recall, two things are relevant in determining
    what consumers choose to purchase.
  • Budget Constraint (what they can afford)
  • Preferences over goods (what they like)

3
Rationality in Economics
  • Behavioral PostulateA decisionmaker always
    chooses its most preferred alternative from its
    set of available alternatives.
  • So to model choice we must model the decision
    makers preferences.

4
Preferences
  • We first define some notation used to describe
    preferences over two different consumption
    bundles A and B.
  • For example, suppose there are only two
    consumption goods Apples and Oranges,
  • A might refer to 2 apples and 3 oranges
  • B might refer to 3 apples and 2 oranges.

5
Preference Relations
  • Comparing two different consumption bundles, A
    and B
  • strict preference A is preferred to B ( A is
    strictly better than B).
  • weak preference A is at least as preferred as B
    ( at least as good but may be better).
  • indifference A is exactly as good as B (consumer
    is indifferent between the two alternatives).

6
Preference Relations
  • Strict preference, weak preference and
    indifference are all preference relations.
  • Particularly, they are ordinal relations i.e.
    they state only the order in which bundles are
    preferred.

7
Preference Relations
p
  • denotes strict preference so A B
    means that bundle A is preferred strictly to
    bundle B.
  • denotes indifference A B means A and B are
    equally preferred.
  • denotes weak preferenceA B means A is
    preferred at least as much as is B or A is weakly
    preferred to B.

p
8
Preference Relations-Implications
  • A B and B A imply A B.

9
Preference Relations-Implications
  • A B and B A imply A B.
  • A B and (not B A) imply A B.

p
10
Preferences Assumptions
  • In order to model decision making we make three
    assumptions about how consumers perceive
    different bundles of goods.
  • Completeness
  • Reflexivity
  • Transitivity

11
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Completeness For any two bundles A and B it is
    always possible to make the statement that either
    A B or
    B A.

12
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Completeness requires that consumers have a
    well-defined preference ordering between any two
    alternatives.
  • The consumer knows how to choose between two
    alternatives.
  • Completeness also requires an explicit statement
    that the consumer is indifferent between two
    identical bundles.

13
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Reflexivity Any bundle A is at least as good as
    itself i.e. A A.

14
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Reflexivity is implied by completeness.
  • Reflexivity requires an explicit statement that
    the consumer is indifferent between two identical
    bundles.

15
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Transitivity IfA is at least as preferred as
    B, andB is at least as preferred as C, thenA is
    at least as preferred as C i.e. A B and B
    C A C.
  • Note transitivity also requires that if

16
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • If preferences are complete, reflexive, and
    transitive, they are said to be rational.

17
Example 3.1 Preference Relations
  • Consider the group of people A, B, and C and the
    preference relation strictly taller than.
  • Is this preference relation complete, reflexive,
    and transitive?

18
Example 3.1 Preference Relations
  • Complete No, because there is not an explicit
    statement about how to rank individuals of the
    same height.
  • If people are the same height, then they cannot
    be ranked.
  • Reflexive No, because there is not an explicit
    statement about how to rank individuals of the
    same height.
  • A person cannot be strictly taller than his or
    herself.
  • Transitive Yes. If A is strictly taller than B,
    and B is strictly taller than C, then it must be
    the case that A is strictly taller than C.

19
Example 3.2 Preference Relations
  • Suppose Coach X ranks players according to
    strength, speed, and obedience.
  • If a player is better than another player in two
    of these three categories, then that player is
    preferred. Otherwise, Coach X is indifferent
    between them.
  • Player A very strong, very slow, and fairly
    obedient.
  • Player B moderately strong, very fast, and very
    disobedient.
  • Player C very weak, moderately fast, and very
    obedient.
  • Are Coach Xs preferences complete, reflexive and
    transitive?

20
Example 3.2 Preference Relations
  • Complete Yes, because Coach X will either
    strictly prefer or be indifferent between any two
    players.
  • Reflexive Yes. Reflexivity requires that a
    player be at least as good in at least two
    categories as itself, which is true.
  • Transitive No. We know that A is strictly
    preferred to B, B is strictly preferred to C, but
    C is strictly preferred to A. This violates
    transitivity.

21
Assumptions about Preference Relations
  • Although one can come up with examples that
    violate these three fundamental assumptions about
    preference relations, we will from here on out
    assume that completeness, transitivity, and
    reflexivity hold in the preferences that we model.

22
Graphical Representation of Preferences
  • We will focus on the two good case.
  • There are many possible consumption bundles
    available to a consumer.
  • We need a way of showing how consumers feel about
    these different consumption bundles relative to
    others.
  • Use Indifference Curves

23
Graphical Representation of Preferences
  • Given a particular consumption bundle, an
    indifference curve maps out all the consumption
    bundles that are equal in the eyes of the
    consumer.
  • In other words, along an indifference curve, the
    consumer is indifferent to all consumption
    bundles.

24
Indifference Curves
  • Take a reference bundle x. The set of all
    bundles equally preferred to x defines the
    indifference curve containing x
  • the set of all bundles for which the consumer is
    indifferent to x.

25
Indifference Curves
If all of these points are on the same
indifference curve, then x x x
x2
x
x
x
x1
26
Indifference Curves
  • Once we have an indifference curve, assuming that
    more of any one commodity is better, we can
    identify how consumers prefer points on the
    indifference curve to points not on the
    indifference curve.

27
Indifference Curves
x2
z x y
p
p
z
x
y
x1
28
Indifference Curves
  • Assuming that more of both goods is preferred to
    fewer, then we know that higher indifference
    curves (to the right) will be preferred to
    consumption bundles on lower indifference curves.

29
Indifference Curves
All bundles on I1 are strictly preferred to all
on I2.
x2
z
x
I1
All bundles on I2 are strictly preferred to
all on I3.
I2
y
I3
x1
30
Indifference curve
  • Define the weakly preferred set of bundle x as
    all points that are at least as good as
    consumption bundle x.
  • Define the strictly preferred set as all points
    that are strictly preferred to consumption bundle
    x.

31
Indifference Curves
Weakly preferred set to x
x2
WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to
x.
x
WP(x) includes I(x).
I(x)
x1
32
Indifference Curves
Strictly preferred set to x
x2
SP(x), the set of bundles strictly preferred
to x, does not include
I(x).
x
I(x)
x1
33
Indifference Curves
  • Indifference curves representing distinct levels
    of preference cannot cross each other.
  • If this were not true, transitivity would be
    violated.

34
Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect
Since x and y are on distinct ICs, one must be
strictly preferred. Assume that x y. From
I1, x z. From I2, z y. By transitivity, y
x. But this is violated by our original
assumption.
I2
x2
I1
x
z
y
x1
35
Drawing Indifference Curves TIP
  • Many different types of preferences can be drawn
    using indifference curves.
  • Tip on drawing an indifference curve
  • Pick an arbitrary point to be on the curve.
  • If one of the commodities increased, what would
    have to happen to the other good to keep the
    consumer equally well off?

36
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
  • For most of the class, we will focus on
    commodities that consumers like (goods), but we
    could also consider indifference curves for
    commodities that consumers dont like (bads) or
    commodities that consumers dont care about one
    way or the other (neutrals).

37
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
  • For a good, more is weakly preferred.
  • When more of at least one commodity is always
    strictly preferred, then indifference curves are
    negatively sloped.

38
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
Good 2
a negatively sloped indifference curve.
Better
Worse
Good 1
39
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
  • If less of a commodity is always preferred then
    the commodity is a bad.
  • How would an indifference curve with one good and
    one bad look?

40
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
Good 2
One good and onebad a positively
sloped indifference curve.
Better
Worse
Bad 1
41
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
  • Neutrals are commodities that the consumer
    doesnt care about one way or the other.
  • If x1 is a good and x2 is a neutral, then what do
    indifference curves look like?

42
Slopes of Indifference Curves Goods, Bads, and
Neutrals
neutral 2
One good and oneneutral a vertical
indifference curve.
Worse
Better
good 1
43
Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves
  • We now consider how to draw indifference curves
    under the following extreme cases.
  • Perfect substitutes
  • Perfect complements
  • Satiated preferences

44
Perfect Substitutes
  • If a consumer always regards units of commodities
    1 and 2 as equivalent (at least in some constant
    proportion), then the commodities are perfect
    substitutes.
  • What do these indifference curves look like?

45
Example 3.3 Perfect Substitutes
  • Consider the case when x1 and x2 are identical in
    the eyes of the consumer so that the consumer is
    willing to trade them 1 for 1.

46
Example 3.3 Perfect Substitutes
x2
Slopes are constant at - 1.
15
I2
Bundles in I2 all have a totalof 15 units and
are strictly preferred to all bundles in
I1, which have a total of only 8 units
in them.
8
I1
x1
8
15
47
Example 3.4 Perfect Substitutes
  • Suppose that Bertha consumes two goods 8 oz
    beers and 16 oz beers.
  • Bertha doesnt care what type of can she buys.
    She only cares about the total amount of beer
    that she can consume.
  • Draw a couple of indifference curves for Bertha.

48
Example 3.4 Perfect Substitutes
8oz beers
Slopes are constant at - 2. For every 16 oz beer,
she is willing to give up 2 of the 8oz
beers.
16
I2
8
I1
16 oz beers
4
8
49
Perfect Complements
  • If a consumer always consumes commodities 1 and 2
    in fixed proportion (for example one-to-one),
    then the commodities are perfect complements
  • Here goods are consumed together in a perfect
    proportion.
  • What do these indifference curves look like?

50
Example 3.5 Perfect Complements
  • Consider the case where the consumer consumes 1
    unit of commodity 1 for every unit of commodity 2
    that she consumes.
  • For example, we could think of commodity 1 as
    being right shoes and commodity 2 as being a left
    shoes.

51
Example 3.5 Perfect Complements
Left shoes
Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains5 pairs
so each is equally preferred.
45o
9
5
I1
Right shoes
5
9
52
Example 3.5 Perfect Complements
Left shoes
Since each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5
pairs, each is less preferred than the bundle
(9,9) which contains 9 pairs.
45o
9
I2
5
I1
Right shoes
5
9
53
Example 3.6 Perfect Complements
  • Jane consumes coffee and sugar in perfect
    proportion.
  • For every cup of coffee she consumes 2 spoons of
    sugar.
  • Draw a couple of indifference curves exhibiting
    these preferences.

54
Example 3.6 Perfect Complements
coffee
Slope of line connecting the kink points is .5.
For every spoon of sugar, she consumes .5 cup of
coffee.
9
I2
5
I1
sugar
18
10
55
Preferences Exhibiting Satiation
  • A bundle strictly preferred to any other, if it
    exists, is a satiation point or a bliss point.
  • For example, suppose the two goods consumed are
    chocolate cake and coke. If a consumer is really
    thirsty and hungry, then more of these two goods
    is better, but if too much is consumed then the
    consumer may become sick and worse off.
  • After the satiation point, these goods become
    bads.
  • What do indifference curves look like for
    preferences exhibiting satiation?

56
Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Satiation(bliss)point
x1
57
Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Better
Better
Satiation(bliss)point
Better
x1
58
Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Better
Better
Satiation(bliss)point
Better
x1
59
Well-Behaved Preferences Monotonic and Convex
  • A preference relation is well-behaved if it is
  • monotonic and convex.

60
Well-Behaved Preferences Monotonic
  • Monotonicity If it is true that for any two
    bundles of goods A and B, where A has at least as
    much of all goods as B and strictly more of at
    least one, that A is strictly preferred to B,
    then preferences are monotonic.
  • If monotonicity holds, the indifference curve
    will have a negative slope.

61
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • Convexity Consumers prefer a mix of goods to
    having all of one or the other

62
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • Averages of bundles are (at least weakly)
    preferred to the bundles themselves.
  • For example, take any two points on an
    indifference curve and connect them with a line.
  • If any point on this line is at least as good as
    the points on the indifference curve, preferences
    are said to be convex.

63
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • Preferences are strictly convex if all points on
    the interior of the connecting line are strictly
    above the indifference curve.
  • Preferences are weakly convex if at least one
    point on the interior of the line is equally
    preferred to points on the indifference curve.

64
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
x is strictly preferred to both x and
x. These preferences are strictly
convex. Convexity shows a preference for
diversity / a mix.
x
x2
x
x2
x
x2
x1
x1
x1
65
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • Are preferences for perfect substitutes and
    perfect complements weakly or strictly convex?
  • Both are weakly convex because one can find at
    least one point on the connecting line that is
    equally as good as the endpoints.

66
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • Another way of stating (weak) convexity is that
    the weakly preferred set is a convex set.
  • A convex set is a set where if you connect any
    two points in the set you will not leave the set.

67
Non-Convex Preferences
The mixture x is less preferred than x or
x. Also, the weakly preferred set is not
convex These preferences show a preference for
extremes. Non-convex preferences.
x2
Better
x
x2
x1
x1
68
More Non-Convex Preferences
  • Preferences that are non-convex exhibit a
    preference for extremes.
  • Consumers like to consume one or the other but
    they do not like to consume the two goods
    together at all.
  • Example ice cream and anchovies

69
More Non-Convex Preferences
The mixture xis less preferred than x or
x. The weakly preferred set is not a convex
set. These are not convex preferences.
x2
Better
x
x2
x1
x1
70
Well-Behaved Preferences Convexity
  • We can also describe a mathematical criteria for
    (strict and weak) convexity.
  • If for any constant t between 0 and 1, and any
    two points x and x on the same indifference
    curve,
  • Preferences are weakly convex if
  • tx(1-t)x is weakly preferred to x
  • Preferences are strictly convex if
  • tx(1-t)x is strictly preferred to x

71
Slopes of Indifference Curves
  • The slope of an indifference curve is called the
    marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS).
  • The MRS represents how much of x2 a consumer
    would be willing to give up in order to get a
    little more of the x1 good.
  • This is the individual consumers tradeoff not
    the market tradeoff.
  • How can a MRS be calculated?

72
Marginal Rate of Substitution
MRS at x is the slope of theindifference curve
at x. If an equation for the indifference curve
is known x2(x1). Then the MRS can be calculated
as dx2/dx1 evaluated at a particular point
.
x2
x
x1
73
EX. 3.7 Calculating MRS
  • Suppose the equation for the indifference curve
    is given by x2(x1)100/x1.
  • What is the MRS at the point (10, 10)?

74
EX. 3.7 Calculating MRS
  • dx2/dx1 -100/ (x12)
  • Evaluated at (10, 10),
  • dx2/dx1 (10,10) -100/ (100)-1
  • This implies that at this point, the consumer is
    willing to trade 1 unit of x2 in order to get 1
    unit of the x1 good for small trades.

75
MRS EX. 3.7 continued
x2
MRS at (10,10) is -1.
Slope is -1.
10
x1
10
76
Diminishing MRS
Good 2
MRS - 5
Notice that the slope gets flatter as good 1
increases.
MRS - 0.5
Good 1
77
Diminishing MRS
  • This property is sometimes called diminishing MRS
    (the MRS gets smaller as x1 goes up).
  • This comes from the interpretation of convexity
    as exhibiting a preference for diversity.
  • If there is a lot of x2 and little x1, then the
    consumer is willing to trade a lot of x2 for one
    more unit of x1.
  • On the other hand, if the consumer has very
    little x2 and a lot of x1, then the consumer is
    not willing to give up much x2 for an additional
    unit of x1.
  • For two goods, the absolute value of the MRS
    always decreases as x1 increases, if preferences
    are strictly convex.

78
MRS Ind. Curve Properties
x2
Here for these nonconvex preferences, the MRS
increases (becomes steeper) as x1 increases
MRS - 0.5
MRS - 5
x1
79
MRS Ind. Curve Properties
Here again, we do not have diminishing MRS over
all ranges of goods.
x2
MRS - 1
MRS - 0.5
MRS - 2
x1
80
MRS Ind. Curve Properties
  • Preferences exhibiting perfect substitutes have
    linear indifference curves.
  • This implies that they have a constant MRS.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com