The Solow Growth Model (Part One) - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

The Solow Growth Model (Part One)

Description:

Previous models such as the closed economy and small open economy ... Y=F(K,L) so... zY=F(zK,zL) By setting z=1/L we create a per worker function. Y/L=F(K/L,1) ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:359
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 17
Provided by: timkoc
Category:
Tags: create | growth | khigh | model | one | part | provided | solow

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The Solow Growth Model (Part One)


1
The Solow Growth Model (Part One)
  • The steady state level of capital and how savings
    affects output and economic growth.

2
Model Background
  • Previous models such as the closed economy and
    small open economy models provide a static view
    of the economy at a given point in time. The
    Solow growth model allows us a dynamic view of
    how savings affects the economy over time.

3
Building the Model goods market supply
  • We begin with a production function and assume
    constant returns. YF(K,L) so zYF(zK,zL)
  • By setting z1/L we create a per worker
    function. Y/LF(K/L,1)
  • So, output per worker is a function of capital
    per worker. We write this as, yf(k)

4
Building the Model goods market supply
  • The slope of this function is the marginal
    product of capital per worker.MPK f(k1)f(k)

Change in y
  • It tells us the change in output per worker that
    results when we increase the capital per worker
    by one.

Change in k
5
Building the Modelgoods market demand
  • We begin with per worker consumption and
    investment. (Government purchases and net exports
    are not included in the Solow model). This gives
    us the following per worker national income
    accounting identity. y cI
  • Given a savings rate (s) and a consumption rate
    (1s) we can generate a consumption function. c
    (1s)y which makes our identity, y (1s)y
    I rearranging, i sy so
    investment per worker equals savings per
    worker.

6
Steady State Equilibrium
  • The Solow model long run equilibrium occurs at
    the point where both (y) and (k) are constant.
    These are the endogenous variables in the model.
  • The exogenous variable is (s).

7
Steady State Equilibrium
  • By substituting f(k) for (y), the investment per
    worker function (i sy) becomes a function of
    capital per worker (i sf(k)).
  • To augment the model we define a depreciation
    rate (d).
  • To see the impact of investment and depreciation
    on capital we develop the following (change in
    capital) formula,?k i dk substituting
    for (i) gives us,?k sf(k) dk

8
Steady State Equilibrium
  • If our initial allocation of (k) were too high,
    (k) would decrease because depreciation exceeds
    investment.
  • If our initial allocation were too low, k would
    increase because investment exceeds depreciation.
  • At the point where both (k) and (y) are constant
    it must be the case that, ?k sf(k) dk 0
    or, sf(k) dkthis occurs at our equilibrium
    point k.
  • At k depreciation equals investment.

9
Steady State Equilibrium (getting there)
  • Suppose our initial allocation of (k1) were too
    low.

k2k1?k
k3k2?k
k4k3?k
k5k4?k

This process continues until we converge to k
k1
k2
k3
k4
k5
K2 is still too low so
K3 is still too low so
K4 is still too low so
K5 is still too low so
10
A Numerical Example
  • Starting with the Cobb-Douglas production
    function we can arrive at our per worker
    production as follows, YK1/2L1/2 dividing by
    L, Y/L(K/L)1/2 or, yk1/2
  • recall that (k) changes until, ?ksf(k)dk0
    ...i.e. until, sf(k)dk

11
A Numerical Example
  • Given s, d, and initial k, we can compute time
    paths for our variables as we approach the steady
    state.
  • Lets assume s.4, d.09, and k4.
  • To solve for equilibrium set sf(k)dk. This
    gives us .4k1/2.09k. Simplifying gives us
    k19.7531, so k19.7531.

12
A Numerical Example
  • But what it the time path toward k? To get this
    use the following algorithm for each period.
  • k4, and yk1/2 , so y2.
  • c(1s)y, and s.4, so c.6y1.2
  • isy, so i.8
  • dk .094.36
  • ?ksydk so ?k.8.36.44
  • so k4.444.44 for the next period.

13
A Numerical Example
  • Repeating the process gives

period k y c i dk ?k
1 4 2 1.2 .8 .36 .44
2 4.44 2.107... 1.264... .842 .399 .443
. . . . . . .
10 8.343... 2.888... 1.689... 1.126... .713 .412
. . . . . . .
8 19.75... 4.44 2.667... 1.777... 1.777... 0.000...
14
A Numerical Example
  • Graphing our results in Mathematica gives us,

15
Changing the exogenous variable - savings
  • We know that steady state is at the point where
    sf(k)dk

sf(k)dk
sf(k)
  • What happens if we increase savings?
  • This would increase the slope of our investment
    function and cause the function to shift up.

k
  • This would lead to a higher steady state level of
    capital.
  • Similarly a lower savings rate leads to a lower
    steady state level of capital.

16
Conclusion
  • The Solow Growth model is a dynamic model that
    allows us to see how our endogenous variables
    capital per worker and output per worker are
    affected by the exogenous variable savings. We
    also see how parameters such as depreciation
    enter the model, and finally the effects that
    initial capital allocations have on the time
    paths toward equilibrium.
  • In the next section we augment this model to
    include changes in other exogenous variables
    population and technological growth.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com