Title: SOSC 102U
1SOSC 102U
- Lecture Note 3
- Gendered Work in Time and Place
2The Sexual Division of Labor in Preindustrial
Europe (1)
- Agricultural Work
- Mens work plow, threshed, harvest, build
houses, hew timer, harrow, dug ditch, and cut
hedges - Womens work weed, harvest, raise domestic
animals (milk, churn butter, make cheese and
butcher these animals), make bread, beer, cloth
and clothing. - Manufacturing Work
- Men in manufacturing substantially earned more
than women and enjoyed more autonomy. - Womens workshops most female labor in these
workhouses were slaves of nobility or the
monasteries or the wives and children of slaves.
Others were serfs or prisons. They received their
board and room in exchange for their labor. These
womens workshops became extinct before
industrialization. - Artisans almost all artisans were men. They
earned an income from the products they made and
sold.
3The Sexual Division of Labor in Preindustrial
Europe (2)
- Cottage industry (or putting-out system) before
industrialization, women and children
manufactured some goods at home through a system
of cottage industry.
Source Cited from Gerhard Lenski, Jean Lenski,
Patrick Nolan, Human Societies An Introduction
to Macrosociology (New York McGraw-Hill, 1991),
p. 228.
4The Industrial Revolution
- Major impact on the sexual division of labor the
changing economic role of a householdFamily
production was replaced by market production in
which capitalists paid workers wages to produce
goods in factories and mines. - Labor force people work for pay or actively
seek paid work - 1. Wage workers
- 2. Unemployed persons
- 3. Nonemployed not privileged classes who can be
exempt from productive work but a growing group
of unpaid workers. They cooked and cleaned for
family members, raised children, cared for sick
relatives, and provided social and emotional
support to family, friends and community. - The distinction between paid work in the labor
market and unpaid domestic work by the
nonemployed has important consequences for
gender inequality, because for the past 200
years, men have been more likely than women to
belong to the labor force, and women have been
more likely than men to be unpaid workers
(Padavic and Reskin, p. 20)
5Textiles Works in Halstead, England, 1825
- Based on Carol Adams, Paula Bartley, Judy Lown,
Cathy Loxton, Under Control Life in a
Nineteenth-century Silk Factory (Cambridge
University Press, 1983) - Case study in Samuel Courtaulds silk mill in
1825, Halstead, Essex (Southeast England) - Compare the wages for mens jobs compared with
the pay for the womens jobs (p. 17)
6Wages of Male Workers in Courtauld
7Wages of Female Workers in Courtauld
8The Sexual Division of Labor between Paid and
Unpaid Work (1)
- The labor force became increasingly male
throughout the nineteenth century (the
masculinization of labor force) - Urbanization and the fall of womens labor force
- Statistics in the U. S.
- 1840 40 industrial workforce was contributed by
women and children - 1890 only 17 of women was in the labor force
- Protective labor laws institutionalize the
masculinization of labor force
9The Sexual Division of Labor between Paid and
Unpaid Work (2)
- The interplay between gender and class
inequality - Upper and middle-class family The Ideology of
Separate Spheres Workplace vs. Family Life - But labor force participation was a necessity for
the poor and working-class women. The ideology of
separate spheres hurt working-class wives, whose
families need to be supported by double incomes.
Many working-class women therefore took up the
work such as doing piecework or taking in
laundry, sewing, or boarders to earn money at
home. The work usually has lower pay and longer
working hour than a real job. - The ideology changed after the 1970s, when the
gap between mens and womens labor force
participation rates narrowed considerably.
10Question
- According to Padavic and Reskin, womens
participation in unpaid domestic work (the
nonemployed work) has serious consequence to
gender inequality, would their status be improved
by increasing their contribution to household
income?
11Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(1)
- Based on Kathy L. M. Walker, Economic Growth,
Peasant Marginalization, and the Sexual Division
of Labor in Early Twentieth Century China
Womens Work in Nantong County, Modern China,
Vol. 19, No. 3 (July, 1993), 354-386. - Nantong, a county in northwestern Shanghai.
- 15th.early 19th.centuries
- The sexual division of labor in Nantong men
till, women weave.
Raw cotton
Yarn
Cotton Cloth
spin
weave
Mens work
Womens work
Sexual division of labor within a peasants
household (the Nantong case, 16th. C.-19th. C.)
12Figures of the men till, the women weave (????)
in China
Wearing blue kerchiefs, women are busy with
weaving,Cotton balls burst and they start to
pick cotton,At market, the cotton cloth they
have woven is very popular,Their products are
well-respected, so are their customs.--Gu Lan
Miao (preliminary translation by Jane Zhang)
Francesca Bray, Technology and Gender Fabrics of
Power in Late Imperial China (Berkeley,
University of California Press, 1997), p. 220.
http//www.ucalgary.ca/library/SpecColl/Chinese/pa
ge31.html
13Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(2)
- Economic significance Womens cotton production
geared the overall economic growth in China
cloth made in the Yangzi Delta district became
the leader of cloth production in the country.
These products were sold in northern, southern
and inland market. - Impact on womens status Womens production for
the market became crucial to family maintenance.
However, womens new profitability did not
improve their position in the family. The income
they generated was controlled not by the women
themselves, but by the family head (the father,
the husband or the father-in-law)
14Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(3)
- After the Opium War (1840s) the introduction of
inexpensive foreign imported machine-spun yarn
made peasant households could weave more cloth.
But the foreign yarn changed the production
process of cotton cloth. - 1. For weaving peasant families adoption of
machine yarn deepened their market dependency.
Previously the wove the cotton grew locally, now
they had to sell raw cotton formerly used for
spinning to obtain the cash necessary to buy
yarn. Peasants with insufficient land to provide
(through the sale of harvested crops) for yarn
purchase and for the expense of loom could not
afford to weave. If they really wanted to weave,
they had to obtain yarn on credit at usurious
rates. - 2. For merchants they could control raw
materials and marketing. Merchants gained new
leverage in determining both terms of trade and
the type of cloth produced. These changes marked
the beginning of a series of developments through
which over the next decade Nantongs
merchant-industrial elite gained growing control
over the forms and conditions of peasant
production without undertaking its direct
supervision.
15Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(4)
Womens work
Men and womens work
These changes resulted from 1) expansion of rural
industry 2) growth of the cotton trade 3) new
modes of obtaining the rural surplus through the
operation of usury-merchant capital. Also because
the merchants could determine the terms and
conditions of trade, they offered cloth producers
with less than subsistence wage-equivalents. The
peasants therefore had to make ends meet by
incomes from both farming and weaving.
16Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(5)
- Impact on sexual division of labor new pattern
of sexual division of labor between men and women
from the early 20th. Century - Women farmed and wove, while men moved into
various forms of permanent, seasonal, or
part-time wage work. When at home, if possible,
the busiest farm seasons, men also engaged in
farming and weaving. The change was a new method
and strategy to forestall further land division
so that cloth production and family subsistence
could be maintained.
17Sexual Division of Labor in Late Imperial China
(6)
- Was Nantong womens status improved?
- Despite the changes in their labor roles, women
remained under the control of male family members
and, by extension, the supervision of
mothers-in-law who owed their position and
primary allegiance to husbands and son. Even when
womens work became the mainstay of family
subsistence, it was in major respects invisible
since men controlled the marketing of the
commodities and the income women generated. - Related, the worst abuse of the family
systemfemale infanticide, child marriage,
contract prostitution, and the buying and selling
of womennot only continued but in fact may have
been on the rise.
18The Women Issues in Developing Countries Today (1)
- 1. As western countries, those who are expected
to do the unpaid domestic work in their homes are
predominantly women - 2. From the 1970s, womens participation in the
labor force has been increasing. Most of the
growth has been in the informal sector of the
economy where income, benefits, and job security
are precarious - 3. Womens work is less valued than mens work.
Womens work is paid less than mens. Those doing
unpaid domestic work receive lower prestige and
power.
19The Women Issues in Developing Countries (2)
- Informal Sector work under family business or
family farms self-employed work sub-contracting
piece-work (paid by productivity but not by
wageno guaranteed minimum income) - Three-quarters of all workers in Africa and Asia
and almost one-half of workers in Latin American
are working in informal sector. - Globalization mobile capita investment from
country to country MNCs Deregulation of state
policies migrant workers