Outline of Lecture on Health Insurance

1 / 73
About This Presentation
Title:

Outline of Lecture on Health Insurance

Description:

MICHAEL ROTHSCHILD AND JOSEPH STIGLITZ. QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS ... As Phelps states in his textbook, 'If the loading fee = 0, the premium just ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:164
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 74
Provided by: Wol6

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Outline of Lecture on Health Insurance


1
Outline of Lecture on Health Insurance
  • Overview of trends in coverage
  • Built upon aversion to risk
  • Core analysis for risk averter
  • Modifications to core model
  • Risk neutral/risk taker
  • Stop-loss Analysis of all or nothing, income
    based public coverage
  • Change in quality
  • Moral Hazard
  • Nearly certain demand
  • Role of taxes
  • Why insurance companies have loading fees
  • Role of Deductible, co-pays and co-insurance
  • Alternative View John Nyman
  • Tax subsidy analysis
  • Why employer based-common explanations
  • A model explaining why firms offer coverage
  • Various Applications
  • Price sensitivity of Demand for insurance or to
    what extent has the recent increase in medical
    care expenditures and premiums led to a decrease
    in coverage--empirical studies
  • Difficulty in measuring price of insurance

2
(No Transcript)
3
(No Transcript)
4
(No Transcript)
5
(No Transcript)
6
(No Transcript)
7
(No Transcript)
8
Characteristics of those insured and not insured
by education
9
(No Transcript)
10
(No Transcript)
11
(No Transcript)
12
(No Transcript)
13
(No Transcript)
14
(No Transcript)
15
(No Transcript)
16
(No Transcript)
17
(No Transcript)
18
(No Transcript)
19
(No Transcript)
20
Model of Demand for Health Insurance
BackgroundExpectation fair value
  • Take money prizes, or a lotttery and form their
    expectation.
  • Fair values are expected values.
  • Think of the actuarial value as equal to the
    expected cost of a loss times the probability of
    that loss.

21
Utility as a function of income
100
95
100
86
73
50
0
0
100
Y
22
2/3
4M
Expected value 3M
1M
1/3
100
95
100
86
73
80
80
Expected utility 80
50
0
0
0
1
2
3
4
5
2.538
Certainty equivalent wealth 2.538
23
Expected utility an example u(w) ln(w)
  • Expected utility .924
  • Certainty equivalent solveln(CE).924
  • Certainty equivalent 2.519M

24
Expected utility an alternative preference
structureu(w) w.5
  • Expected utility 1.666675/3
  • Certainty equivalent solveu(CE)5/3 CE.5
    5/3
  • Certainty equivalent 25/9 2.7777

25
Key concept
  • Value (utility) depends upon preferences.
  • If marginal utility falls as wealth rises, the
    consumer is averse to risk.

26
Arrow-Pratt measure An attribute of a utility
function. Risk Aversion Denote a utility
function by u(c). The Arrow-Pratt measure of
absolute risk aversion is defined
by RA-u''(y)/u'(y) This is a measure of the
curvature of the utility function. This measure
is invariant to affine (affine adjective,
describing a function with a constant slope.)
transformation of the utility function, which is
a useful attributed because such transformation
do not affect the preferences expressed by
u(). If RA() is decreasing in y, then u()
displays decreasing absolute risk aversion. If
RA() is increasing in y, then u() displays
increasing absolute risk aversion. If RA() is
constant with respect to changes in y, then u()
displays constant absolute risk aversion.
27
E(U) 86 with insurance
100
95
UTIL
86
73
80
80
Expected utility 80 without insurance
50
E(L)
0
0
1 YL
2
3
4 Ya
Y/W
2.538
Risk premium Max .462
28
Modifications to basic model of demand for
insurance
  • Risk taker or risk neutral
  • Stop-loss insurance (Medicaid as example)
  • Role of taxes
  • Increase in cost of medical care and quality
  • Moral Hazard
  • Nearly certain demand (dental care, eye exam,
    etc.)
  • Move to board for these examples.

29
EQUILIBRIUM IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS AN
ESSAY ON THE ECONOMICS OF IMPERFECT INFORMATION
MICHAEL ROTHSCHILD AND JOSEPH STIGLITZ
QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Best known
classic article in field of economics of
insurance coverage
30
Consider an individual who will have an income of
size W if he is lucky enough to avoid accident.
In the event an accident occurs, his income
will be only W - d. The individual can insure
himself against this accident by paying to an
insurance company a premium a1, in return for
which he will be paid ?2 if an accident occurs.
Without insurance his income in the two states,
"accident," "no accident," was (W, W - d) with
insurance it is now (W - ai, W - d a2), where
a2 ?2 a1. The vector a (a1, a 2)
completely describes the insurance contract.
31
On an insurance market, insurance contracts (the
a's) are traded. To describe how the market
works, it is necessary to describe the supply
and demand functions of the participants in the
market. There are only two kinds of
participants, individuals who buy insurance and
companies that sell it. Determining individual
demand for insurance contracts is
straightforward. An individual purchases an
insurance contract so as to alter his pattern of
income across states of nature. Let W1 denote
his income if there is no accident and W2 his
income if an accident occurs the expected
utility theorem states that under relatively
mild assumptions preferences for income in these
two states of nature are described by a function
of the form, (1) V(P, W1, W2) (1
p)U(W1) pU(W2). where U( represents the
utility of money income and p the probability
of an accident. Individual demands may be
derived from (1). A contract a is worth V (p, a
) V(p, W - ai, W - d a2). Individuals select
from all possible insurance contracts the one
that maximizes V (p, a ). An individual will
never purchase a contract that makes him worse
off than without any insurance contract.
32
Supply of Insurance Contracts
  • How do insurance companies decide which
    contracts they should offer for sale and to which
    people?
  • The return from an insurance contract is a
    random variable. Assume that companies are
    risk-neutral, that they are concerned only with
    expected profits, so that contract a when sold to
    an individual who has a probability of incurring
    an accident of p, is worth
  • (2) ?(p, ) (1 - p) a1 - p a2 ai - p(a1
    a2).
  • Even if firms are not expected profit maximizers,
    on a well-organized competitive market they are
    likely to behave as if they maximize (2).
  • Insurance companies have financial resources such
    that they are willing and able to sell any
    number of contracts that they think will make an
    expected profit. The market is competitive in
    that there is free entry. Together these
    assumptions guarantee that any contract that is
    demanded and that is expected to be profitable
    will be supplied.

33
Equilibrium in a competitive insurance market
is a set of contracts such that, when customers
choose contracts to maximize expected utility,
(i) no contract in the equilibrium set makes
negative expected profits and (ii) there is no
contract outside the equilibrium set that, if
offered, will make a nonnegative profit. This
notion of equilibrium is of the Cournot-Nash
type each firm assumes that the contracts its
competitors offer are independent of its own
actions. However, when customers have different
accident probabilities, insurance companies have
imperfect information. They wish to learn about
this prior to selling them insurance.
34
  • Linking the Contingent Claims and Expected
    Utility Approaches to Choice under Uncertainty
  • Consider an individual who derives utility from
    consumption in two possible states of nature. In
    the bad state of nature there is an accident,
    which occurs with probability ?B. Let
  • cB consumption in the bad state of nature
    (i.e., if the accident occurs)
  • cG consumption in the good state of nature
    (i.e., if the accident does not occur)
  • W the initial endowment of wealth
  • A the amount of the accident
  • K the amount of insurance coverage
  • ? the price per dollar of insurance (i.e., the
    premium).
  • The preferences for the consumer are represented
    with a Von Neuman-Morgenstern utility function
  • u(cB , cG ?B ,1-?B ) ?B cB? (1-?B) cG?. The
    usual expected utility diagram is shown in the
    upper quadrant of figure one. Figure one is drawn
    for parameter values ?B 0.25, ? 0.35, ?
    0.4.

35
(No Transcript)
36
John Nyman Why do people purchase health
insurance? Many economists would answer that it
permits purchasers to avoid risk of financial
loss. This note suggests that health insurance
is also demanded because it represents a
mechanism for gaining access to health care that
would otherwise be unaffordable. For example,
although a US300,000 procedure is unaffordable
to a person with US50,000 in net worth, access
is possible through insurance because the annual
premium is only a fraction of the procedure's
cost. The value of insurance for coverage of
unaffordable care is derived from the value of
the medical care that insurance makes
accessible consumer surplus from the health care
services that would otherwise be inaccessible.
This value may be large, especially if the
procedure that insurance made possible were
life-saving. In this model, consumers derive
utility from disposable wealth w and health H. H
is a function of Medical care M and utility
derived from w and M may differ by your health
state. U ui (w, M) where I is healthy or
sick. Uw) and uww
37
Nyman continuedConsider an illness where
the standard treatment protocol's cost, M,
exceeds endowed wealth, W. For example, a
consumer might have US50,000 in net worth from
all sources and be considering the purchase of
insurance coverage for a liver transplant that
costs US300,000 for the entire treatment
protocol. If diagnosed, there might be no time or
ability to save the extra amount out of income,
and lending institutions are unlikely to write a
US250,000 (the difference between the cost of
the procedure and what the patient is able to
raise by selling all his assets) uncollateralized
loan because of the riskiness of the procedure
and possibility that the loan will not be repaid.
For health care purchases like this, there might
be no private mechanism for gaining access to
this procedure if ill, save for already having
purchased health insurance coverage.An
individuals gain from insurance is access to M
expenditures of medical care is ill at a cost of
the premium p. Insurance allows individuals
access to care they could otherwise not afford.
38
Current tax laws
Under current tax law, health insurance premiums
are largely tax exempt if the insurance is
provided through an employer but generally are
not deductible when a person purchases insurance
directly. The share of the premium paid by the
employer is not counted as income to workers and
retirees under the federal income and Social
Security payroll taxes. The employees share of
the premium also can be tax-exempt in firms with
flexible spending plans (such as Section 125
cafeteria plans). Out-of-pocket health spending
in excess of 7.5 percent of adjusted gross income
is tax-deductible for all individuals. Also, many
employees have access to a reimbursement account
under their employers flexible spending plan,
through which out-of-pocket health costs can be
paid in pretax dollars.
39
Cost to Government of subsidies to health
insurance via the tax system tax expenditures
40
Value to consumer of tax subsidy by family income
level
41
Equity (lack thereof) of Tax Subsidy
42
Modifications of tax subsidy
  • For some forms of medical care, tax subsidy is
    really a direct subsidy that reduces the price of
    care
  • Dental care
  • Eye care
  • Form of subsidy means that high income families
    receive the largest subsidies.
  • Possible reform
  • Only cover expenditures that are high risk and
    unlikelydisallow coverage of routine care

43
Modifications of tax subsidy -2
  • Regressive nature of subsidy
  • Set maximum premium subject to subsidy
  • Set uniform subsidy rate
  • Set uniform subsidy rate and make it refundable
  • Set uniform rate but with an income/asset test so
    it is reduced as income increases (income/asset
    test)
  • Combine income/asset test with refundable credit
    and set maximum premium that is eligible for
    subsidy

44
Why employer based-common explanations
  • Economies of scale re administration
  • Pool of risk large firms minimize risk for
    insurer or company if self insure.

45
Introduction to model of why firms offer coverage
  • If employees value health insurance, employers
    should be able to reduce cash compensation in
    return for providing insurance. Pauly (1997)
    refers to offering of health insurance to reduce
    the total cost of compensation as the economic
    theory of ESI.
  • Definitions.
  • Potential surplus the difference between
    employee valuation
  • of ESI and the total cost to the employer of
    covering employees of that type.
  • If potential surplus is positive, the best the
    employer could do would be to capture the entire
    potential surplus by holding cash wages at the
    point where the employee is indifferent between
    cash only compensation and compensation with
    health benefits.
  • Extractable surplus the portion of potential
    surplus that the firm can actually obtain to
    reduce its cost of compensation.
  • the size of the extractable surplus depends on
  • the size of the potential surplus (and hence on
    factors such as the marginal tax rate of each
    worker, expected medical expenses and the
    difference in the cost of an individual private
    policy
  • and a comparable employer-sponsored policy).

46
Why do firms offer insurance?Traditional view
keep employees (stability of work force). Here
is an alternativedecrease cost of labor.
Starting point is equilibrium without insurance
47
ROLE OF TAX SUBSIDY IN IMPROVING OPPORTUNITIES
FOR FIRM TO INCREASE PROFITS
  • Under tax-exclusion, an employees own
    expenditure of x/(1t) purchases coverage
    equivalent to an employers expenditure of x, so
    that potential surplus increases by x/(1t)x
    (t/(1t))x (where t represents an appropriate
    aggregation of federal, state and payroll taxes).
  • Ex. Of 30 MTR
  • Premium for policy is 6000 per year. Load factor
    is 10 so total premium 6,600. If employee
    paid the 6,600 as wage, would have only 4,620
    to spend. (tax .36,600). To buy this plan,
    employee have to add 1980 in other income to
    this increase in pay or buy less expensive
    policy. Tax subsidy here is 1980. Under most
    circumstances this means the employee buys the
    policy below the actuarially fair value.
  • The effective price of this insurance policy to
    the employee, taking the load as the price, is
    negative! (L - .3 TP) or (600- .36600)
    (600-1980 -1380).
  • Add in Social Security and state and local taxes
    adds to the subsidy in the same manner.
  • Implication one factor influences potential
    gain to firm is family income of workers. Bigger
    potential gain when have high wage employees.

48
Firms with low wage workers have less opportunity
to profit from offering insurance the minimum
wage presents a floor below which firmscannot
trade implicit wage reductions for insurance
premiums.
49
Allowing worker valuations of coverage to differ
Offer two different packages a and b to maximize
potential profit
50
Adverse selection a leftward shift in the firms
break-eveniso-cost line E0, where the amount of
the shift equals the PV of future premium
increases incurred by insuring high cost
employees.
51
Modifications to basic model of why firms offer
coverage
  • Value to employees
  • Taxes
  • Possibility of spousal based coverage
  • Multiple types of employees

52
Other factors influence profitability of offering
coverage
  • Health of workers expenditures on medical care
  • Cost of coverage
  • Tax subsidy
  • Composition of work force wage level,
    willingness to pay, if have another worker in
    facmily

53
How are premiums determined?
  • Fully insured plans determine their premiums
    based upon the sum of expected medical costs or
    claims, margin or reserve for higher than
    anticipated costs, expected expenses (i.e.,
    administration), and profit/contribution to
    surplus funds. Expected claims are determined
    using the past experience of the insurers group
    insurance business(particularly for employers of
    a similar type), the past experience of the group
    itself, and data from inter-company studies.22
    This means that employers with above average
    claims experience in the past (those with sicker
    enrollees) and those employers of a type (e.g.,
    industry, size) that tend to have above average
    costs will face higher premiums. Because of
    uncertainty about claims costs, insurers also
    include a protective
  • financial margin in the premium rate. This margin
    will vary with the size of the
  • employer, since average claims for large groups
    are considerably more consistent over
  • time than are the average claims of small groups.
    The expense/administration charge is
  • generally calculated as a share of premiums, and
    decreases as a percentage as the size of
  • the group increases, reflecting real economies of
    scale.

54
Why do premiums increase?
  • More medical care use
  • Increase in price of care
  • Improvement in quality (technology change)
  • Poor performance of insurance companys
    investments
  • Increase in administrative costs
  • Adverse selection

55
Why the recent decrease in private coverage?
  • Possibilities firms less likely to offer fewer
    workers eligible firms pass more of cost on to
    employee (line shifts to left) firms try to
    discourage take-up.
  • Cost of health coverage up
  • Cutler Take-up ratei ß0 ß1 Employee Costi
    ß2 Premiumi Xi ß ei

56
(No Transcript)
57
(No Transcript)
58
(No Transcript)
59
Cutlers findings
60
(No Transcript)
61
Does racial composition play a role?
62
Has composition of employment by firm size
changed?
63
What those eligible report re not taking up
coverage
64
Competing for spouses firm to provide coverage
  • Dranove et al 2002 JHE argue that these patterns
    of health insurance contributions may be driven,
    at least in part, by the presence of two-career
    couples and employer competition to be the
    employer not chosen for insurance. They present
    a model in which
  • competitive forces lead employers to raise
    contributions to encourage their workers to
    switch plans and obtain insurance from their
    spouses employers instead.
  • They attempt to model a choice by firms that the
    equilibrium required employee contribution is
    sensitive to several critical
  • Factors
  • the cost of insurance,
  • the percentage of two-career couples,
  • The income tax rate,
  • the heterogeneity of plans and employee
    preferences
  • In their model, firms are symmetrical and all
    workers are married.
  • If there is only one worker, and the MTR is
    substantial, firms will prefer to directly pay
    for the full cost of the premium (Vanness-Wolfe
    model explains why this is preferred.)
  • The higher the MTR, the higher the proportion the
    firm pays
  • The higher the proportion of workers with a
    working spouse, the higher the required premium
    contribution.
  • Predictions consistent with generally observed
    facts employees asked to pay higher share there
    are more spouses working and the MTR are lower.

65
Empirical Studies
  • Families with single worker
  • Feldman et al (1989) 3,000 employees in 17 firms
    in Minneopolis nested logit model.
  • Price elasticities of -.53 to -.15
  • Royalty and Solomon(1999) university employees
  • own price elasticities of -.96 to 1.75
  • Buchmueller and Feldstien (1996) university
    employees.
  • If monthly premium increases by 10, 26 of
    health plan enrollees switch to lower prices
    plan.
  • Bottom line employees on average are price
    sensitive with respect to choice of plans.
  • Families with two workers and choice of plan
  • Blumberg et al (2002) 1996 MEPS data.
  • Individual worker less likely to take up coverage
    if spouse also offered coverage at work.
  • Small price elasticity -.09 to -.01
  • Dranove, et al (2000)1993 RWJF employer health
    insurance survey.
  • Model predicts that firms will try to encourage
    employees to take up coverage with spouses
    employer. Firms with more employees with two
    sources of coverage will be less generous.
  • Findings employee required contributions higher
    when more employees have working spouses. Also
    firms with higher costs of coverage have much
    higher required contributions.

66
  • Institutional Options for ESI 1
  • An employer interested in sponsoring a health
    insurance plan for its workers and their
    dependents has a number of options.
  • The first is fully insured products for single
    employers (as distinguished from contracts
    written for groups of employers). This option
    represents the purchase of an employment-based
    group health insurance policy from a licensed,
    risk-bearing carrier.
  • Blue Cross Blue Shield , commercial, and health
    maintenance organizations (HMO).
  • Within these types, various products are made
    available, including indemnity plans, HMOs,
    preferred provider organizations (PPO), and
    point-of-service (POS) options for HMO products.
  • Fully insured plans are subject to state
    regulation in addition to some federal regulation
    (notably, the Health Insurance Portability and
    Accountability Act (HIPAA) of 1996).

67
Institutional Options for ESI 2
  • The second type of insurance option facing
    employers is to insure themselves or
  • what is sometimes called "singly" self-insure.
  • Firms can establish reserves and manage their own
    cash flow in such a way as to insure or
  • indemnify their own workers against most
    health-related expenses.
  • Federal law, the Employee Retirement Insurance
    Security Act (ERISA 1974), exempts employers from
    state insurance regulations as long as they are
    providing self-funded health insurance
    arrangements for their own workers. Self-insured
    employers are not exempt from the
  • federal HIPAA law.
  • ..

68
Institutional Options for ESI 3
  • The third broad category of insurance options are
    those which allow multiple employers to enter
    into insurance arrangements together.
  • These options include Multiple Employer Welfare
    Arrangements (MEWAs), multi-employer plans
    (Taft-Hartley plans), business coalitions, and
    health insurance purchasing cooperatives.
  • A MEWA is an insurance arrangement that offers
    benefits to the workers of more than one
    employer.
  • A MEWA represents an agreement among employers
    alone it is not collectively bargained by
    workers representatives and multiple employers

69
  • PREMIUM SUBSIDIES HAVE SMALL EFFECT ON
    COVERAGEFederal employees gained the ability to
    pay health insurance premiums with pre-tax
    dollars, with the subsidy extended to postal
    employees in 1994 and then to remaining employees
    in 2001. A study by Jonathan Gruber and Ebonya
    Washington, takes advantage of this natural
    experiment to estimate the effects of premium
    subsidies on coverage rates among federal
    employees.
  • FINDINGSSmall Effects of Premium Subsidies on
    CoverageWorker responses to the subsidy suggest
    an elasticity of take up with respect to premiums
    of roughly 0.02, similar in scale but lower than
    the response found in other studies.
  • For family coverage, the regression coefficient
    implies that each 10 percent of premium the
    employee bears makes the employee 0.68 percent
    less likely to take up insurance. Employees pay
    roughly 20 percent of premium mean family take
    up was 61.5 percent. The arc elasticity of price
    with respect to premium over the range 0 to 20
    percent is thus -.022.
  • Large Effects of Premium Subsidies on
    CostsSimulations of the effect of the policy
    change on the number insured show the number of
    newly insured persons ranging from 8,261 to
    17,954. The range reflects assumptions about what
    share of newly insured were previously uninsured
    (50 percent at the low end 100 percent at the
    high end.) Total costs are 693 million, of which
    647 million represents the revenue loss
    associated with allowing employees to pay
    premiums with pre-tax dollars, resulting in
    yearly costs per newly-insured person that range
    from 31,000 to 83,000.
  • Small Effects of Premium Subsidies on Choice of
    Health Plan In contrast to previous work,
    federal employees appear less likely to switch
    health plans in response to a change in the
    employee share of premium. Such choices lead
    employees to offset only about 2.5 of the
    additional premiums.
  • POLICY IMPLICATIONS This paper suggests that tax
    credits will not be very effective at increasing
    coverage rates among the uninsured who work for
    firms that offer coverage, and may be very costly
    to the federal government.

70
(No Transcript)
71
Issues with empirical work in this area
  • One of the key variables in determining coverage
    is the price of insurance.However defining and
    measuring that price is not straightforward.Conce
    ptual Issues How to deal with the large set of
    options heterogeneity in insurance products.
    In a full structural demand system, employers
    and employees would face a myriad of prices for a
    large number of potential products. Included
    would be publicly subsidized products. Employers
    may perceive (and act on) a set of prices that
    differs from the set relevant to employees.
    Identifying the right choice set for individuals
    is complicated. Another issues is the extent
    to which health insurance benefits influence
    worker selection into firms If so, the set of
    health plans in an individuals choice set may
    reflect all plans in the market (assuming the
    individual can select the firm with his preferred
    plan) or only those plans offered by his employer
    if no job sorting is assumed. The choice set
    should also reflect options for coverage through
    ones spouse.Should one use the full premium?
    or employee (or employer) share or some
    combination of the two as the relevant price
    measure? Depends on what one assumes about the
    extent to which health care premiums are shifted
    to groups of workers or to individual workers.

72
Another alternative the premium
  • One possible measure of price is the premium
    itself. Unlike the load, whichexplicitly
    incorporates benefit design into the definition
    of price (because benefitsdetermine the expected
    payout), use of the premium as the price measure
    requires controlling for benefit packages.
    Essentially this is equivalent to a hedonic
    pricing approach. Much of the work on competition
    in insurance markets has used this
    approach.However, if premium variation is due
    to variation in prices or costs of medicalcare
    we would expect elasticities to differ if the
    medical care price variation is driven by
    variation in the quality of medical care, the
    elasticity may well differ from what would be
    observed if the variation in medical care were
    due to variation in market power of medical care
    providers.Finally, over time health care
    premiums have risen, largely due to new
    medicaltechnology. Very little is known about
    how rising premiums will affect coverage rates
    over time. Elasticities based cross sectional
    variation in premiums, willgenerally not provide
    appropriate measures of the elasticities of
    coverage over time.

73
Should We Measure Price at the market/ firm/ or
individual level?
  • 1. Market Level View insurance as a composite
    good and assume prices vary at the market level.
    Uses variation in the menu of prices without
    worrying about the details of the endogenous
    choice of plans or benefit packages made by firms
    or workers. Avoids issues related to the joint
    insurance decisions within families. Because the
    market price approach does not use data on the
    relative prices of different benefits packages
    and plan designs within the market, it cannot
    address questions related to which plan a firm or
    worker would purchase it may be a reasonable
    method to address the decision to purchase
    coverage vs. to not purchase coverage.

74
Should We Measure Price at the market/ firm/ or
individual level?
  • Firm level The key question of interest at the
    firm level is the sensitivity of small firms to
    premiums. The problem is the lack of observed
    premiums for firms that do not offer coverage.
  • Individual level LOAD, OUT-OF-POCKET OR PREMIUM?

75
Conceptually measuring price
  • The dominant paradigm today, reflected in widely
    used health economics textbooks, defines the
    price of insurance as the difference between the
    premium and the expected payout, commonly
    referred to as the load (Feldstein, 1999 Phelps,
    1997) The motivation for this approach reflects a
    definition of the insurance products as primarily
    afinancial instrument. Individuals pay a premium
    in exchange for an expected payout. As Phelps
    states in his textbook, If the loading fee 0,
    the premium just matches the expected benefits
    and the insurance itself would be free. In such
    a setting the relevant price for each health plan
    in an individuals choice set would be the
    loading fee.
  • This does not end the problem of empirical
    estimation as we do not directly observe the
    loading fee.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)