Title: R2
1R2
2Asset Pricing Perspective
- R-sq. is simply a measure of the performance of
the asset-pricing model used - Roll (1988)
- Perfect hindsight, Excludes firm-specific event
dates, same low R-sq. - Extensions Cornell (1990) small sample, R-sq?
when highest 200 volume days are excluded Robin
(1993) - large sample, only 30 high volume days
Brown (1999) acct. study, R-sq. ? when only
private info. - Shiller (1981) and West (1988)
- firm-specific price volatility is too large to be
associated with changes in firms fundamentals - the excess fluctuation can have different sources
such as bubbles or fads (i.e. noise) - See http//people.few.eur.nl/smant/m-economics/sh
iller.htm - Shleifer and Vishny (1997) result is consistent
noise trading causes prices to diverge from
fundamentals - Empirical evidence on R-sq. around index
additions/deletions Barberis et al. (2005)
SP500, betas ? of stocks added (investors treat
SP stocks as belonging to one category),
Greenwood (2005) Nikkei225
3Campbell et al. 2001 JF - Summary
- Simple summary of historical movements in market,
industry, and firm-level volatility - Disaggregated approach (they mean individual
stock level study) - Decomposition of volatility that does not require
the estimation of covariances or betas for
industries or firms - 1962-1997
- Increase in firm-level volatility
- Decline in correlations among stocks (R2)
- same as
- Decline in explanatory power of market model
- Higher number of stocks to achieve given
diversification - Volatility moves countercyclically
4Campbell et al. (2001) ivol?
- Conjectured explanations by Campbell et al.
- A lot more new listings in US (Brown and Kapadia
(2005)) - Earlier listings
- Breaking up conglomerates
- Exec stock options
- Betas more volatile
- NOT
- ivol? not just because CFs are now separately
traded, but also because info about those CFs is
disseminated more rapidly - HOWEVER
- better price discovery changes the timing of
information, not the quantity of information, and
thus does not change volatility! - (discounting will reduce the vol of returns since
news enters prices earlier, even if price vol
increases)
5Campbell not price discovery
- 3-period model
- Time 2 future profits X are realized
- Time 1 info arrives and expected profits are
E1X - Time 0 expected future profits are normalized
to 0 - Volatility form time 0 to time 1 is
- Var(E1X)
- Volatility form time 1 to time 2 is
- Var(X-E1X)
- Average volatility is
- Which is unaffected by the timing of info.
- More careful analysis in West (1988)
6Campbell et al. 2001 JF - Motivation
- Aggregate volatility is not constant (market
risk) - Non-aggregate volatility is important because
- Not all investors can diversify
- number of stocks to achieve diversification
depends on idiosyncratic volatility - One-stock arbitrageurs
- Calculating abnormal returns for event studies
- Pricing individual stock options
- In some macro theoretical models, aggreagate
output may be affected by changes in
industry-level vol of productivity growth, and/or
differential arrival rate of information about
management quality among firms
7Campbell et al. 2001 JF Existing empirical
evidence
- leverage effect
- the tendency for volatility to rise following
negative returns - Black (1976), Christie (1982), Duffee (1995)
- Reallocation across industries or firms
- Loungani et al. (1990), Bernard and Steigerwald
(1993), Brainard and Cutler (1993) - Effect on investment
- Leahy and Whited (1996)
- Market vol decomposed into country and industry
effects - Roll (1992) and Heston and Rouwenhorst (1994)
- Emerging markets
- Bekaert and Harvey (1997)
8Campbell et al. 2001 JF Results
- Confirm no trend in market vol using monthly
data - No trend in market and industry vol using daily
data - Firm-level vol large and significant positive
trend - All vol measures are pos corr
- Market vol tends to lead the other series
- All vol measures tend to lead recessions
- All vol measures forcast economic activity
9Campbell et al. 2001 JF Methodology
- Variance decomposition is difficult based on CAPM
(requires knowledge of firm-specific betas) - Use market-adjusted-return model as in
Campbells 1997 textbook - a restricted market model with ?i0 and ?i1
- Maybe the major criticism of this paper
10Campbell et al. 2001 JF Methodology
- Relation b/w market-adjusted-return model and
CAPM - Aggregate (4) and (5) across industries and firms
11Campbell et al. 2001 JF Methodology
- (15) and (16) show that cross-sectional variation
in betas can produce common movements in the
variance components ?mt2,??t2,??t2, even if the
CAPM variance components est.??t2 and est. ??t2
do not move at all with the market variance ?mt2
12Campbell et al. 2001 JF R2 result
equally weighted average R2 statistic of a market
model, estimated using the past 60 months of
monthly data (solid line) or the past 12 months
of daily data (dotted line). Stocks included in
the calculation at each point in time are
required to have a complete return history over
the past 60 months (solid line) or 12 months
(dotted line).
13Pro and Con Campbell et al. results
- Finance
- Wei and Zhang (2006) follow up on Campbell
(2001) - Bekaert et al. (2005) no trend in ivol across
OECD markets - Accounting
- Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2006)
- earnings quality and forecast dispersion explain
differences in firm specific idiosyncratic
volatility - temporal link between idiosyncratic volatility
and the two information quality proxies persists
14Con Morck et al. results finance, country-level
- Griffin et al. (2007) main result emerging
markets do as well or better than developed
markets at incorporating simple forms of public
information into prices - within country smaller stocks have much lower R2s
on average - consistent with Roll (1988) - no evidence that better legal, regulatory, and
governance climates are related to higher levels
of stock market efficiency - investor protection measures are ever
significantly related to R2 after controlling for
market volatility and the number of firms - longer and more recent 1994 to 2005 sample period
- Kelly (2006)
15Con Durnev et al. (2003) results firm-level
- Accounting
- Teoh, Yang and Zhang (2006) relationship b/w R2
and 4 accounting anomalies, US data - accruals, net operating assets, post-earnings
announcement drift, and V/P anomalies all reject
the information interpretation earnings response
coef. - for firms with lower R2 values, future earnings
are less correlated with current returns - Ashbaugh-Skaife et al. (2006) 6 developed
markets, cross-sectional design, show that
results are sensitive to sample selection - Alves et al. (2006) US and UK data
- Confirm declining trend in R2
- R² and its components are poorly correlated with
information-related measures such as market
value, bid-ask spread, market-to-book ratio and
analyst following - Finance
- Hou et al. (2006) R2 and momentum
- investors overreaction to their private
information can help explain the negative
relationship between R2 and assets price
informativeness.
16Support for info interpretation of ivol -
Ferreira and Leux (2007) JF
- Shows how governance provisions and informed
trading interact to influence the incorporation
of information into stock prices - The absence of anti-takeover provisions creates
incentives to collect private information, which
is a central determinant of idiosyncratic
volatility - Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) predict that
improving the cost-benefit trade-off on
information collection leads to more informed
trading and more informative pricing - To take into account the fact that limits to
arbitrage, pricing errors, and noise also
manifest in volatility, FL verify their
conclusions using other measures of information
flow - Alternative measures of private information flow
PIN, private info - IRRC dataset 1990-2001, daily data for ivol, mkt
model, FF, and industry factors model - Validity of this study is questionable if the
G-Index is not a pure anti-takeover measure - Sokolyk (2006) shows that the G-Index is not
related either to likelihood of being acquired or
the magnitude of takeover premia
17Support for info interpretation of ivol
- Qin Yafeng (2006)
- higher commonality in liquidity in emerging
markets than in developed markets - time-series analysis at individual security level
shows that individual liquidity is more affected
by market uncertainty than by individual security
idiosyncratic uncertainty, which is in contrast
to securities from developed markets - Other papers
- Core, Guay, and Rusticus (2006)
- Goyal and Santa-Clara (2003)
- Cremers and Nair (2005)
- Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2005) provide
independent evidence that idiosyncratic
volatility and PIN - Wei and Zhang (2006)
18Corporate Governance Perspective
- R-sq. contributes to understanding a countrys
information environment - Country level (R-sq. seems to perform well as an
inverse proxy of firm-specific info being
reflected in prices) - Morck et al. (2000) R-sq. ? in poor inv. prot.
countries (Art talked about their results last
time) - Li et al. (2003) extend to emerging markets,
openness - Jin and Myers (2006) opaqueness positive
relationship b/w info and ivol. - Chan and Hameed (2006) analysts greater
analyst coverage increases stock price
synchronicity (R2), i.e. analyst info has more
market-wide content - Firm-level
- Durnev at al. (2001) R-sq. captures the degree
to which share prices reflect info about
firm-specific fundamentals - Piotroski and Roulstone (2004) sophisticated
investors and R-sq., analysts and institutions
R?, insiders R?
19Lee and Liu (2006) reconcile the debate
- ivol has a information and a noise component
- In good (poor) info environment (the info
production cost is low (high)) the dominant
component of ivol is info (noise) and thus there
is a positive (negative) relationship b/w ivol
and price informativeness - US data, confirms U-shaped relationship b/w
informativeness and ivol