Title: Rethinking reputation: Group membership and trustworthiness
1Rethinking reputation Group membership and
trustworthiness
- Margaret Foddy
- Carleton University
- Ottawa, Canada
- Third CEFOM/21 International Symposium,
- Sapporo, Japan
2Outline of talk (for the tired ones)
- Review theoretical background for ingroup trust
- Summarize work on selective interaction that
results from ingroup trust - Convince you that category based trust is robust
but not necessarily strong - Consider reputation in the context of ingroup
identity, and its effect on group-based trust - Report a study on reputation (when it means, what
does x know about what y did to a person in the
ingroup/outgroup) - Speculate on possible implications across
societies, and theoretical models (especially the
role of category based trust) - Consider links to other processes such as
exclusion from groups, willingness to stay in, or
leave groups,
3BACKGROUND
- The allocator studies and trust in strangers
- Focus on unilateral trust, not cooperation
- Explored the utility of social identity and
self-categorization theory for understanding
group-based trust in strangers - Collaboration with Michael Platow, (now
Australian National University) Toshio
Yamagishi and Toko Kiyonari, Hokkaido University
4Trust expectation that an other person will
perform an action which is beneficial, or not
detrimental to us
- When we trust, we commit ourselves to an action
- agree to put ones outcomes in anothers hands
- take a cooperative action
- Make oneself vulnerable
- Before we know what the other will do
- When there is no assurance mechanism
5Trust in strangers is important in establishing
new relationships
- Whom shall we trust?
- People whose interests are aligned assurance
(encapsulated trust Hardin) - People who share category and/or group membership
with us group-based trust - People who have proven trustworthy to us, or to
others (reputation)
6(In)group heuristic?naïve theory of groups
- People believe others in their own groups will
treat them well - People do in fact show higher ingroup fairness,
are subject to principles of ingroup fairness
and trustworthiness (Yamagishi) - Ingroup trust may be a second order belief, or
one based on taking the perspective of other(s),
producing a consensus that groups can be relied
on if you are included within its boundaries
(Tyler) - The effects are relatively weakpeople trust
ingroup more, but still place trust in strangers
outside own group - (because)
- Group boundaries are relatively fluid (Brewer)
- Salience principles
- People extend and contract the boundaries of the
group this may limit the utility of group-based
trust for both theorist and actors - Interesting question is this a psychological,
sociological or economic question? (for
discussion later)
7Group identity and trust what is the
basis?Shared group membership affects
- Evaluations of ingroup members vs outgroup
(ingroup more positive? And if so, why?) Turner - Differential distribution of positive outcomes to
ingroup members Tajfel - Expectations of fairness and cooperation from
others in the group (Yamagishi) - ?Provide a categorical basis for trust in
strangers
8Experimental paradigm
- Allocator game a 2-dictator game
- Allocator has X to split between self and
recipient focus is on recipient - 2 Allocators one each from
- the persons ingroup (e.g.La Trobe Uni)
- an outgroup (e.g. Melbourne Uni)
- RECIPIENT chooses one allocator to receive money
from, and gives reasons for choice, predicts how
much each allocator would have given him or her - We assess relative, not absolute, trust, but
results are similar when third choice option of
sure thing is provided similar when there is
direct reciprocity as in the Berg game)
9Results from choose the allocator studies
- Strong preference for ingroup allocator, but not
extreme differences in expectations of positive
treatment - Preference holds for large and small ingroup
categories (in the West and East?) for intact,
minimal and categorical groups - Preference disappears if allocator does not know
of shared identity blocks group based trust - Preference for ingroup allocator even if outgroup
stereotype is more positive (even economics
students prefer ingroup (economics) allocator) - Group stereotype has weak effect on expectations
and preferences - Ingroup heuristic includes expectations of fair
treatment from fellow group members?reduces
uncertainty, forms basis for trust
10Does shared identity matter only if there is no
other information?
- What about a persons reputation?
- Is it more important than shared group
membership ?
11How has reputation been conceptualized?
- the estimation in which one is held character
in public opinion the character to attribute to
a person, thing or action repute - (plus a large literature in economics, political
science, sociology etc. indicating that there are
multiple dimensions to reputation) - Personal reputation first or second hand
knowledge of the pattern of a persons past
behavior (e.g. fair cooperative competent) - Organizational reputation as above
- Summarized in trait terms, generalized or a
record of behavior and outcomes (e.g. a
university) - reputation is owned by a person, and can be
manipulated, communicated, tested in law, etc. - Reputation reduces uncertainty can be a positive
or negative resource - Little research attention to the group contexts
in which a person establishes a reputation - Who is the relevant public?
- What mechanisms are in place to govern true and
false reputation (Toshio)
12Groups, identity and reputation
- Category vs target based reputation Reputation
developed by/attached to the group may be
transferred to individuals with no information
about the individuals behavior (e.g. nurses
used car salesmen) naïve theory says people can
be expected to act in accordance with the group
stereotype, but individuating information may
reverse the stereotype-based inference - Ta da! (Main point)
- Effects of reputation on trust depend on the
relationship between the truster and the target
of trust - Group membership may condition interpretation of
information about anothers behavior - Expect different behavior from ingroup and
outgroup members towards self - A third persons behavior towards an outgroup
member may not be informative of their likely
behavior towards an ingroup - Category based ingroup trust may
- Replace reputation
- Combine with reputation
- Be replaced by reputation
13How does reputation workin the group context?
- Reputation information may individuate the
allocator and produce attributions to traits, or
inferences about the persons values (e.g. fair
shady exploitative) - Individuating information may be regarded as more
reliable/informative than shared group membership
as basis for trust - Information about allocators behavior may block
group categorization effects block effects of
group heuristic and in-group favoring norm - Forecasting cross-cultural questions
- Is reputation information more important in the
East or the West? - Are contextual effects of the group relationship
between truster and trustee more important in
East or West/
14Or, is reputations effect on trust moderated by
the group identities of the people involved?
- Information about outgroup members treatment of
their own groups may not be informative fairness
within the outgroup does not predict fairness to
those not in it - Information about ingroup members treatment of
outgroup may not be predictive of how they will
treat ingroup members, or may confirm that
positive ingroup bias will operate for ingroup
(confirm the naïve theory about ingroup behavior)
15Experimental paradigm reputation
- Choose between ingroup (A) and outgroup (B)
- Recipient told allocators scheduled to make two
separate allocationsone to ingroup (A), one to
outgroup (B) recipient - Experimental conditions
- 1.There is reputation information about neither
allocator (baseline) - OR about what ONE allocator has given another
recipient who was - 2. From allocators ingroup
- 3. From allocators outgroup
- No reputation information about the other
allocator, who has not done second allocation
16Information about ONE allocators division of 16
in a previous trial
17Predictions
- If individual reputation is basis of choice, the
fair allocator (regardless of target) will be
preferred over the allocator with no reputation
information, regardless of group, and the
no-reputation allocator preferred to the one
who has been unfair in the past - If group membership affects the meaning of past
fair behavior, then - Past fairness within the outgroup (B?B) will not
increase choice of outgroup by A - Fairness by outgroup to ingroup in past (B?A)
will reduce ingroup preference (not a typical
intergroup situation) - Unfairness within the ingroup (A?A) will reduce
ingroup preference (allocator violates ingroup
norms)
18Frequency of choice of allocator when allocator
has been FAIR (all choosers from group A)
- Ingroup(A) Outgroup(B)
- Control 18 3
- Reputation info
- A?A 18 2
- A?B 17 4
- B?B 17 4
- B?A 6 14
19Expected of funds Allocator was FAIR
- Ingroup(A) Outgroup(B)
- Reputation info
- A?A .48 .34
- A?B .46 .38
- B?B .48 .34
- B?A .37 .42
- Note recipients made predictions for both
allocators, regardless of choice made -
20Frequency of choice of allocator when allocator
has been UNFAIR (all choosers from group A)
- Ingroup(A) Outgroup(B)
- Reputation info
- A-A 10 9
- A-B 10 10
- B-B 17 3
- B-A 17 3
- Control 18 3
21Expected of funds to new recipient Allocator
was UNFAIR
- Ingroup(A) Outgroup(B)
- !A?A .32 .28
- A?B .28 .32
- B?B .39 .18
- B?A .32 .29
-
- Overall lower expectations than in FAIR
condition - Smaller difference in expectations from A and B
- Reputation information does not undermine trust
in ingroup allocator as in ingroup allocator - (!here is an ingroup member who does not treat an
ingroup member well - (here is an outgroup person who does not treat
an ingroup member well)
22When ingroup allocator has been unfair, why do at
least half still choose ingroup?
- Recipients gave reasons for choice of allocator
- Reasons coded
- Those choosing the unfair ingroup allocator
referred to shared reciprocal obligation, common
interests and similarity as a basis for expecting
fairer treatment from ingroup compared with
outgroup - Those choosing outgroup did not refer to shared
group membership main reasons were the unfair
past behavior of the ingroup allocator
(reputation), and decision to take a gamble with
the outgroup
23Summary of results
- People do NOT prefer an outgroup allocator who
has been generous to a fellow outgroup member
(allocators ingroup), over an ingroup allocator
about whom they have no information - People DO prefer an outgroup allocator who has
been generous to a member of the persons own
ingroup (B was fair to A)attribution to
individual traits? People are evenly divided
about reputation information when - Ingroup member is unfair to the ingroup
- Ingroup member is unfair to the outgroup
-
24Conclusions 1
- Reputation is not set up in a vacuumbehavior of
a target towards others is interpreted in part in
terms of the relationships of self and the
target, and the target with others (this
information may not always be known) - Expectation of ingroup fairness is the default
option not so clear that outgroup unfairness is
the default (Brewer, 1981 Mummenday, 2000) - Reputation may help identify the prevailing group
norms, and a given actors adherence to them
clearer basis for trust or distrust - When reputation information is ambiguous, person
may apply a group, individual, or universalistic
template to interpret the information may
reflect level of self-categorization, situational
cues - We know little about the relationship between the
source of reputation information (ingroup
outgroup) and its influence on future trust of
ingroup and outgroup members
25Group-based reputation and trust the same
across cultures?
- Will simple shared category activate trust in
cultures where group implies a network of
obligation and sanction (assurance)? - Is reputation information more important in
collectivist or individualistic cultures?
Will it destroy the ingroup preference
completely? - Are the norms of ingroup favouritism the same
across cultures? - Are the effective groups the same across
cultures? Categoriesminimal groupsconnected
groupsdyads? Reputation can operate in all of
these, but may have different effects - How is reputation information conveyed? Do we
trust some informants more than others
(second-order trust may arise from shared group
membership with informants). Does it matter who
told us? (e.g. an outgroup member told me that
Toshio is not reliable will I believe this? If
an ingroup member tells me he is unreliable
(joke), I may be more willing to believe it
26Is individual reputation more important in
collectivist societies?
- The yes side
- If trust is based more on assurance and specific
relationships in collectivist societies (i.e. not
generalized trust), reputation should be more
importanttarget-based trust should dominate - Category-based trust is weaker in collectivist
societies, so reputation information will
dominate (evidence is mixed) - formal assurance systems in Western cultures may
make reputation irrelevant - Group loyalty makes universal principles of
fairness irrelevant - The no side
- Individual reputation in Western societies is
very important, and is used to make attributions
to individual as a basis for predicting future
behavior and trustworthiness the same applies to
organizations - Particularistic familism is as common in the West
as in the East - Reputation is an important part of English common
law (you can sue someone for damaging your
reputation) - E-business puts a lot of emphasis on reputation
- However, the issue of whether reputation is
interpreted in group terms has not been
systematically explored across cultures
27Why does reputation matter?
- Conditions the interpretation of behavior to
ingroups and outgroups - Forms the basis for selective interaction
- May form the basis for inclusion or exclusion of
people from groups - Affects peoples estimates of whether a common
resource is viable, and therefore willingness to
stay in a group (e.g. if all members have a
negative reputation, group will be less viable
than if all positive) - Why do ingroup effects on reputation matter?
- Double standards in judging people (more lenient
to ingroup) - Informative about naïve theory of groups
- Important to theories of group identification
- Window on cross-cultural differences in how trust
is formed, and how trustworthy behavior is
generated
28Conclusions 2
- Cultural differences in trust, the importance of
reputation, and the willingness to exclude others
from the group are not yet well-established - Minimal group effects are obtained in Japan and
China - Trust in category members occurs in both types of
culture (sometimes) - There is not a lot of information about how group
processes may differ between the East and the
West - Globalization means that the social structural
sources of differences may be disappearing - We have almost no idea how the Middle East fits
into the picture!! Is behavior in these cultures
a reflection of shared beliefs and second order
beliefs, or coercion? - We need theoretical frameworks to understand any
differences - Naïve theory of groups
- Content of cultural beliefs
- Social structural influences? incentive
structures