Title: Cost-Benefit Approach to Public Support of Private R
1Cost-Benefit Approach to Public Support of
Private RD Activity
Bettina Peters Centre for European Economic
Research (ZEW) b.peters_at_zew.de
DIMETIC Doctoral European Summer School Pecs,
July 14, 2010
2Part IIEconometrics of Evaluation of Public
Funding Programmes
3Motivation
- Public support of private RD activity is not
without cost either crowding-out may occur! - Once subsidies are available, companies have an
incentive to apply for any project (even for the
ones which are also privately profitable) as
subsidy comes at marginal cost equal to zero. - Subsidies may not only stimulate the projects
with high social return. - In the worst case (total crowding out), private
funding is simply replaced with public funding. - growing literature about evaluation of RD
programmes
4The Evaluation Problem
- The aim of quantitative methods of evaluation is
the measurement of effects generated by policy
interventions on certain target variables - We are interested in the causal effect of a
treatment 1 relative to another treatment 0 on
the outcome variable Y. - In case of public RD support
- What is the effect of an RD subsidy on the
subsidized firms RD expenses (input)? or - Or the impact on other variables like patent
applications, firm growth, employment etc.
(output)
5Different Effects of RD subsidies
Self-assessment by companies (259 subsidized
German companies in 2001)
Source Czarnitzki et al. (2001)
6The Evaluation Problem
- In most cases, we are interested in the average
treatment effect on the treated (TT) - TT the difference between the actual observed
value of the subsidzed firms and the
counterfactual situation - Which average value of RD expenditure would
the treated firms have shown if they had not
been treated
S Status of group, 1 Treatment group 0
Non-treated firms YT outcome in case of
treatment YC outcome of the treated firm in
the case it would not have received the subsidy
(counterfactual situation)
7The Evaluation Problem
- Actual outcome E(YTS 1) can be estimated by
the sample mean of Y in the group of treated
(subsidized) firms - Problem The counterfactual situation E(YCS 1)
is never observable and has to be estimated! - ? How to do estimate the counterfactual?
8The Evaluation Problem
- Naive estimator for ATT Use the average RD
expenditure of non-subsidized firms assuming that - Assumption is justified in an experiment where
subsidies are given randomly to firms. - In real life, however, it is likely that funded
firms are typically not a random sample, but are
the result of an underlying selection process - Subsidized firms differ from non-subsidized firms
- It is likely that the Subsidized firms differ
from non-subsidized firms and that the subsidized
companies would have spent more on RD than the
non-subsidized companies even without the subsidy
program.
9The Evaluation Problem
- Policy makers want to maximize the probability of
success and thus try to cherry-pick firms with
considerable RD expertise, - i.e. firms with high high RD in the past,
professional RD management, good success with
their other RD projects or experienced in
applying for public funding will be preferably
selected. - Selection bias in the estimation of the treatment
effect. - We cannot use a random sample of non-treated
without any adjustment. - As the highest expected success is correlated
with current RD spending, subsidy becomes an
endogenous variable (depending on the firms
characteristics). - Solution in non-experimental settings
Microeconometric evaluation methods (surveys of
Heckman et al., 1999 Blundell and Costa-Dias,
2000, 2002).
10Microeconometric Evaluation Methods
- Before-after comparison panel data
- Difference-in-difference estimator (DiD) panel
data - Instrumental Variables estimator (IV)
cross-sectional data - Selection models cross-sectional data
- Matching methods cross-sectional data
- Mixed Method Conditional difference-in-difference
combines the DiD estimator and matching methods
panel data
11Before-After Comparison
- Suppose firm i got funding in period t, and we
observe RD expenses in t and t-1. - ATT could be estimated based on the average
difference of RD of treated firms in t (Yit) and
the RD of the same firm in the previous period
where it did NOT receive a treatment Yi,t-1. - Requires panel data
- Allows to control for individual fixed effects,
but not for macroeconomic shocks
12- Difference-in-Difference Estimator
The DiD estimator is based on a
before-and-after comparison of subsidized firms
and a non-subsidized control group.
Advantage - no functional form for outcome
equation required - not even a regressor is
needed - controls for common macroeconomic
trends - controls for constant
individual-specific unobserved effects NOTE
when covariates should be included, one can
estimate an OLS model in first differences. (but
functional form assumption necessary!) Disadvantag
e - strategic behavior of firms to enter
programs would lead to biased estimates
(Ashenfelters dip) - panel data required
including observations BEFORE AND AFTER (or
WHILE) treatment - biased if reaction to
macroeconomic changes differs between groups
(1) and (0) - problem to construct data if RD
subsidies show high persistence
13Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimators
- Suppose y b0 b1 x1 u
- We think that x1 is endogenous, i.e. COV(x,u)!0.
- e.g. wage equation
- wage may depend on education and ability.
- But we only observe x1 education.
- Then, u v b2ability (where v is a new error
term, b2 is the coefficient of ability) - OLS would be inconsistent as it relies on
COV(x,u)0. - Suppose we have an instrument w, that fullfils
two requirements - w is uncorrelated with the error term u ?
COV(w,u)0, i.e.(i.e. z should have no partial
effect on y once we control for x1) - and w is correlated with the endogenous variable
x, i.e. COV(w,x)!0. - IV estimator
14Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimators
- The recent utilization of IV estimators in
context of evaluation goes back to Imbens/Angrist
(1994) and Angrist et al. (1996) who invent the
Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE). - IV estimators have the advantage over selection
models that one does not have to model the
selection process and to impose distributional
assumptions. - Main disadvantage need of an instrument, whose
requirement are more demanding than those for the
exclusion restriction in selection models. - Instruments can be
- other variables (external instruments, often
hard to find and justify) - lagged values of endogenous variables (requires
panel data) - In the case of RD it is very difficult to find
valid instruments.
15Selection models
- control function approach
- Selection models are based on a two step
procedure (based on Heckmans work, 1974, 1976,
1979) - estimate the propensity to get an RD subsidy for
all firms - estimate outcome equation for participants and
non-participants including acorrection for a
possible selection mechanism,
16Selection models
- Under the assumption of joint normality, we can
estimate - Madalla (1983) ATT is determined by subtracting
the estimated RD expenditure of publicly funded
firms, which they would have conducted if they
had not received public RD funding, from the
expected RD expenditure of funded firms. The
difference is augmented by the selection
correction
17Selection models
- Advantage
- Controls for unobserved characteristics (entering
the first- and second-step equation). - Root-N-consistency
- Disadvantage
- Restrictive distributional assumption on the
error terms (joint normality). - An exclusion restriction is needed which is
included in the selection equation but not in the
structural equation to identify the treatment
effects. - A fully parametric model for the selection and
for the structural equation has to be defined.
18Semiparametric Selection Models
- Semiparametric estimators Gallant and Nychka
(1987), Cosslett (1991), Newey (1999), or
Robinson's (1988) partial linear model. - Semiparametric estimators identify only the slope
parameters of the outcome equation. Intercept in
outcome equation is no longer identified, but
required for deriving ATT - An additional estimator for the intercept is
needed to identify the treatment effects, e.g.
Heckman (1990),Andrews and Schafgans (1998). - See Hussinger (2008) for applications of such
estimators for the evaluation of innovation
policy.
19Matching
- Ex post mimic an experiment by constructing a
suitable control group by matching treated and
non-treated firms - Selected control group is as similar as possible
to treatment group in terms of observable
characteristics. - Matching is a nonparametric method to identify
the treatment effect
20Matching
- A1 Conditional independence assumption (CIA)
(Rubin 1974, 1977) All the relevant differences
between the treated and non-treated firms are
captured in their observable characteristics -
- gt For each treated firm, search for twins in the
potential control group having the same
characteristics, X, as the subsidized firms. - A2 We observe treated and non-treated firms with
the same characteristics (common support) - Under these assumptions, the ATT can be
calculated as
21Matching
- Treatment effect for firm i
- Two common matching estimators
- Nearest Neighbor wij1 for the most similar
firm, zero otherwise gt only one control
observation is used - Kernel-based entire control group is used for
each treated firm, weights wij are determined
by a kernel that downweights distant
observations from Xi.
22Kernel-Based Matching
- Weights are the kernel density at Xj - Xi
(rescaled that they sum up to 1) - Often the Gaussian kernel or the Epanechnikov
kernel is used, - Calculation of counterfactual requires
kernel-regression (e.g. Nadaraya-Watson
estimator) - locally weighted average of the entire control
group (for each treated firm)
23Kernel-Based Matching
- Bandwith h may be chosen according to Silvermans
rule of thumb - with k number of arguments in the matching
function - If you want to include more than a single X in
the matching function, you can use the
Mahalanobis distance
24Propensity Score
- Usually X contains many variables which make it
almost impossible to find control observations
that exactly fit those characteristics of the
subsidized firm. - Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) showed that it is
possible to reduce X to a single index - the
propensity score P - and match on this index. - It is possible to impose further restrictions on
the control group, e.g.that a control
observations belongs to the same industry or same
region etc.
25A NN Matching Procedure
- Specify and estimate probit model to obtain
propensity scores - Restrict sample to common support
- Delete all observations on treated firms with
propensity scores larger than the maximum and
smaller than the minimum in the potential control
group. - Do the same step for other variables that are
possibly used in addition to the propensity score
as matching argument. - Choose one observation from sub sample of treated
firms and delete it from that pool - Calculate the Mahalanobis distance between this
treated firm and all non-subsidized firms in
order to find the most similar control
observation. - Z contains the matching arguments (propensity
score and/or additional variables such as e.g
industry or size classes) - O is the empirical covariance matrix of the
matching arguments based on the sample of
potential controls
26A NN Matching Procedure
- Select observation with minimum distance from
potential control group as twin for the treated
firm - NN matching with replacement selected controls
are not deleted from the set of potential control
group so that they can be used again - NN matching without replacement selected
controls are deleted from the set of potential
control group so that they cannot be used again - Repeat steps 3 to 5 for all observations on
subsidized firms - The average effect on the treated mean
difference of matched samples - With YC_hat being the counterfactual for firm i
and nT is the sample size of treated firms. - Sampling with replacement ? ordinary t-statistic
on mean differences is biased (neglects
appearance of repeated observations) ? correct
standard errors Lechner (2001) ? estimator for
an asymptotic approximation of the standard
errors
27Matching in Stata
- Psmatch2.ado
- Software and documentation from Barbara Sianesi
and Edwin Leuven, IFS Londonhttp//www.ifs.org.uk
/publications.php?publication_id2684
http//ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s432001.html
28Disadvantages of Matching
- It only allows controlling for observed
heterogeneity among treated and untreated firms
(in observable cahracteristics in X) - Common support is necessary, that is, the range
of the propensity score of the control group must
cover the treatment group. - If the common support is rather small in your
data, matching is not applicable
29Mixed method Conditional Difference-in-Differenc
e
- Conditional difference-in-difference (DiD) method
for repeated cross-sections, which combines
ordinary DiD estimation with matching - The Conditional DiD estimator consists of
matching firms i and j with the same observable
characteristics X_i,t0 X_j,t0 where i receives
treatment in t1 but not in t0 and j is a
non-treated firm in both periods. - Heckman et al. (1998) show that CDiD based on
non-parametric matching proved to be a very
effective tool in controlling for both selection
on observables and unobservables.
30Microeconometric Evaluation Methods
- Before-after comparison panel data
- Difference-in-difference estimator (DiD) panel
data - Instrumental Variables estimator (IV)
cross-sectional data - Selection models cross-sectional data
- Matching methods cross-sectional data
- Mixed Method Conditional difference-in-difference
combines the DiD estimator and matching methods
panel data
31Which method to use?
- The econometric method that you can apply heavily
depends on the data you have - Panel or cross-section?
- Is the treatment variable a binary indicator
(yes/no) or is it a continuous treatment
variable? - Do I have candidates for instrumental variables?
- Do I want to make functional form assumptions of
my RD investment equation? - Do I want to specify a structural model or
simultaneous equation system?
32Empirical Studies
- Busom (2000), 154 obs., Spanish manufacturing,
parametric selection model - Wallsten (2000), 479 obs., US SBIR program,
simultaneousequations model, 3SLS (incl. amount
of funding) - Czarnitzki (2001), 640 obs., Eastern German
manufacturing, NN-Matching - Czarnitzki/Fier (2002), 1,084 obs., German
service sector, NN-Matching - Fier (2002), 3,136 obs., German manufacturing
(specific program), NN-Matching - Lach (2002), 134 obs. Israeli manufacturing, DiD
and dynamic panel models - Almus/Czarnitzki (2003), 925 obs., Eastern German
mf., NN-matching - Gonzales et al. (2006), 2.214 obs. Spanish
manufacturing, simultaneousequations model with
thresholds - Hussinger (2008), 3744 obs., German manufacturing
sector 1992-2000, parametric and semiparametric
selection models - Schmidt and Aerts (2008), Germany and Flanders,
CIS34, NN matching and CDID - Surveys David et al. (2000 survey on
crowding-out effects), Klette et al. (2000,
including output analyzes like firm growth, firm
value, patents etc.), Parsons and Phillips
(2007), Aerts et al. (2007)
33Example for Effect of RD subsidies on RD
Expenditure Using Matching Estimators
- Schmidt and Aerts (2008), Two for the price of
one? Additionality effects of RD subsidies A
comparison between Flanders and Germany, Research
Policy 37 (5), 806-822 - Data German and Flemish Community Innovation
Surveys (3 and 4) - 2 methods
- Matching estimator and
- conditional DiD
34Mean Comparison Before Matching
35Mean Comparison Before Matching
36Probit Estimations and Marginal Effects
37Mean Comparison After Matching
38Mean Comparison After Matching
39Average Treatment Effects of the Treated
Companies
40To sum up Does public funding stimulate or crowd
out private RD expenditure?
- Nearly all empirical studies reject the
hypothesis of a total crowding out (i.e. no
change in total private RD expenditure due to
public funding). - Exception Wallsten (2000) for US SBIR program
- Hypothesis of partial crowding out is also often
rejected. - David et al. (2000) At the macro level, only 2
out of 14 studies yield a substitute relationship
of public and private RD investment. At the firm
level 9 out of 19. - Czarnitzki et al. (2002) average multiplier
effect of 1 which can be higher for specific
groups
41To sum up Does public funding stimulate or crowd
out private RD expenditure?
- Crowding in effects Public RD subsidies
stimulates net RD expenditure (total RD exp.
minus subsidy) - Gonzales et al. (2006) multiplier effect for
Spanish firms in 1990-1999 slightly above 1 - Fier et al. (2004) multiplier effect of 1,14 for
German firms in 1990-2000 (varies according to
technology fields) - Hussinger and Czarnitzki (2004) multiplier
effect of 1.44 - Parsons and Phillips (2007) average multiplier
effect of 1.29 for surveyed studies - Large variation in estimated multiplier effect,
not surprising because funding schemes are
different and have to be taken into account.
42Extensions
- Heterogeneous treatments
- Effects on innovation output
- Effects on innovation behaviour
43Heterogeneous Treatments
- So far, simply binary indicator (funded yes/no)
- Heterogeneous Treatments, e.g.
- Countinuous treatment
- Categorial treatment
- Countinuous treatment
- Hirano and Imbens (2005)
- different subsidies levels
- generalized propensity score (GPS) method for the
estimation of so called dose-response functions. - Categorial treatment
- Imbens (2000), Gerfin and Lechner (2002)
- divide treated firms in different groups, e.g.
low subsidy and high subsidy - distinguish between different policy programs.
44Effects on Innovation Output (Output
Additionality)
- Subsidies may just increase wages of RD
employees but not the number of RD personnel. If
an increase in wages does not go along with
higher research productivity, subsidies are
likely to result in higher innovation input, but
not necessarily in innovation output. - Subsidized projects may be associated with higher
risk than privately financed projects. If failure
rates are higher, subsidies are likely to result
in higher RD investment, but not necessarily in
innovation output. - Czarnitzki and Hussinger (2004) and Czarnitzki
and Licht (2006) add patent equation to the input
model. Both purely private RD and publicly
funded RD increase patenting output. Subsidized
RD is a little less productive, though.
45Effects on Innovation Behaviour(Behavioural
Additionality)
- Example Current practice in Europe is to support
research consortia (firmsfirms / firms
scientific institutions) rather than giving
subsidies to individual firms. - Czarnitzki, Ebersberger and Fier (2007) apply
Gerfin/Lechner methodology to investigate effects
of subsidies vs. RD collaborations in Germany
and Finland - RD collaboration achieves RD input (and output)
more than subsidies to individual firms - AND there is room for fostering collaboration
especially in Germany (Treatment effect on the
untreated).
46(No Transcript)
47Further challenges in research
- Output effect mainly measured in terms of patents
(patents are an indicator of inventions, not
necessarily of innovations) - Alternative innovation out share of sales with
new products (Hussinger 2008) - Empirical Does collaborative RD funding result
in collusion in product market? - Overall welfare effect might be negative
- Specifities of policy schemes are not exploited
in current research. - Ideally, policy makers would like to know if a
certain program design is more likely to prevent
crowding-out effects than another. - Selection equation is a reduced form estimation.
Decision of the firm to apply and decision of the
government to support a firm are not separately
accounted for. - Solution Structural models (see work by Otto
Toivanen)
48More Literature
- NBER Summer Course in Econometrics by Guido
Imbens and Jeff Wooldridge - http//www.nber.org/minicourse3.html
- Includes videos of lectures and extensive lecture
notes - Survey by Imbens and Wooldridge (2009)
- http//www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/imbens/fi
les/recent_developments_econometrics.pdf - published in Journal of Economic Literature
49Part IIISimple Cost-Benefit Approach to Public
Support of Private RD Activity
50State Aid for RDI
- Community Regulation Dec. 30, 2006
- State aid for RDI shall be compatible if the
aid can be expected to lead to additional RDI
and if the distortion of competition is not
considered to be contrary to the common interest,
which the Commission equates for the purposes of
this framework with economic efficiency - To establish rules ensuring that aid measures
achieve this objective, it is, first of all,
necessary to identify the market failures
hampering RDI - Negative effects of the aid to RDI must be
limited so that the overall balance is positive.
51Cost-Benefit Analysis
- Empirical evidence that social returns to RD
exceed private returns identifies market failure
and thus provide a central argument in favour of
direct or indirect public support of private RD
activities. - But only necessary but sufficient condition
- Public RD programmes are always associated with
costs which go beyond the pure size of the
subsidy - Cost-Benefit-Analysis
- Evaluation of taxed-based RD support (RD tax
credits) in Australia (Lattimore 1997),
Netherlands (Cornet 2001a,b) and Canada (Parsons
and Phillips 2007) - Evaluation of direct project-based RD support in
Germany (Peters, Kladroba, Licht, Crass 2009)
52Cost-Benefit Analysis
- Basic idea
- Government supports RDI activities of firms in
period t0 (size of the support P1 ) - No returns to RD in funding period (t0)
- Returns Rt accruing from RD from period t1
onwards - Compare net present value of benefits and costs
- A project is beneficial if C0 is larger than 0 or
equivalently benefit/cost-ratio is larger than 1
53Benefits
- Returns
- in period t1 R
- in period t2 R(1-d), where d is the
depreciation rate on knowledge -
- What is R?
- Returns R to RD are equal to the actual change
of private RD expenditure times the average
social rate of return s. - Change of private RD expenditure depends on size
of public support P and multiplier/crowding out
effects m - Further account for the fact that a proportion ?
of the subsidies may just use to increase wages
of RD employees but not to increase the amount
of research that is undertaken.
54Benefits
- Returns are discounted with discount factor i,
consisting of - the time preference rate r (reflecting e.g. the
interest rate of risk-free investment) and - the risk premium p (additional return a firm
requires to invest in risky RD projects) - Present value of the benefits of subsidizing
private RD having a finite time-horizon of T - having an infinite time-horizon
55Benefits
- Alternative assumptions about multiplier effects
m based on econometric evaluation studies - 0 (total crowding out)
- 0.6 (strong crowding out)
- 0.9 (weak crowding out)
- 1.0
- 1.15 (weak crowding in, preferred conservative
estimate) - 1.3 (medium crowding in average estimated
effect reported in the survey - by Parson Philips 2007)
- 2 (strong crowding in)
- Social rate of return s based on spillover
literature - Assumption additionally publicly funded RD
yields the same average social return - Preferred assumption s0.5 (alternatives 0.15 /
0.3 / 0.7 and 1.0)
56Benefits
- Wage elasticity of labour ?
- Goolsbee (1998) based on data of 17,700 US
scientists and engineers from the years 1968 to
1994 he estimates that an increase of public RD
funding by 11 increase wages on average by 3.3
(wage elasticity varies between 2 and 6
depending on educational background). - Given that 2/3 of RD expenditure is for labour,
they estimated the actual increase in research to
be roughly 23 lower. - Marey and Borghans (2000) 20-30 of increase in
RD expenditures due to introduction of tax
credits is related to higher wages - Effect will depend on labour market specifities
- Preferred assumption 10 alternative
assumptions 5, 20 and 30
57Benefits
- Depreciation rate d
- d15 (alternatively 10, 20)
- Time preference rate r
- r3.5 (alternatively 5)
- Risk premium p
- p 3 (alternatively 5)
- Time horizon
- T15 (alternatively 5, 10, 20 years and infinite
horizon)
58Costs
- Different types of costs
- Direct programme costs (P) in period t0 (size of
subsidy or forgone taxes) - Administrative costs of government
- Administrative costs of firms
- Tax funding of subsidies induce a distortion of
resource allocation ?welfare loss (marginal
excess burden) - Forgone returns of an alternative investment
- Present value of costs
- cs public administrative costs
- cu administrative costs of the firm
- tx macroeconomic costs of tax financing
- ß return to the alternative investment
59Costs
- Administrative costs
- Till now scarcely evaluated Gunz et. al. (1997)
and Parsons and Phillips (2007) for Canada - Administrative costs of firms
- Administrative costs of the firms varies with the
policy measure - They are expected to be much lower with RD tax
credits than with RD project funding (require
less paperwork and entail fewer layers of
bureaucracy) - Proportion of the administrative costs decreases
with absolute project size resp. absolute
altitude of the tax abatement - For project based funding 3-25 of support
received (average 8) - For fiscal funding 15 (10, 5) of the tax
abatement if tax abatement (lt100,000 ,
100,000-500,000 , gt500,000 ) - Basic specification cU8 (alternative
assumptions 5, 10, 20)
60Costs
- Administrative costs to government
- 1.7 related to the whole taxes foregone in case
of tax credits - 3-8 in case of project based funding
- Basic specification cS3 (alternative
assumptions 2, 5, 10) - Macroeconomic costs of tax financing
- Lattimore (1997) estimated welfare losses due to
distortive effects of tax financing of public
funding 15-50 of direct program costs - Distortive effect depends on type of taxes raised
- Parsons and Phillips (2007) estimated a
distortive effect of 27. - Basic specification tx30 (alternative
assumptions 15, 50) - Return to the alternative investment
- Basic specification ß5
61A Simple Cost-Benefit Approach to Public Support
of Private RD Activity
Benefit-to-Cost-ratio
Using the preferred parameter estimates, benefits
of public RD subsidies would exceed costs by
roughly 1.66
62Multiplier, Social Benefits and the
Cost-Benefit-Relationship of Public RD Funding
area of probable combinations of multiplier
effects and social benefit rates
welfare gains
macroeconomic costs macroeconomic benefits
multiplier
welfare losses
social rate of return
63Effect of Time Preference Rate, Risk Premium and
Depreciation Rate
Additional parameter assumptions m1.15, s0,5,
P1,cU0.08, cS0.03, tx0.3, ?0.1, ß0.05 and
T15. Source Peters et al. (2009)
64Effect of Tax Distortion and Administrative Costs
Additional parameter assumptions m1.15, s0,5,
P1,r0.035, p0.03, d0.15, tx0.3, ?0.1,
ß0.05 and T15. Source Peters et al. (2009)
65Effect of Wage Elasticity and Time Horizon
Additional parameter assumptions m1.15, s0,5,
P1,cU0.08, cS0.03, r0.035, p0.03,
d0.15,ß0.05 and tx0.3. Source Peters et al.
(2009)
66Summary
- Using the preferred parameter estimates, benefits
of public RD subsidies would exceed costs by
roughly 1.66. - Positive effects for a broad range of parameter
values. - Overall effect of public RD funding crucially
depend on the amount of social returns to RD and
multiplier effects. - Even in case of low social returns to RD public
funding might be beneficial, the likelihood
increases with increasing multiplier effects. - Crowding out effects do not necessarily imply a
welfare loss (v.v.) - E.g. strong crowding out effects (m0.6) could be
compensated by an average social rate of return
of 0.5. - Other parameters are less important.
- Only a modest impact of time preference rate,
risk premium and administrative costs. - Moderate impact of depreciation rate, tax
distortion and time horizon
67Limitations
- Ideally, policy makers would like to know which
program design is presumably the most efficient. - Program-specific cost-benefit analysis would
require program-specific estimates of model
parameters (multipliers, social rates of return,
) - not yet available
- It is argued that there is presumably a
trade-off - Social benefits are expected to be higher for tax
credits whereas multiplier effects are expected
to be higher for public subsidies.
68Back-up slide
69Aid Intensities within EU State Aid Rules
Share of Public Funding in Total Project Costs