Intermediate Microeconomic Theory - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 24
About This Presentation
Title:

Intermediate Microeconomic Theory

Description:

Intermediate Microeconomic Theory Cost Curves * * Cost Functions We have solved the first part of the problem: given factor prices, what is cheapest way to produce q ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:125
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 25
Provided by: Informat2233
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Intermediate Microeconomic Theory


1
Intermediate Microeconomic Theory
  • Cost Curves

2
Cost Functions
  • We have solved the first part of the problem
    given factor prices, what is cheapest way to
    produce q units of output?
  • Given by conditional factor demands for each
    input i, xi(w1,, wn, q)
  • However, this is only half the problem.
  • To model behavior of the firm, we also have to
    derive how much output a firm will find optimal
    to produce, given input and output prices.

3
Cost functions
  • Key to firms output decision is the firms cost
    function
  • Gives the total cost of producing a given amount
    of output, given some input prices and assuming
    the firm acts optimally (i.e. cost minimizes).
  • Suppose a firm used n inputs for production, with
    conditional demand functions for each input given
    by
  • x1(w1,, wn, q)
  • xn(w1,, wn, q)
  • What would be the generic form for its cost
    function?

4
Cost functions Example
  • Consider a firm that builds a product with only
    two inputs (L, K) with Cobb-Douglas technology of
    the form
  • q f(L,K) L0.5 K0.5
  • If wL 8 and wK 2, what will be optimal way to
    produce some amount q?
  • What will be this firms cost function given
    these prices and technology?
  • So, how much will it cost to produce q 10
    optimally?

5
Cost functions and Opportunity Costs
  • It is important to remember that a cost function
    includes all costs of production, including
    opportunity costs.
  • With Cobb-Douglas technology assumed, figuring
    out costs is easy because we have implicitly
    assumed only two inputs.
  • Things can be more complicated though.

6
Cost functions with Opportunity Costs
  • Suppose I am considering getting into the chair
    making business, where I would deliver however
    many chairs I make to Ikea one year from now.
  • To make any chairs at all, I need to buy a saw
    which costs 400 (though I can re-sell it for
    200 at the end of the year)
  • Then, each chair I make requires 3 boards of wood
    (at 2/board).
  • Making chairs also required time. Specifically, I
    can turn my time into chairs according to the
    production function q L0.5.
  • If I currently have 1000 in savings at 10
    annual interest, and any time I spent making
    chairs would mean less time working at my current
    job which pays 20/hr, what would be my cost
    function for making chairs?

7
Short run vs. Long(er) run
  • It is often important to distinguish between the
    Short-Run (SR) and Long(er)-Run (LR) when
    considering costs.
  • Short-run some factors of production are fixed
    (i.e. cant be adjusted).
  • Long(er)-run previously fixed factors of
    production can be adjusted.

8
Short Run Cost Curve
  • The key aspect of a fixed factor of production is
    that it will mean there will be some component of
    cost that is the same regardless of how much
    output (if any) is produced (in short run).
  • How does this relate to the chair making example?
  • What might be some other production processes
    that have fixed inputs the short run?

9
Short Run Cost Curve Analytically
  • Short-run cost function where x2 fixed at x2f
    (and only two inputs)
  • CSR(q) w1x1(qx2 x2f) w2x2f
  • Short run cost function where there are n inputs,
    where inputs 1 to k are variable and k to n are
    fixed
  • So, short-run cost function can be written
  • CSR(q) cv(q) F

10
Short Run vs. Long Run Costs Analytically
  • Example Consider again a firm where
  • q f(L, K) L0.5 K0.5, wL 8, wK 2.
  • From before, we know long-run (i.e. when both
    factors are variable) cost function in this case
    will be
  • C(q) 8q
  • Suppose in the short-run Capital (K) is fixed at
    24 machine hrs.
  • What is short-run cost function?

11
Short-Run Cost function
  • Given how cost functions are derived, will the
    cost of producing any given level of output be
    greater in the short-run or the longer run?

12
Cost Curves
  • In modeling optimal firm behavior, it will often
    be helpful to think of costs graphically via
    cost curves.
  • The first thing we want to think about is how the
    cost of producing one more unit changes over
    the production cycle.
  • Consider a discrete cost function where
  • c(1) 20
  • c(2) 30
  • c(3) 35
  • c(4) 45
  • c(5) 60
  • What would graph of this look like?
  • What if we graphed cost of one more?
  • What might we call the cost of producing one
    more unit and its associated curve?

13
Marginal Costs Graphically
  • Marginal Cost Curve MC(q)
  • Denotes the cost of producing a little bit
    more, given you have already produced q units
  • So MC(q) C(q1) C(q)/1
  • Actually rate of change, however, so
  • MC(q) C(q?q) C(q)/?q
  • And taking the limit as ?q goes to 0,
  • Therefore, we can get an idea of what the MC(q)
    curve looks like from the cost curve and vice
    versa.

C(q)

q

MC(q)
q
14
Cost functions and Returns-to-Scale
  • We can also describe returns-to-scale via a cost
    curve/marginal cost curve
  • If marginal costs are decreasing over a range of
    output levels, we say that technology exhibits
    increasing returns-to-scale (IRS) over that
    range.
  • If marginal costs are constant over a range of
    output levels, we say that technology exhibits
    constant returns-to-scale (CRS) over that range.
  • If marginal costs are increasing over a range of
    output levels, we say that technology exhibits
    decreasing returns-to-scale (DRS) over that
    range.
  • Graphically?

15
Cost functions and Returns-to-Scale
  • Consider Cobb-Douglas production function f(L,K)
    L0.5K0.5, with wL 8 and wK 2.
  • Recall that the (Long-Run) cost function for this
    technology was
  • CLR(q) 8q
  • Does this exhibit CRS, DRS, or IRS?
  • Now consider the same Cobb-Douglas production
    function f(L,K) L0.5K0.5, with wL 8 and wK
    2, but where K is fixed at 24.
  • Recall that the (Short-Run) cost function for
    this technology was
  • Does this cost function exhibit DRS, CRS, IRS?

CSR(q) q2/3 48
16
Cost functions and Returns-to-Scale
  • From now on, we will generally be considering
    relatively Short-run (i.e. at least one factor
    fixed), so cost functions will exhibit DRS at
    some point.

17
Cost Curves
  • In modeling optimal firm behavior, it will often
    be helpful to think of two other cost curves as
    well.
  • Average Cost Curve AC(q)
  • Denotes the average cost of producing each unit,
    given q units are produced.
  • AC(q) C(q)/q
  • Average Variable Cost Curve AVC(q)
  • As discussed above, we can often think of our SR
    cost function as
  • C(q) cv(q) F
  • So AVC(q) cv(q)/q

18
Cost Curves
  • Consider our example, C(q) q2/3 48
  • (i.e. the cost function that arises from
    production function f(L,K) L0.5K0.5 with K fixed
    at 24 and wL 8, wK 2)
  • What is equation for AC(q)?
  • What is equation for AVC(q)?
  • What is equation for MC(q)?

19
Cost Curves (cont.)
  • How do these curves relate to each other?
  • First note MC(q) C(q) C(q-1)/1
  • Next, recall
  • AVC(q) cv(q)/q
  • C(q)-F/q (noting that cv(q) C(q)-
    F)
  • C(q)-C(0)/q (noting that C(0) F)
  • (C(q)-C(q-1) (C(q-1)-C(q-2))(C(
    1)-C(0))/q
  • So AVC(q) MC(q) MC(q-1) MC(1)/q

20
Cost Curves (cont)
  • Given AVC(q) MC(q) MC(q-1) MC(1)/q,
  • AVC is essentially the average Marginal cost of
    producing each unit, given firm has produced q
    units.
  • Therefore,
  • If MC(q) lt AVC(q) over some range of q, then
    AVC(q) must be decreasing over that range (if you
    continually add something below the average,
    average will go down)
  • Alternatively, if MC(q) gt AVC(q) over some range
    of q, then AVC(q) must be increasing over that
    range (if you continually add something above the
    average, average will go up)
  • So MC(q) must intersect AVC(q) at the q with the
    minimum Average Variable cost (call it q)

21
MC(q) and AVC(q)
MC(q)

AVC(q)
q q
22
Cost Curves (cont)
  • Now, recall AC(q) C(q)/q cv(q) F/q
  • AVC(q) F/q
  • So AC(q) - AVC(q) F/q
  • (difference between AC(q) and AVC(q) decreases as
    q increases)
  • Also, AC(q) MC(q) MC(q-1) MC(1)/q
    F/q
  • Therefore, if MC(q) lt AC(q) over some range of q,
    then AC(q) must be decreasing over that range.
  • Alternatively, if MC(q) gt AC(q) over some range
    of q, then AC(q) must be increasing over that
    range.
  • So MC(q) also intersects AC(q) at the q with the
    minimum Average Cost (call it q).

23
MC(q) and AVC(q)
MC(q)

AC(q)
AVC(q)
F
q q q
24
Long-run vs. Short-run MC curves
  • Recall our discussion of long-run vs. short-run.
  • For example, consider a firm deciding how large
    of a plant to build.
  • Suppose there are three possible size plants.
  • Each plant size will be associated with its own
    cost curve and MC curve
  • In the short-run, the firm is stuck with a given
    plant size, but over the longer-run they can
    choose which plant size to use based on how much
    they plan to build.
  • How will cost curve and MC curve change from the
    short-run to the longer-run?
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com