Kidney Exchange - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 47
About This Presentation
Title:

Kidney Exchange

Description:

Building on existing practices in kidney transplantation, ... liver transplants Chicago hospitals accused of ... (About 25% all living-donor transplants were in ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:306
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 48
Provided by: AlR58
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Kidney Exchange


1
Kidney Exchange
  • 4th Barcelona Economics LectureHospital Clinic,
    Barcelona
  • 8 November 2004

2
  • Roth, Alvin E., Tayfun Sönmez, and M. Utku Ãœnver,
    Kidney Exchange, Quarterly Journal of
    Economics, 119, 2, May, 2004, 457-488.
  • ____ Pairwise Kidney Exchange, June 2004.
  • _____ The Importance of Three Way Kidney
    Exchange, in preparation

3
ProposalNew England Center for Kidney Donor
Exchange
  • Presented to the ROTC
  • September 20, 2004
  • (Approved!)

Frank Delmonico, MD (NEOB and MGH) Susan
Saidman, PhD (MGH Histocompatibility Lab) Al
Roth, PhD (Prof. of Economics Business Admin,
Harvard) Tayfun Somnez, PhD (Dept. of Economics,
Koc University Utku Unver, PhD (Dept. of
Economics, Koc University
4
  • On Saturday I gave a companion talk as the Pareto
    Lecture, at a conference of economic theorists
  • In that talk I emphasized some of the theoretical
    issues that arise in designing a Kidney Exchange.
  • Today Ill speak more of practical issues, and
    how those shape what can be done (and what kind
    of theory is needed).

5
Economists As Engineers
  • In recent years, game theorists have become
    usefully involved in the design of markets.
  • See e.g. Roth and Peranson (1999), Roth
    (2002,medical labor markets) Wilson (2002,
    electricity markets), Abdulkadiroglu and Sönmez
    (2003, schools), Milgrom (2004, auctions),
    Niederle and Roth (2004, gastroenterologist labor
    market)
  • A certain amount of humility is called for
    successful designs most often involve incremental
    changes to existing practices, both because
  • It is easier to get incremental changes adopted,
    rather than radical departures from preceding
    practice, and
  • There may be lots of hidden institutional
    adaptations and knowledge in existing
    institutions, procedures, and customs.

6
Kidney transplants
  • There are over 60,000 patients on the waiting
    list for cadaver kidneys in the U.S.
  • In 2003 there were over 8,500 transplants of
    cadaver kidneys performed in the U.S. (and over
    2,000 in Spain, which has one of the most
    effective cadaver organ donation systems in the
    world)
  • In the same year, about 3,500 patients died while
    on the waiting list.
  • In 2003 there were also over 6,000 transplants of
    kidneys from living donors in the US, a number
    that has been increasing steadily from year to
    year.
  • (I dont know the local statistics, but I
    understand that the Hospital Clinic is one of the
    places at which live donor transplants are done
    here.)

7
Live-donor transplants are much less organized
than cadaver transplants
  • The way such transplants are typically arranged
    is that a patient identifies a willing donor and,
    if the transplant is feasible, it is carried out.
  • Otherwise, the patient remains on the queue for a
    cadaver kidney, while the donor returns home.
  • Recently, however, in a small number of cases,
    additional possibilities have been utilized
  • Paired exchanges exchanges between incompatible
    couples
  • Indirect exchanges an exchange between an
    incompatible couple and the cadaver queue

8
Paired Exchange (still relatively rare)
9
Baltimore Center Carries Out Triple-Swap
TransplantsAugust 2, 2003, New York Times
  • The triple-swap kidney transplant operation was
    announced in a news conference today at the Johns
    Hopkins Comprehensive Transplant Center, which
    said it believed that this was the first time
    three simultaneous kidney transplants have been
    performed
  • Months in the making, the exchange was the only
    way all three recipients could have received a
    kidney, the lead surgeon, Dr. Robert A.
    Montgomery, said, because of tissue, blood or
    antibody incompatibilities among the donors and
    their originally designated recipients.
  • Johns Hopkins has recently hired a paired kidney
    exchange coordinator to facilitate further
    exchanges

10
How might more frequent and larger-scale kidney
exchanges eventually be organized?
  • Building on existing practices in kidney
    transplantation, we consider how exchanges might
    be organized to produce efficient outcomes,
    providing consistent incentives (dominant
    strategy equilibria) to patients-donors-doctors.
  • Why are incentives/equilibria important?
    (becoming ill is not something anyone chooses)
  • But if patients, donors, and the doctors acting
    as their advocates are asked to make choices, we
    need to understand the incentives they have, in
    order to know the equilibria of the game and
    understand the resulting behavior.
  • Experience with the cadaver queues make this
    clear

11
Incentives liver transplants
  • Chicago hospitals accused of transplant fraud
  • 2003-07-29 112007 -0400 (Reuters Health)
  • CHICAGO (Reuters) Three Chicago hospitals were
    accused of fraud by prosecutors on Monday for
    manipulating diagnoses of transplant patients to
    get them new livers.
  • Two of the institutions paid fines to settle the
    charges.
  • By falsely diagnosing patients and placing them
    in intensive care to make them appear more sick
    than they were, these three highly regarded
    medical centers made patients eligible for liver
    transplants ahead of others who were waiting for
    organs in the transplant region, said Patrick
    Fitzgerald, the U.S. attorney for the Northern
    District of Illinois.
  • These things look a bit different to economists
    than to prosecutors? it looks like these docs
    may simply be acting in the interests of their
    patients

12
Incentives and efficiencyNeonatal heart
transplants
  • Heart transplant candidates gain priority through
    time on the waiting list
  • Some congenital defects can be diagnosed in the
    womb.
  • A fetus placed on the waiting list has a better
    chance of getting a heart
  • And when a heart becomes available, a C-section
    might be in the patients best interest.
  • But fetuses (on Moms circulatory system) get
    healthier, not sicker, as time passes and they
    gain weight.
  • So hearts transplanted into not-full-term babies
    may have less chance of surviving.
  • Michaels, Marian G, Joel Frader, and John
    Armitage 1993, "Ethical Considerations in
    Listing Fetuses as Candidates for Neonatal Heart
    Transplantation," Journal of the American Medical
    Association, January 20, vol. 269, no. 3,
    pp401-403

13
Kidney Matching
  • Two genetic characteristics play key roles
  • ABO blood-type There are four blood types A, B,
    AB and O.
  • Type O kidneys can be transplanted into any
    patient
  • Type A kidneys can be transplanted into type A or
    type AB patients
  • Type B kidneys can be transplanted into type B or
    type AB patients and
  • Type AB kidneys can only be transplanted into
    type AB patients.
  • So type O patients are at a disadvantage in
    finding compatible kidneys.

14
  • 2. Tissue type or HLA type
  • Combination of six proteins, two of type A, two
    of type B, and two of type DR.
  • Prior to transplantation, the potential recipient
    is tested for the presence of antibodies against
    HLA in the donor kidney. The presence of
    antibodies, known as a positive crossmatch,
    significantly increases the likelihood of graft
    rejection by the recipient and makes the
    transplant infeasible.

15
Goals of a structured method of direct kidney
exchange
  1. Assemble a database of incompatible patient-donor
    pairs. (Right now, the incompatible donors are
    largely lost.)
  2. Identify which exchanges are possible, and which
    sets of exchanges make best use of available
    donor kidneys
  3. allow not only for paired-exchange but also other
    forms of exchange such as a three-way exchange.

16
Some relevant economics papers
  • Shapley, Lloyd and Herbert Scarf (1974), On
    Cores and Indivisibility, Journal of
    Mathematical Economics, 1, 23-37.
  • Roth, Alvin E. and Andrew Postlewaite (1977),
    Weak Versus Strong Domination in a Market with
    Indivisible Goods, Journal of Mathematical
    Economics, 4, 131-137.
  • Roth, Alvin E. (1982), Incentive Compatibility
    in a Market with Indivisible Goods, Economics
    Letters, 9, 127-132.
  • Atila Abdulkadiroglu and Tayfun Sönmez 1999
    House allocation with existing tenants. Journal
    of Economic Theory 88, 233-260.

17
DONOR KIDNEY EXCHANGE FOR INCOMPATIBLE RECIPIENTS
  • by Francis L. Delmonico, MD 1, Paul E. Morrissey,
    MD 1, George S. Lipkowitz, MD 2, Jeffrey S.
    Stoff, MD 1, Jonathan Himmelfarb, MD 1, William
    Harmon, MD 1, Martha Pavlakis, MD 1, Helen Mah 1,
    Jane Goguen 1, Richard Luskin 1, Edgar Milford,
    MD 1 and Richard J. Rohrer, MD 1. 1, New England
    Organ Bank, Newton, MA and 2, LifeChoice Donor
    Services, Windsor, CT.
  • Reports two live donor exchanges (4 recipients)
    and 8 list paired exchanges (16 recipients) from
    2001-02.

18
House allocation
  • Shapley Scarf 1974 housing market model n
    agents each endowed with an indivisible good, a
    house.
  • Each agent has preferences over all the houses
    and there is no money, trade is feasible only in
    houses.
  • Gales top trading cycles (TTC) algorithm Each
    agent points to her most preferred house (and
    each house points to its owner). There is at
    least one cycle in the resulting directed graph
    (a cycle may consist of an agent pointing to her
    own house.) In each such cycle, the corresponding
    trades are carried out and these agents are
    removed from the market together with their
    assignments.
  • The process continues (with each agent pointing
    to her most preferred house that remains on the
    market) until no agents and houses remain.

19
Theorem (Shapley and Scarf) the allocation x
produced by the top trading cycle algorithm is in
the core (no set of agents can all do better than
to participate)
  • When preferences are strict, Gales TTC algorithm
    yields the unique allocation in the core (Roth
    and Postlewaite 1977).

20
Theorem (Roth 82) if the top trading cycle
procedure is used, it is a dominant strategy for
every agent to state his true preferences.
  • The idea of the proof is simple, but it takes
    some work to make precise.
  • When the preferences of the players are given by
    the vector P, let Nt(P) be the set of players
    still in the market at stage t of the top
    trading cycle procedure.
  • A chain in a set Nt is a list of agents/houses
    a1, a2, ak such that ais first choice in the
    set Nt is ai1. (A cycle is a chain such that
    aka1.)
  • At any stage t, the graph of people pointing to
    their first choice consists of cycles and chains
    (with the head of every chain pointing to a
    cycle).

21
Cycles and chains
Cycles and chains
i
22
The cycles leave the system (regardless of where
i points), but is choice set (the chains
pointing to i) remains, and can only grow
i
23
  • Paired kidney exchanges similarly seek the gains
    from trade among patients with willing donors,
    but (with the recent Johns Hopkins 3-pair
    exchange being a notable exception) mostly among
    just two pairs.
  • In the context of kidney exchange, if we consider
    exchange only among patients with donors, the
    properties of the housing market model
    essentially carry over unchanged (as long as
    donor preferences coincide with those of their
    intended recipient).
  • However donors (unlike houses) have preferences.
    So all parts of a live-donor exchange are done
    simultaneously, to avoid incentive problems.

24
How big are the welfare gains?
  • Theory show us how to go from inefficient to
    efficient procedures, but it doesnt tell us how
    big the gains are likely to be.
  • For that we turn to computational simulations,
    using data on the mismatch frequencies, patient
    demographics, etc.
  • We first consider unrelated donor-patient pairs.
    (About 25 all living-donor transplants were in
    this category in 2001.)

25
Patient and Donor Characteristics
  • Population Caucasian ESRD patient population
    between 18 and 79 years of age in the U.S. Renal
    Data System (USRDS).
  • Blood-type and age distribution Distributions
    for new ESRD waitlist patients recorded between
    January 1995 and April 2003 in the USRDS
    database.
  • Gender distribution Data recorded between 1992
    and 2001.
  • HLA distribution The distribution reported in
    Zenios 1996 using the USRDS registration data
    for years between 1988 and 1991.
  • We assume that all HLA proteins and blood type
    are independently distributed following Zenios
    1996.

26
Simulated patient preferences
  • Preferences are determined using the graft
    survival analysis of Mandal et. al. 2003. We
    assume that the preferences of each patient
    depends on the donor age and the number of HLA
    mismatches. Using the graft survival analysis of
    Mandal et. al. 2003, MRS is determined as
  • 5.14 years of younger donor age per each
    additional HLA mismatch for patients younger than
    60 years of age, and
  • 5.10 years of younger donor age per each
    additional HLA mismatch for patients older than
    59 years of age

27
How big are the benefits? N30
28
How big are the benefits? N100
29
How about actual patient populations?
  • While the simulated results look good, they are
    drawn from general patient distributions.
  • Actual patient populations will consist of
    incompatible patient-donor pairs.
  • Patients who are already known to be incompatible
    with one donor may be much harder to matche.g.
    they are more likely to be highly sensitized

30
MGH Dataset (constructed by Susan Saidman)
  • MGH patients w/ incompatible (ABO or XM) donor(s)
  • Data included
  • ABO type of patient donor
  • HLA type of patient donor
  • Most recent class I and II PRAs
  • Called abs or safe antigens
  • Relationship of donor to recipient
  • Reason donor was incompatible
  • If donor not HLA typed, HLA types were assigned
    from list of UNOS deceased donors
  • 44 patients and 68 donor/patient pairs
  • 23 O 13 A 6 B 2 AB

31
Example of two-pair exchange (B-O,O-B)
Rec ID ABO Cl I PRA Cl II PRA Called abs Called abs Donor ID Donor ID Relatn ABO Donor HLA type Reason incompat
R28 O 0 0 D28.2 D28.2 Sib B DR52 ABO
R45 B 0 41 DR53 DR53 D45 D45 Child O DR51, 53 Class II ab
Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45 Exchange D45 gives to R28 D28.2 gives to R45
Rec ID ABO Cl I PRA Cl II PRA Called abs Donor ID Donor ID Relatn Relatn ABO Donor HLA type
R28 O 0 0 D45 D45 - - O DR51, 53 -
R45 B 0 41 DR53 D28.2 D28.2 - - B DR52 -
32
Example of three-pair exchange (A-B,B-B,B-A)
Rec ID ABO Cl I PRA Cl II PRA Called abs Called abs Donor ID Relatn ABO Donor HLA type Reason incompat
R19 B 0 50 DR12 DQ2,7 DR12 DQ2,7 D19 Child B DR2, 3 DQ1, DQ2 Pos B XM
R43 A 0 0 - - D43 Spouse B DR2, 8 DQ1, 4 ABO
R31 B 0 0 - - D31 Spouse A DR7, DQ2, 3 ABO
Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31 Exchange D43 gives to R19, D31 gives to R43, and D19 gives to R31
Rec ID ABO Cl I PRA Cl II PRA Called abs Donor ID Donor ID Relatn ABO Donor HLA type
R19 B 0 50 DR12 DQ2,7 D43 D43 B DR2, 8 DQ1, 4
R43 A 0 0 - D31 D31 A DR7, DQ2, 3
R31 B 0 0 - D19 D19 B DR2, 3 DQ1, DQ2
33
Note that
  • The initial screening and computer match
    identifies potentially compatible donor and
    recipient pairs
  • A crossmatch will always be required before pair
    can be confirmed to be compatible
  • Extensive antibody screening of patients and
    careful identification of all antibody
    specificities by a sensitive and specific method
    can help prevent unexpected positive crossmatches

34
Summary of analysis of MGH dataset
  • If only two way exchanges allowed
  • 8 patient-donor pairs in the dataset can
    potentially exchange kidneys (2 ABO-O 3 ABO-A 3
    ABO-B)
  • If three way exchanges allowed
  • 11 patient-donor pairs in the dataset can
    potentially exchange kidneys (3 ABO-O 3 ABO-A 4
    ABO-B 1 ABO-AB)
  • There is also a possible five way exchange
  • Allows 12 patient-donor pairs to potentially
    exchange kidneys
  • But logistics currently not practical

35
Properties of Cycles for n30
36
Properties of cycles for N100
37
Discussion of the Computational Results
  • The computational results (for both the simulated
    data and the MGH data) suggest that adoption of
    the TTC mechanism will significantly improve the
    utilization rate of potential living-donor
    kidneys.
  • But under the TTC mechanism, average/maximal
    sizes of exchanges grow as the population grows.
    For large populations of patient-donor pairs,
    some of the efficient exchanges may be
    impractically large.

38
Suppose exchanges involving more than two pairs
are impractical?
  • Our New England surgical colleagues have 0-1
    (feasible/infeasible) preferences over kidneys.
  • Initially, exchanges may be restricted to pairs.
    (see also Bogomolnaia and Moulin (2004)
  • This involves a substantial welfare loss compared
    to the unconstrained case
  • But it allows us to tap into some elegant graph
    theory for constrained efficient and incentive
    compatible mechanisms.

39
Pairwise matchings and matroids
  • Let (V,E) be the graph whose vertices are
    incompatible patient-donor pairs, with mutually
    compatible pairs connected by edges.
  • A matching M is a collection of edges such that
    no vertex is covered more than once.
  • Let S S be the collection of subsets of V such
    that, for any S in S, there is a matching M that
    covers the vertices in S
  • Then (V, S) is a matroid
  • If S is in S, so is any subset of S.
  • If S and S are in S, and SgtS, then there is
    a point in S that can be added to S to get a set
    in S.

40
Pairwise matching with 0-1 preferences
  • All maximal matchings match the same number of
    couples.
  • If patients have priorities, then a greedy
    priority algorithm produces the efficient
    (maximal) matching with highest priorities.
  • Any priority matching mechanism makes it a
    dominant strategy for all couples to
  • accept all feasible kidneys
  • reveal all available donors
  • So, there are efficient, incentive compatible
    mechanisms in the constrained case also.

41
(No Transcript)
42
Gallai-Edmonds Decomposition
43
Summary
  • There are several potential sources of increased
    efficiency from assembling a database of
    incompatible pairs (aggregating across time and
    space), including
  • More couple exchanges
  • longer cycles of exchange, instead of just pairs
  • If longer cycles of exchange arent (initially)
    feasible, constrained efficient matches can still
    be achieved with good incentive properties

44
Why 3-way exchanges add so much
  • Example Consider a population of 9 incompatible
    patient donor pairs consisting of
  • O-A, O-B (difficult to match O patients)
  • A-B, A-B, B-A (more A-B than B-A pairs)
  • A-A, A-A, A-A (odd number of A-A pairs)
  • B-O (scarce O donor)
  • 3 two-way exchanges are possible 6 transplants
  • (A-B,B-A) (A-A,A-A) (B-O,O-B)
  • If three-way exchanges are also feasible 8
    transplants
  • (A-B,B-A) (A-A,A-A,A-A) (B-O,O-A,A-B)

45
Four-way exchanges add less
  • In connection with blood type (ABO)
    incompatibilities, 4-way exchanges add less, but
    make additional exchanges possible when there is
    a (rare) incompatible patient-donor pair of type
    AB-O.
  • (AB-O,O-A,A-B,B-AB) is a four way exchange in
    which the presence of the AB-O helps three other
    couples
  • Incompatibilities involving positive cross
    matches may sometimes generate larger exchanges,
    but it appears that these are relatively rare

46
Summary (for surgeons)What do the economists
bring to the table?
  • To arrange exchanges efficiently in a population
    of patients with incompatible donors, there are
    distributional issues, not just issues of medical
    compatibility.
  • For example, consider four incompatible
    patient-donor pairs P1, P2, P3, P4, and suppose
    pairwise exchanges are possible between P1 and
    P2 P2 and P3, and P1 and P4.
  • Then the exchange P1-P2 results in two
    transplantations, but the exchanges P1-P4 and
    P2-P3 results in four.

47
Summary (for economists)
  • As game theorists start to take a more active
    role in practical market design, we have to deal
    with constraints, demands, and situations
    different than those that arise in the simplest
    theoretical models of mechanism design
  • Here we address some of the issues that have come
    up as we try to help surgeons implement an
    organized exchange of live-donor kidneys
  • Not only do these issues appear to allow
    satisfactory practical solutions, they suggest
    new directions in which to pursue the underlying
    theory.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com