Title: Individual Demand Curves
1Chapter 3
2Individual Demand Curves
- This chapter studies how people change their
choices when conditions such as income or changes
in the prices of goods affect the amount that
people choose to consume. - This chapter then compares the new choices with
those that were made before conditions changed - The main result of this approach is to construct
an individuals demand curve
3Demand Functions
- If we knew a persons preferences and all the
economic forces that affect his or her choices,
we could predict how much of each good would be
chosen. - This summarizes this information in a demand
function a representation of how quantity
demanded depends on prices, income, and
preferences.
4Demand Function
- The three elements that determine the quantity
demanded are the prices of X and Y, the persons
income (I), and the persons preferences for X
and Y. - Preferences appear to the right of the semicolon
because we assume that preferences do not change
during the analysis.
5Homogeneous Demand Function
- Individual demand functions are homogeneous since
quantity demanded does not change when prices and
income increase in the same proportion. - The budget constraint PXX PYY I is identical
to the budget constraint 2PXX 2PYY 2I. - Graphically the lines are the same.
6Changes in Income
- When a persons income increase, while prices
remain the same, the quantity purchased of each
good might increase. - This situation is shown in Figure 3.1 where the
increase in income is shown as the budget line
shifts out from I1 to I2 to I3. - The slope of the budget lines are the same since
the prices have not changed .
7FIGURE 3.1 Effect of Increasing Income on
Quantities of X and Y Chosen
Quantity of Y per week
Y1
U1
I1
Quantity of X per week
X1
0
8FIGURE 3.1 Effect of Increasing Income on
Quantities of X and Y Chosen
Quantity of Y per week
Y2
U2
Y1
U1
I2
I1
Quantity of X per week
X1
0
X2
9FIGURE 3.1 Effect of Increasing Income on
Quantities of X and Y Chosen
Quantity of Y per week
Y3
Y2
U3
U2
Y1
U1
I2
I3
I1
Quantity of X per week
X1
0
X2
X3
10Changes in Income
- In response to the increase in income the
quantity of X purchased increases from X1 to X2
and X3 while the quantity purchased of Y also
increases from Y1 to Y2 to Y3. - Increases in income make it possible for a person
to consume more reflected in the outward shift in
the budget constraint that allows an increase in
overall utility.
11Normal Goods
- A normal good is one that is bought in greater
quantities as income increases. - If the quantity increases more rapidly than
income the good is called a luxury good as with
good Y in Figure 3.1. - If the quantity increases less rapidly than
income the good is called a necessity good as
with good X in Figure 3.1.
12APPLICATION 3.1 Engels Law
- One important generalization about consumer
behavior is that the fraction of income spent on
food tends to decline as income increases. - This finding was discovered by Prussian
economists Ernst Engel (1821-1896). - Table 1 show Engels data with Table 2 showing
recent data for U.S. consumers.
13TABLE 1 Percentage of Total Expenditures of
Various Items in Belgian Families in 1853
14TABLE 2 Percentage of Total Expenditures by U.S.
Consumers on Various Items, 2000
15Inferior Goods
- An inferior good is one that is bought in smaller
quantities as income increases. - In Figure 3.2 as income increases from I1 to I2
to I3, the consumption of inferior good Z
decreases. - Goods such as rotgut whiskey, potatoes, and
secondhand clothing are examples of inferior
goods.
16FIGURE 3.2 Indifference Curve Map Showing
Inferiority
Quantity of Y per week
Y1
U1
I1
Z1
Quantity of Z per week
0
17FIGURE 3.2 Indifference Curve Map Showing
Inferiority
Quantity of Y per week
Y2
U2
Y1
U1
I2
I1
Z2
Z1
Quantity of Z per week
0
18FIGURE 3.2 Indifference Curve Map Showing
Inferiority
Quantity of Y per week
Y3
U3
Y2
U2
Y1
U1
I1
I2
I3
Z2
Z1
Quantity of Z per week
Z3
0
19Changes in a Goods Price
- A change in the price of one good causes both the
slope and an intercept of the budget line to
change. - The change also involves moving to a new
utility-maximizing choice on another indifference
curve with a different MRS. - The quantity demanded of the good whose price has
changed changes.
20Substitution Effect
- The part of the change in quantity demanded that
is caused by substitution of one good for another
is called the substitution effect. - This results in a movement along an indifference
curve. - Consumption has to be changed to equate MRS to
the new price ratio of the two goods.
21Income Effect
- The part of the change in quantity demanded that
is caused by a change in real income is called
the income effect. - The price change also changes real purchasing
power and consumers will move to a new
indifference curve that is consistent with this
new purchasing power.
22Substitution and Income Effects from a Fall in
Price
- As shown in Figure 3.3, when the price of good X
falls, the budget line rotates out from the
unchanged Y axis so that the X intercept lies
father out because the consumer can now buy more
X with the lower price. - The flatter slope means that the relative price
of X to Y (PX/PY) has fallen.
23Substitution Effect from a Fall in Price
- The consumer was originally maximizing utility at
X, Y in Figure 3.3. - After the fall in the price of good X, the new
utility maximizing choice is X, Y. - The substitution effect is the movement on the
original indifference curve to point B.
24FIGURE 3.3 Income and Substitution Effects of a
Fall in Price
Quantity of Y per week
Y
U1
X
0
Quantity of X per week
25FIGURE 3.3 Income and Substitution Effects of a
Fall in Price
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
Y
B
New budget constraint
U1
X
XB
0
Quantity of X per week
Substitution effect
26FIGURE 3.3 Income and Substitution Effects of a
Fall in Price
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
Y
Y
U2
B
New budget constraint
U1
Quantity of X per week
X
XB
X
0
Substitution effect
Income effect
Total increase in X
27Substitution Effect from a Fall in Price
- If the individual had to stay on the U1 with the
new price ratio, the consumer would choose B
since that is the point where the MRS is equal to
the slope of the new budget line (shown by the
dashed line). - Staying on the same indifference curve is the
same as holding real income constant. - The consumer buys more good X.
28Income Effect
- The movement from point B to X, Y results
from the increase in purchasing power. - Because PX falls but nominal income (I) remains
the same, the individuals real income
increases so that he or she can be on utility
level U3. - The consumer buys more good X.
29The Effects Combined
- Using the hamburger-soft drink example from
Chapter 2, suppose the price of soft drinks falls
from .50 to .25. - Previously the consumer could purchase up to 20
soft drinks, but now he or she can purchase up to
40. - This price decrease shifts the budget line
outward and increases utility.
30The Effects Combined
- If the consumer bought his or her previous choice
it would now cost 7.50 so that 2.50 would be
unspent. - If the individual stayed on the old indifference
curve he or she would equate MRS to the new price
ratio (consuming 1 hamburger and 4 soft drinks). - This move is the substitution effect.
31The Effects Combined
- Even with constant real income the consumer will
buy more soft drinks since the opportunity cost
of eating a burger in terms of the soft drinks
forgone is now higher. - Since real income has increased the person will
choose to buy more soft drinks so long as soft
drinks are a normal good.
32Substitution and Income Effects from an Increase
in Price
- An increase in PX will shift the budget line in
as shown in Figure 3.4. - The substitution effect, holding real income
constant, is the move on U2 from X, Y to point
B. - Because the higher price causes purchasing power
to decrease, the movement from B to X, Y is
the income effect.
33FIGURE 3.4 Income and Substitution Effects of an
Increase in Price
Quantity of Y per week
U2
New budget constraint
Y
Old budget constraint
Quantity of X per week
X
0
34FIGURE 3.4 Income and Substitution Effects of an
Increase in Price
Quantity of Y per week
U2
U1
B
New budget constraint
Y
Old budget constraint
Quantity of X per week
XB
X
0
Substitution effect
35FIGURE 3.4 Income and Substitution Effects of an
Increase in Price
Quantity of Y per week
U2
U1
B
Y
New budget constraint
Y
Old budget constraint
Quantity of X per week
X
XB
X
0
Income effect
Substitution effect
Total reduction in X
36Substitution and Income Effects from an Increase
in Price
- In Figure 3.4, both the substitution and income
effects cause the individual to purchase less
soft drinks do to the higher price of soft drinks.
37Substitution and Income Effects for a Normal
Good Summary
- As shown in Figures 3.3 and 3.4, the substitution
and income effects work in the same direction
with a normal good. - When the price falls, both the substitution and
income effects result in more purchased. - When the price increases, both the substitution
and income effects result in less purchased.
38Substitution and Income Effects for a Normal
Good Summary
- This provides the rational for drawing downward
sloping demand curves. - This also helps to determine the steepness of the
demand curve. - If either the substitution or income effects are
large, the change in quantity demanded will be
large with a given price change.
39Substitution and Income Effects for a Normal
Good Summary
- If the substitution and income effects are small,
the effect of a given price change in the
quantity demanded will also be small. - This kind of analysis also offers a number of
insights about some commonly used economic
statistics.
40APPLICATION 3.2 The Consumer Price Index and Its
Biases
- The Bureau of Labor Statistics monthly calculates
the Consumer Price Index (CPI) which is a
principal measure of inflation in the U.S.. - To construct the CPI, a typical market basket of
commodities purchased by consumers in the base
year (currently 1982) is calculated.
41APPLICATION 3.2 The Consumer Price Index and Its
Biases
- The ratio of the current cost of the basket to
the base year price is the measure of the value
of the CPI. - The rate of change in the CPI between two periods
is the reported rate of inflation.
42An Algebraic Example
- Suppose the 1982 typical market basket contained
X82 of good X and Y82 of good Y. - The prices of these goods are and
- The cost of this bundle in the 1982 base year
would be written as
43An Algebraic Example
- To compute the cost of the same bundle of goods
in, say 2002, requires that we compute the cost
of the bundle using current prices
44An Algebraic Example
- The CPI is defined as the ratio of the costs of
these two market baskets - If the basket cost 100 in 1982 prices and 180
in 2002, the value of the CPI would be 1.80 and
with a measured 80 percent increase in prices
over the 20 year period.
45Substitution Bias in the CPI
- The CPI does not take into account the real
possibility that consumers would substitute among
commodities because of changes in relative
prices. - In Figure 1, the typical individual is initially
consuming X82, Y82 maximizing utility on U1 with
1982 constraint I.
46FIGURE 1 Substitution Bias of the Consumer Price
Index
Quantity of Y per year
Y82
U1
I
I
I
0
Quantity of X per year
X82
47Substitution Bias in the CPI
- Suppose the 2002 relative prices change so that
PX/PY falls. - The cost of the 1982 bundle in terms of 2002
prices is reflected in the constraint I which is
flatter and goes though the 1982 bundle. - The consumer would substitute X for Y and stay on
U1 on budget line I.
48Substitution Bias in the CPI
- Since I is inside I (which is used to compute
the CPI), the CPI tends to overstate the
inflation rate. - Unfortunately, adjusting the CPI to take such
substitution into account is difficult because it
would require that we know the utility function
of the typical consumer.
49New Product Bias in the CPI
- New products typically experience sharp declines
in prices and rapidly grow in rates of
acceptance. - If the CPI does not include these new products,
this source of welfare increase is omitted. - The CPI basket is revised but not rapidly enough
to eliminate this bias.
50Outlet Bias in the CPI
- The typical basket is bought at the same retail
outlets every month. - This method can omit the benefits of sales or
other bargains. - The CPI does not currently take such
price-reducing strategies and thus tends to
overstate inflation.
51Consequences of the CPI Biases
- Measuring and correcting for these biases is not
an easy task. - The CPI is such a widely used measure of
inflation that any change becomes a hot political
issue. - However, there is a general agreement that the
CPI overstates inflation by as much as 0.75 to
1.0 percent per year.
52Consequences of the CPI Biases
- Politicians have proposed caps on Cost of Living
Adjustments (COLAs) tied to the CPI on government
programs, but none have yet been enacted. - However, the private sector has adjusted so that
few private COLAs provide full offsets to
inflation measured by the CPI.
53Substitution and Income Effects for Inferior Goods
- With an inferior good, the substitution effect
and the income effects work in opposite
directions. - The substitution effect results in decreased
consumption for a price increase and increased
consumption for a price decrease.
54Substitution and Income Effects for Inferior Goods
- The income effect results in increased
consumption for a price increase and decreased
consumption for a price decrease. - Figure 3.5 shows the two effects for an increase
in PX. - The substitution effect, holding real income
constant, is shown by the move from X, Y to
point B both on U2.
55FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
Quantity of Y per week
Y
U2
Old budget constraint
0
Quantity of X per week
X
56FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
Quantity of Y per week
B
New budget constraint
Y
U2
Y
Old budget constraint
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
57FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
Quantity of Y per week
B
New budget constraint
Y
U2
Y
Old budget constraint
Xb
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
X
58Substitution and Income Effects for Inferior Goods
- The income effect reflects the reduced purchasing
power due to the price increase. - Since X is an inferior good, the decrease in
income results in an increase in the consumption
of X shown by the move from point B on U1 to the
new utility maximizing point X, Y on U1.
59Substitution and Income Effects for Inferior Goods
- Since X is less than X the price increase in X
results in a decrease in the consumption of X. - This occurs because the substitution effect, in
this example, is bigger than the income effect. - Thus, if the substitution effect dominates, the
demand curve is negatively sloped.
60Giffens Paradox
- If the income effect of a price change is strong
enough with an inferior good, it is possible for
the quantity demanded to change in the same
direction as the price change. - Legend has it that this phenomenon was observed
by English economist Robert Giffen.
61Giffens Paradox
- When the price of potatoes rose in Ireland the
consumption of potatoes also increased. - Potatoes were not only an inferior good but
constituted the source of a large portion of
Irish peoples income. - The situation I which an increase in a goods
price leads people to consume more of the good is
called Giffens paradox.
62FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
Quantity of Y per week
B
New budget constraint
Y
U2
Y
Old budget constraint
Xb
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
X
63FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for
an Inferior Good
Quantity of Y per week
B
New budget constraint
Y
U2
Y
Old budget constraint
Xb
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
X
64FIGURE 3.5 Income and Substitution Effects for a
Giffen Good
Quantity of Y per week
New budget constraint
B
Y
U2
Old budget constraint
Y
U1
Xb
0
Quantity of X per week
X
X
65The Lump Sum Principle
- The lump-sum principle hold that taxes that are
imposed on general purchasing power will have a
smaller welfare costs than will taxes imposed on
a narrow selection of commodities. - Consider Figure 3.6 where the individual
initially has I dollars to spend and chooses to
consume X and Y yielding U3 utility.
66FIGURE 3.6 The Lump-Sum Principle
Quantity of Y
I
Y
U3
Quantity of X per week
X
67The Lump Sum Principle
- A tax on only good X raises its price resulting
in budget constraint I and consumption reduced
to X1, Y1 and utility level U1. - A general income tax that generates the same
total tax revenue is represented by budget
constraint I that goes though X1, Y1.
68FIGURE 3.6 The Lump-Sum Principle
Quantity of Y
I
Y1
Y
I
Y2
U3
U1
Quantity of X per week
X1
X
69FIGURE 3.6 The Lump-Sum Principle
Quantity of Y
I
Y1
Y
I
I
Y2
U3
U2
U1
Quantity of X per week
X1
X2
X
70The Lump Sum Principle
- The utility maximizing choice on I is X2, Y2
yielding utility level U2. - The lump-sum general income tax generates the
same amount of tax revenue but leaves the
consumer on a higher utility level (U2) than the
utility level associated with the tax only on
good X (U1).
71The Lump Sum Principle
- The intuitive explanation of the lump-sum
principle is that a single-commodity tax affects
people in two ways - it reduces their purchasing power,
- it directs consumption away from the good being
taxed. - The lump-sum tax only has the first of these two
effects.
72Generalizations of the Lump-Sum Principle
- The utility lass associated with the need to
collect a certain amount of tax revenue will be
minimized by taxing goods for which the
substitution effect is small. - Even though the tax will reduce purchasing power,
it will minimize the impact of directing
consumption away from the good being taxed.
73APPLICATION 3.3 Wouldnt Cash Be a Better Way to
Help Poor People?
- The lump-sum principle suggests that the trends
in expanding in-kind programs may be unfortunate - These programs do not generate as much welfare
for people as would the spending of the same
funds in a cash program
74APPLICATION 3.3 Wouldnt Cash Be a Better Way to
Help Poor People?
- In Figure 1 a subsidy on good X (constraint I)
raises utility to U2 - For the same funds, an income grant (I) raises
utility to U3
75FIGURE 1 The Superiority of an Income Grant
Y per period
I
U3
I
B
U2
I
U1
X per period
76Changes in the Price of Another Good
- When the price of one good changes, it usually
has an effect on the demand for the other good. - The decrease in the price of X (a normal good)
caused both an income and substitution effect
that caused an increase in the quantity demanded
of X.
77Income and Substitution Effects of a Fall in Price
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
Y
Y
U2
B
YB
New budget constraint
U1
Quantity of X per week
X
XB
X
0
Substitution effect
Income effect
Total increase in X
78Changes in the Price of Another Good
- In addition, the substitution effect caused a
decrease in the demand for good Y as the consumer
substituted good X for good Y. - However, the increase in purchasing power brought
about by the price decrease causes an increase in
the demand for good Y (also a normal good).
79Changes in the Price of Another Good
- Since, in this case, the income effect had a
dominant effect on good Y, the consumption of Y
increased due to a decrease in the price of good
X. - With flatter indifference curves as shown in
Figure 3.7, the situation is reversed. - A decrease in the price of good X causes a
decrease in good Y, as before.
80FIGURE 3.7 Effect on the Demand for Good Y of a
Decrease in the Price of Good X
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
Y
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
81FIGURE 3.7 Effect on the Demand for Good Y of a
Decrease in the Price of Good X
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
A
Y
New budget constraint
B
U2
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
82FIGURE 3.7 Effect on the Demand for Good Y of a
Decrease in the Price of Good X
Quantity of Y per week
Old budget constraint
A
Y
C
Y
New budget constraint
B
YB
U2
U1
0
Quantity of X per week
X
X
83Substitutes
- Substitutes are goods that are used for
essentially the same purpose. - Two goods such that if the price of one
increases, the demand for the other rises are
substitutes. - If the price of one good decreases and the demand
for the other good decreases, they are also
substitutes.
84Complements
- Complements are goods that go together in the
sense that people will increase their use of both
goods simultaneously. - Two goods are complements if an increase in the
price of one causes a decrease in the quantity
demanded of the other or a decrease in the price
of one good causes an increase in the demand for
the other.
85APPLICATION 3.4 Why Are So Many Trucks on the
Road?
- In the 1990s, virtually all new vehicle
registrations were trucks, mostly SUVs - Sharp decline in real gasoline prices
- In 1980s, gas cost 1.5 per gallon
- In 1999, it cost 1.1 per gallon
- Adjusted for inflation, it is a fall of 40 in
real terms - Opportunity costs of operating trucks has thus
decreased, causing substitution effect - Regulation Corporate Average Fuel Economy
standards did not cover SUVs - By September 2005, 1 gallon of gas cost 3.00
- Sales of large SUVs slumped in 2004-2005
- By 2005 the CAFE standards started to include
SUVs as well
86Construction of Individual Demand Curves
- An individual demand curve is a graphic
relationship between the price of a good and the
quantity of it demanded by a person holding all
other factors (preferences, the prices of other
goods, and income) constant. - Demand curves limit the study to the relationship
between the quantity demanded and changes in the
own price of the good.
87FIGURE 3.8 Construction of an Individuals
Demand Curve
Quantity of Y
per week
Budget constraint for P
9
X
U
1
Quantity of X
X
0
per week
(a) Individual
s indifference curve map
Price
PX
Quantity of X
X
0
per week
(b) Demand curve
88FIGURE 3.9 Construction of an Individuals
Demand Curve
Quantity of Y
Budget constraint for PX
per week
Budget constraint for PX
U
2
U
1
Quantity of X
X
X
X
0
per week
(a) Individual
s indifference curve map
Price
PX
PX
Quantity of X
X
X
0
per week
(b) Demand curve
89FIGURE 3.8 Construction of an Individuals
Demand Curve
Quantity of Y
Budget constraint for PX
per week
Budget constraint for PX
Budget constraint for PX
U
3
U
2
U
1
Quantity of X
X
X
X
0
per week
(a) Individual
s indifference curve map
Price
P
9
X
P
0
X
P
-
X
Quantity of X
X
X
X
0
per week
(b) Demand curve
90FIGURE 3.8 Construction of an Individuals
Demand Curve
Quantity of Y
Budget constraint for PX
per week
Budget constraint for PX
Budget constraint for PX
U
3
U
2
U
1
Quantity of X
X
X
X
0
per week
(a) Individual
s indifference curve map
Price
P
9
X
P
0
X
P
-
X
d
X
Quantity of X
X
X
X
0
per week
(b) Demand curve
91Substitutes and Flat Demand
- If a good, say X, has close substitutes, a
increase in its price will cause a large decrease
in the quantity demanded as the substitution
effect will be large. - The demand curve for a type of breakfast cereal
will likely be relatively flat due to the strong
substitution effect.
92Lack of Substitutes and Steep Demand
- If the good has few substitutes, the substitution
effect of a price increase or decrease will be
small and the demand curve will be relatively
steep. - Water is an example of a good with few
substitutes.
93Special Case Food
- Food has no substitutes so it might be thought
that no change in consumption would occur with a
price increase. - But food constitutes a large part of an
individuals budget so that price changes will
cause relatively larger effects on the quantity
demanded that might be thought due to the income
effect.
94FIGURE 3.9 Shifts in Individuals Demand Curve
PX
PX
PX
P1
P1
P1
X
X
X
X1
X1
X1
X2
X2
X2
0
0
0
(a)
(b)
(c)
95FIGURE 3.10 Shifts in Individuals Demand Curve
PX
PX
PX
P1
P1
P1
X
X
X
X1
X1
X1
X2
X2
X2
0
0
0
(a)
(b)
(c)
Normal Good
Good X is a substitute with Y, and the price of Y
increases
Good X is a complement to Y, and the price of Y
increases
96Shifts in an Individuals Demand Curve
- Changes in preferences can also shift demand
curves. - Demand could shift rightward as a result for an
increased preference for cold drinks when a
sudden hot spell occurs. - Increased environmental consciousness during the
1980s and 1990s increased the demand for
recycling and organic food.
97APPLICATION 3.5 Fads, Seasons, and Health Scares
- Fads (bandwagon effects)
- Widespread use causes additional demand
- When saturation point is reached, demand rapidly
dwindles - Impossible to predict which products will catch
on - Seasonality
- Easy to predict seasonal demand Christmas trees,
turkeys for Thanksgiving etc - Cod in high demand during Lent Catholic
requirements on dietary restrictions
98Health Scares
- Smoking reduction in the US after the surgeon
generals report in 1964 - Cholesterol decline in demand for beef and dairy
products, also eggs - 1982 Tylenol accident
- Cyanide tablets inserted in a few Tylenol bottles
- Dramatic drop in demand followed for Tylenol
(50) - 1988 cyanide injection in Chilean grapes
- 1993 study on fat content in Chinese food,
Chinese restaurants suffered - Krispy Kreme stock in 2000, 1997 European demand
for US beef
99Be Careful in Using Terminology
- A movement downward along a stationary demand
curve in response to a fall in price is called an
increase in quantity demanded while a rise in the
price of the good results in a decrease in
quantity demanded. - A rightward shift in a demand curve is called an
increase in demand while a leftward shift is a
decrease in demand.
100Consumer Surplus
- The extra value individuals receive from
consuming a good over what they pay for it is
called consumer surplus. - Consumer surplus is also what people would be
willing to pay for the right to consume a good at
its current price. - This concept is used to study the welfare effects
of price changes.
101Consumer Surplus
- In graphical terms, consumer surplus is given by
the area below the demand curve and above the
market price. - In Figure 3.11, total consumer surplus is given
by area AEB (80).
102FIGURE 3.11 Consumer Surplus from T-Shirt Demand
Price (/shirt)
Price (/shirt)
A
15
11
9
E
B
d
Quantity (shirts)
15
10
20
103Consumer Surplus and Utility
- Figure 3.12 illustrates the connection between
consumer surplus and utility
104FIGURE 3.11 Consumer Surplus and Utility
Initially, the person is at E with utility
U1. He or she would need to be compensated by
amount AB in other goods to get U1 if T-shirts
were not available.
Other Goods
A
B
The individual would be willing to pay BC for the
right to consume T-shirts rather than spending I
only on other goods.
C
E
U1
I
U0
Both distance AB and BC approximate the consumer
surplus area
I
Quantity (shirts)
20
105Application 3.6 Valuing New Goods
Price
Only the point E is known right after the
introduction of a new product
Consumer surplus from the introduction of a new
product
Economists developed methodologies to determine
the tangency to an indifference curve that is not
observed!
E
New Good
106New Goods
- Cell Phones
- Gains estimated to be 50 billion
- Not entered into CPI until after 15 years after
introduction - Minivans introduced in the US in the 1980s
- Gains of 3 billion over 1984-1988
- Active competition among minivan suppliers
contributed to this welfare increase