Title: Neoliberalism and the Developmental State in Asia
1Neoliberalism and the Developmental State in Asia
2The Asian Story
- Different countries in Asia have served as
example of development success with transition
from low to middle and even developed country
status. - Japan the first Asian success.
- But three tiers of development after Japan
- First tier Korea and Taiwan.
- Second tier Malaysia, Indonesia, Thailand
- Third tier China (and India?)
3The success of Asian late industrializers
- Between 1970 and 1995, the share of the
industrialised countries in global manufacturing
value added fell from 85 to about 78 per cent,
while developing countries registered an increase
in their share from 10 to 20 per cent - Almost all of this shift in manufacturing
production was to countries in East and Southeast
Asia, the combined share of which more than
doubled from 4 per cent to 11 per cent over this
period
4The paradox
- Early Asian success was attributed by many to the
Developmental State which got prices wrong
Japan, Korea and Taiwan. But this too privileged
growth based on exports. - Subsequent tiers of industrialization were seen
as founded on letting markets work or adopting
neoliberal policies. - Support from the1997 crisis and subsequent
trajectory of the early miracles? - With the transition in China and India, Asia
became the showcase for neoliberalism when it had
failed elsewhere.
5Amsden and late industrialization
- Countries that industrialize without the
competitive edge of a monopolized original
technology - Different from countries that experienced the
first and second industrial revolutions. Former
had the benefit of invention (search for new
products and processes), the latter of innovation
(mass commercialization of invention). - The mode of late industrialization has been one
of borrowing technology from more technically
advanced societies, or what may be called
learning. - True of all successful industrializers in Asia,
including Japan
6Similarities
- Important role for the State even if with
differences. The state in Korea, Japan and Taiwan
has been more effective than other
late-industrializing countries because it has had
the power to discipline big business, and thereby
to dispense subsidies to big business according
to a more effective set of allocative principles.
- Intervention rather than market determines
prices interest rates, exchange rates, export
subsidies, directed credit, etc. If the metaphor
of the First Industrial Revolution is laissez
faire, and that of the Second infant industry
protection, then that of late industrialization
is a category comprehensive enough to overcome
the penalties of latenesscall it the subsidy.
7The interpretation
- Industrialization is constrained by demand, both
internally and externally. - Any country, particularly a small one, can
produce without regard to the size of its home
market, so long as it can export. The problem is
that most Third World countries cannot export
because they are not competitive internationally,
despite low wage rates problem is that raising
productivity and creating international
competitiveness, not effective demand - Issue not one of inadequate effective demand, but
of too much. What is needed is more foreign
exchange, savings and public revenues for these,
and not effective demand, are the constraints on
exoanding the pie.
8The Korean case
- High profits in Koreas mass-production
industries have been derived not merely from
investments in machinery and modern work methods
(what Marx calls relative surplus-value
extraction and what the school of regulation
calls an intensive regime) but also from the
worlds longest working week (what Marx calls
absolute surplus-value extraction and what the
regulationists call an extensive regime). - In Korea these two forms of profit making operate
side by side, and characterize the same group of
workers simultaneously. Land reforms also plays a
role.
9Differentiating features
- Central coordination linked to broad
diversification may be a unique competitive
advantage, or scope economy, of late
industrializers, for it allows them to enter new
industries quickly and efficiently. - Subsidies in Korea (as in Japan and Taiwan) have
been allocated to big business according to the
principle of reciprocity, in exchange for
performance standards, whereas in other
late-industrializing countries subsidies have
tended to be dispensed as giveaways - The corporate office, inclusive of RD functions,
tends to be the strategic focus of companies that
compete on the basis of innovation, because it is
at the administrative level that new technology
is developed and marketed. By contrast, the shop
floor tends to be the strategic focus of firms
that compete on the basis of making borrowed
technology work.
10Challenge to export pessimism
- The fallacy of composition argument
- The price effect of UDC competition
- The state of the world economy argument
- The concentration of LIC exports
- The concentration of relocative FDI flows
- The obstacles to migrating from labour to
technology-intensive exports - Export dependence and the transient miracle
11The Indian alternative
- Export pessimism and import substitution
- Implications of geography and demography for the
size of the domestic market - The legacy of industrialization at Independence
- Commitment of the State
12Belied promise
- The share of manufacturing in GDP did rise from
around 9 per cent in 1950-51 to 13 per cent in
1966-67. But it did not cross the 14 per cent
mark for a little more than a decade after that,
and touched 16.4 per cent at its peak in 1996-97.
- In 1960, industry contributed 37 per cent of GDP
in Brazil, 45 per cent in China, 19 per cent in
India, 19 per cent in Indonesia, around 25 per
cent in South Korea, 19 per cent in Malaysia and
19 per cent in Thailand. By 1985, the figures
were 45 per cent in Brazil, 43 per cent in China,
26 per cent in India, 36 per cent in Indonesia,
39 per cent in South Korea, 39 per cent in
Malaysia, and 32 per cent in Thailand. By 2010,
industrys share fell in some (due to the rise of
services) but increased further in others. The
figures now were 28 per cent in Brazil, 47 per
cent in China, 27 per cent in India, 47 per cent
in Indonesia, 39 per cent in South Korea, 44 per
cent in Malaysia and 45 per cent in Thailand.
13Limits to growth
- Failure to implement land reform meant that mass
market for manufactures remained constrained and
the system was faced with an agricultural
constraint. - Failure to finance public expenditure with
taxation - Wage goods constraint
- Profit squeeze due to a rise in the product wage
in the non-agricultural sector - Inability to sustain public expenditure in the
context of persisting agricultural inflation.
14Is export-led constraint free?
- Not really for a number of reasons. Consider
Japan, Korea and the second-tier industrializers - Lose of cost competitiveness
- Infrastructural bottlenecks
- Exchange rate appreciation
- Shift to non-tradables and speculative investment
- Need to open up market, especially financial
markets - Implications for financial firms
- Vulnerability to boom bust cycles
- Impact on overleveraged firms
15Lessons from the 1997 crisis
- Limits to externally driven growth
- Banks and financial institutions are not merely
prone to over-exposure in individual markets, but
to exposure reflective of unsound financial
practices. - Corollary supply-side factors were likely to
result in boom-bust cycles in financial flows to
developing countries - Sudden and whimsical turn-around in flows can set
off currency speculation in the host country
16Increased MNC presence
- In current dollars, the value added of U.S. MNCs
grew at an average annual rate of 3.1 percent, to
3,593.0 billion in 2009 from 2,644.7 billion in
1999. - The value added of parents grew at an average
annual rate of 1.7 percent to 2,453.4 billion,
and the value added of foreign affiliates in U.S.
dollars grew at an average annual rate of 7.0
percent to 1,139.6 billion. - Faster growth abroad was concentrated in emerging
markets, such as China, Brazil, India, and
Eastern Europe.
17Lessons from the 1997 crisis 2
- When the surge in capital flows is reversed, a
massive liquidity crunch and a wave of
bankruptcies result in severe deflation. Asset
prices collapse and pave the wave for
international acquisitions of domestic firms at
low prices. - A crisis triggered by finance capital becomes the
prelude for conquest by international capital in
general, with substantial changes in the
ownership structure of domestic assets.
18(No Transcript)
19(No Transcript)
20US MNCs value added in 2009
21Annual percentage change in value added 1999-2009
22Some evidence on relocation
- Developing countries not a major beneficiary and
India not a major beneficiary among developing
countries. - Relocation can be be associated with very low
value addition in the exporting hub. - Chinas example suggests that this is likely to
be truer in large countries where MNC interest is
in the domestic market. - Implications for policy?
23The China experience
- The large increases in the value added of
affiliates in manufacturing in China were
widespread by industry and mainly reflected
expanded production to serve the large and
growing local market. - Roughly two-thirds of the total output of these
affiliates was sold to local customers in both
1999 and 2009. The share of these affiliates
total output that was sold to U.S. customers
actually declined to 10.2 percent in 2009 from
16.3 percent in 1999.
24Implications for Miracle growth
- Difficult to sustain
- Shifting location of the current miracle
- China and India recent favourites
25The age of finance
- Global finance after the 1970s
- The pressure to exploit the opportunity
- Understanding financial liberalisation
- Impact on cross border flows
- Implications for successful countries
26Reduced trade dependence?
- One striking feature of recent growth trends in
the region is that in most of the important
economies, net exports (or the excess of export
over imports) is not an important contributor to
GDP, and therefore a major stimulus to growth. - Amounted to less than 10 per cent of GDP in China
and Thailand and less than 5 per cent in Korea
during the 2000s. Malaysia is an outlier, with
its ratio of net exports to GDP fluctuating
between 16 and 23 per cent in this period. - The perception that the leading economies of the
Asian region are benefiting from a stimulus from
external markets is true, if at all, only of
China and to a much lesser extent Thailand.
27(No Transcript)
28Investment as driver
- The two countries that have been topping the
growth league tables in recent years, China and
India, have been recording increases in their
gross capital formation to GDP ratios. The ratio
for China is way above that in other countries,
approaching half of GDP in recent years. The
ratio in India rose sharply between 2001 and
2007, but is showing signs of slipping since. - While Indonesia, Korea and Thailand too have
recorded relatively high investment ratios, their
levels in the 25-30 per cent range are not such
as to warrant the conclusion that autonomous
investment has been the principal driver of
domestic demand.
29(No Transcript)
30Some implications
- However, in both China and India, questions have
arisen about the mode of financing such
investment, with excessive reliance on borrowing.
This is acceptable so long as the returns from
such investment are high enough to ensure a
profit after meeting interest and amortisation
costs. Initially, this may indeed be true. But as
a larger number of projects are brought into the
credit ambit, the share of projects offering
lower returns would rise. - This threatens the viability of the projects and
therefore the sustainability of the investment
boom and viability of the financial system as
well.
31Domestic demand Consumption
- In most Asian economies final consumption
expenditure contributes around 65 to 75 per cent
of GDP, serving as an important source of demand.
The exception is China. In China extremely high
investment rates have meant a decline in the
final consumption expenditure to GDP ratio from a
low of around 60 per cent to less than 50 per
cent in recent years. - It is in the other economies of the region that
consumption seems to matter as a source of demand
and inducement to investment.
32(No Transcript)
33Autonomous demand?
- Increased consumption, since it is tethered to
increases in income, is not normally seen as a
stimulus to investment and growth, but an outcome
of the latter. - However, there is one way in which consumption
can be autonomous in the sense that it is not
tethered to current income. That would be true if
a significant share of incremental consumption is
financed with credit. - Unfortunately, this kind of path is not
sustainable.
34Regime of accumulation
- Less noted associated tendency
- Similarity in the regime of accumulation
- Shift to dependence on growth led by household
debt financed expenditure away from public
expenditure - Substantial rise in household debt in more than
one Southeast Asian country - Worst off is South Korea but problem exists or
emerging elsewhere in Asia as well
35The South Korean problem
- In 2010 (2011 survey), six out of ten households
in Korea were in debt, and more than a third of
them were unable to meet their annual expenses
with their incomes - Debt also weighed heavy on current incomes. One
in every 10 households spent more than 40 per
cent of annual income on servicing that debt. - Having to borrow more to stay afloat, a large
proportion of households could be caught in a
debt trap that would force default.
36Magnitude of the problem
- Growth in household debt a longer-term
phenomenon. From KRW 210 trillion in 1997, the
debt of households in Korea rose to more than KRW
450 trillion in 2002 and stood at KRW 922
trillion at the end of June in 2012. - The ratio of household debt to net household
disposable income rose from less than 100 per
cent before the turn of the century, to the
3-digit mark in 2001, more than 140 per cent in
2006 and an unsustainable 160 per cent in 2011. - The 2011 figure is higher than the level that
prevailed in the United States before the
subprime crisis broke. - The household savings rate in what used to be a
high-saving nation fell from more than 15 per
cent before the 1997 crisis to around 10 per cent
in 2000 and a low of 2-3 per cent recently.
37Household loans in total loans()
38Three phases in Korea
- Directed credit from a predominantly public
banking system to private corporates in the
industrial sector. Finances investment otherwise
induced. - Shift (post financial liberalisation) of lending
away from productive investment to sectors like
the stock market, real estate and housing. Partly
financed with low-cost foreign finance.
Self-reinforcing up to a point. - Increase in lending to the retail sectorhousing,
automobile purchases and personal creditwith
securitisation and transfer of risk. Borrowing by
the bottom quintile in terms of income was
increasing the fastest. Based on expansion of the
universe of borrowers.
39Implications
- Displacement of exports and public expenditure
with debt financed household expenditure as
stimulus. - Credit expansion driven not by prior induced
investment (JR). Autonomous public expenditure
financed with debt and expansion of the universe
of private borrowers. - Requires liquidity expansion. Requires also
financial liberalisation that triggers shift to
fragmented credit assets, with no external
collateral and securitisation.
40Other instances
- In Malaysia too, the ratio of household debt to
GDP has risen from 33 per cent in 1997 to 78 per
cent in 2011. Household debt to disposable income
ratio at 140 per cent - Before the crisis households accounted for a
third of loans provided by the banking sector,
and credit to the corporate sector accounted for
67 per cent of loans outstanding. After the
crisis that ratio moved up and now stands well
above the 50 per cent mark. - Housing loans account for 55 per cent of
household debt, automobile loans for another 23
per cent and credit card advances for a little
more than 5 per cent.
41The Indian case
- Sharp increase in credit financed housing
investment and consumption, facilitated by
financial liberalization. - Credit served as a stimulus to industrial demand
in three ways - Financed a boom in investment in housing and real
estate. - Financed purchases of automobiles
- Expanded demand for consumer durables.
42Commercial Bank Credit Expansion
43(No Transcript)
44(No Transcript)
45(No Transcript)
46(No Transcript)
47China Debt finance and growth
- In the early 1990s Chinas government decided to
accelerate growth. With the mandate to raise
investment and promise of rewards if they did,
provincial leaders went on a spending spree. - The result was a borrowing and spending spree, to
finance not just infrastructure but large
prestige projects, which were not revenue
earning. They were helped by the fact that
provincial governments substantially influenced
appointments to and the operations of regional
bank branches. - The inflationary spiral that followed and the
evidence that provincial governments were finding
it difficult to service the debts they had
accumulated to finance these projects, led the
central government to ban borrowing by provincial
governments in 1994. But investemtn kept going
through LGFVs.
48The post-crisis stimulus
- Credit growth in China has accelerated since the
beginning of 2009, facilitated by the
governments decision to relax informal
quantitative limits on bank credit growth as a
response to the growth slowdown resulting from
the deceleration in export growth. The resulting
credit boom raised the level of net new bank
credit by 50 percent compared with its level 2008
as a whole. - Such credit has financed a surge in public
investment which when mandated by government is
not constrained by expectations of market demand
and profitability. But it has also hiked private
investment, particularly in real estate. A credit
surge of this kind encourages speculation, leads
to asset price inflation and runs the risk of
fuelling a bubble based on loans of poor quality.
49Property bubble
- According to a 2013 survey (by Gan Li), about 65
per cent of Chinas wealth is invested in real
estate. A lot of this investment could be
speculative with 42 per cent of housing demand in
the first half of 2012 coming from those who
already own at least one home. In many areas,
these new properties remain unoccupied,
indicating that some of the construction is in
areas where demand is low. This has led to price
declines that can be damaging since investment
has been financed by credit that needs to be
repaid.
50Debt burden
- According to an audit conducted in the middle of
2011 in the aftermath of stimulus spending, local
government-associated debt had risen to 1.65
trillion or around 27 per cent of Chinese GDP. In
comparison, central debt was estimated at around
20 per cent of GDP. The audit showed that that
outstanding local government debt rose by 62 per
cent in 2009 alone, when Rmb 9600 billion was
pumped into the system as part of the stimulus. - Overall, credit in China is estimated to have
risen from 130 to 210 per cent of GDP over the
last five years.
51Signs of trouble
- But the wisdom of concealing a proactive fiscal
policy, by making state-owned banks lend to
state-sponsored financing vehicles, which in turn
lend to state-backed projects is now in question.
Defaults are on the rise. - The five biggest banks which account for ore than
half of all bank loans, wrote off Rmb569 (9.5bn)
million in debts according to their 2013 results.
That was 127 per cent more than in 2012. - According to figures released recently by the
PBC, loans provided by trust companies that
populate the shadow banking sector rose by an
annual 23 per cent to touch RMB17.3 trillion
(2.9 trillion) or 30 per cent of credit advanced
in 2013. Around 650 billion of trust loans are
expected to fall due in 2014, raising the
possibility of further defaults in different
parts of the economy.
52Conclusion
- The regime of accumulation under neoliberalism
- It is indeed true that neoliberal policy has come
to play an important role in Asia. It has,
however, not succeeded everywhere. But only the
success stories receive attention despite the
1997 crisis. - Even among successes what is missed is that the
factors explaining the expansion of domestic
demand, which supports this growth, are not
necessarily sustainable.