Title: TRADING WITH THE WORLD
133
TRADING WITHTHE WORLD
CHAPTER
2Objectives
- After studying this chapter, you will able to
- Describe the trends and patterns in international
trade - Explain comparative advantage and explain why all
countries can gain from international trade - Explain why international trade restrictions
reduce the volume of imports and exports and
reduce our consumption possibilities - Explain the arguments that are used to justify
international trade restrictions and show how
they are flawed - Explain why we have international trade
restrictions
3Silk Routes and Sucking Sounds
- Since ancient times, people have expanded trading
as far as technology allowedMarco Polos silk
route between Europe and China is an example. - Many people fear free trade and some predicted a
giant sucking sound as jobs left the United
States for Mexico under the NAFTA. - Why do we trade with other nations?
- Do tariffs that restrict trade bring any benefits?
4Patterns and Trends in International Trade
- Imports are the good and services that we buy
from people in other countries. - Exports are the goods and services we sell to
people in other countries.
5Patterns and Trends in International Trade
- Trade in Goods
- Manufactured goods represent 55 percent of U.S.
imports and 68 percent of exports. - Raw materials and semi-manufactured materials
represent 14 percent of U.S. exports and 15
percent of imports. - The largest export item from the United States is
capital goods and the largest import item is
automobiles.
6Patterns and Trends in International Trade
- Trade in Services
- International trade in services such as travel,
transportation, and insurance is large and
growing. - Geographical Patterns of International Trade
- The United States trades with countries all over
the world, but its biggest trading partner is
Canada with 20 percent of U.S. exports and 17
percent of U.S. imports. - Japan is our second largest trading partner with
8 percent of our exports and 9 percent of our
imports.
7Patterns and Trends in International Trade
- Trends in the Volume of Trade
- In 1960, the United States exported 3.5 percent
of its total output and imported 4 percent of the
total amount that American spent on goods and
services. - In 2003, the United States exported 10 percent of
its total output and imported 15 percent of the
total amount that American spent on goods and
services.
8Patterns and Trends in International Trade
- Net Exports and International Borrowing
- The value of exports minus imports is called net
exports. - In 2003, imports exceeded exports in the United
States, so net exports were negative 500
billion. - When a country imports more than it exports, it
must borrow from foreigners or sell some of its
assets. - When a country exports more than it imports, it
must make loans to foreigners or buy some of
their assets.
9The Gains from International Trade
- Comparative advantage is the fundamental force
that generates trade between nations. - The basis for comparative trade is divergent
opportunity costs between countries. - Nations can increase the consumption of goods and
services when they allocate resources to the
production of those goods and services for which
they have a comparative advantage.
10The Gains from International Trade
- Opportunity Cost in Farmland
- Figure 33.1 shows the production possibilities
frontier for an imaginary country called Farmland.
11The Gains from International Trade
- Without international trade, Farmland produces
and consumes 15 billion bushels of grain and 8
million cars at point A. - The opportunity cost of a car is 9,000 bushels of
grain.
12The Gains from International Trade
- Opportunity Cost in Mobilia
- Figure 33.2 shows the production possibilities
frontier for another imaginary country called
Mobilia.
13The Gains from International Trade
- Without international trade, Mobilia produces and
consumes 18 billion bushels of grain and 4
million cars at point A'. - The opportunity cost of a car is 1,000 bushels of
grain.
14The Gains from International Trade
- Comparative Advantage
- Cars are cheaper for Mobilia to produce than for
Farmland, because less grain is given up to
produce each car. - Grain is cheaper for Farmland to produce than for
Mobilia because fewer cars are given up to
produce each bushel. - A country has a comparative advantage in
producing a good if it can produce that good at a
lower opportunity cost than any other country. - Farmland has a comparative advantage in producing
grain, and Mobilia has a comparative advantage in
producing cars.
15The Gains from International Trade
- The Gains from Trade Cheaper to Buy Than to
Produce - If Mobilia bought grain for the price that
Farmland produces it, Mobilia could buy 9,000
bushels of grain for 1 cara much lower price
than the opportunity cost of producing grain in
Mobilia. - If Farmland bought cars for what Mobilia pays for
them, Farmland could buy 1 car for 1,000 bushels
of graina much lower price than the opportunity
cost of producing cars in Farmland.
16The Gains from International Trade
- The Terms of Trade
- The quantity of grain that Farmland must pay
Mobilia for a car is called Farmlands terms of
trade with Mobilia. - Figure 33.3 shows how the forces of international
demand and supply determine the terms of trade
and the volume of trade.
17The Gains from International Trade
- With no international trade, Mobilia can produce
a car for 1,000 bushels of grain, so at that
price, it plans to sell no cars to Farmland. - But as the price rises above 1,000 bushels of
grain per car the quantity of cars supplied by
Mobilia increases.
18The Gains from International Trade
- With no international trade, Farmland can produce
a car for 9,000 bushels of grain, so at that
price, it plans to buy no cars from Mobilia. - But as the price falls below 9,000 bushels of
grain per car the quantity of cars demanded by
Farmland increases.
19The Gains from International Trade
- The equilibrium terms of trade (price) is 3,000
bushels of grain per car and 4 million cars are
exported by Mobilia and imported by Farmland.
20The Gains from International Trade
- Balanced Trade
- The number of cars exported by Mobilia equals the
number of cars imported by Farmland. Farmland
pays Mobilia with 12 billion bushels of grain
(four million cars multiplied by 3,000 bushels
for each car)Mobilia imports and Farmland
exports 12 billion bushels of grain. Trade is
balanced. - For each country, the value of exports equals the
value of imports4 million cars are worth the
same as 12 billion bushels of grain.
21The Gains from International Trade
- Changes in Production and Consumption
- Farmland buys cars at a lower price than it would
pay if it made them itself, and sells its grain
at a higher price. - Mobilia buys grain at a lower price than it would
pay if it grew the grain itself, and sells its
cars at a higher price. Everyone gains from
trade. - The production possibilities frontier illustrates
the production possibilities of a country, but it
does not show the consumption possibilities of a
country that engages in international trade.
22The Gains from International Trade
- Figure 33.4 shows how both countries gain from
trade.
23The Gains from International Trade
- Calculating the Gains from Trade
- Farmland increase its consumption of both cars
and grain by decreasing car production and
increasing grain production until its own
opportunity cost of producing cars equals that of
the world terms of trade and exchanging grain for
cars at those terms of trade. - Mobilia increases its consumption of both cars
and grain by increasing car production and
decreasing grain production until its own
opportunity cost of producing cars equals that of
the world terms of trade and exchanging cars for
grain at those terms of trade.
24The Gains from International Trade
- Gains for All
- Both countries gain by consuming output
combinations outside their respective production
possibilities frontier. - Trade does not create winners and losers.
- It creates only winners.
- Farmers selling grain and Mobilians selling cars
face increased demand and higher prices. - Farmers buying cars and Mobilians buying grain
face increased supply and lower prices.
25The Gains from International Trade
- Gains from Trade in Reality
- Gains from trade occur in the real global
economy. - The United States buys TVs and VCRs from Korea,
machinery from Europe, and fashion goods from
Hong Kong and in exchange for machinery, grain,
lumber, airplanes, computers, and financial
services. - Everyone gains from this trade.
- The combination of diverse preferences and
economies of scale create comparative advantages
that generate a large volume of international
trade in similar but differentiated products.
26International Trade Restrictions
- Governments restrict international trade to
protect domestic producers from competition by
using two main tools - Tariffs
- Nontariff barriers
- A tariff is a tax that is imposed by the
importing country when an imported good crosses
its international boundary. - A nontariff barrier is any action other than a
tariff that restricts international trade.
27International Trade Restrictions
- The History of Tariffs
- Figure 33.5 shows how the average tariff rate has
generally fallen over the last 70 years. - Average tariffs reached their peak of 20 percent
in 1933.
28International Trade Restrictions
- The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
is an agreement between nations to have a series
of trade negotiations, or rounds, to reduce
tariffs on international trade. - The United States joined GATT in 1947.
- Subsequent rounds of the GATT occurred in the
1960s, late 1970s and 1980s, resulting in gradual
decline in the average tariff rate in the United
States
29International Trade Restrictions
- The Uruguay round was the most ambitious and lead
to the creation of the World Trade Organization
(WTO). - The United States became a WTO member in 1994.
- WTO membership brings greater obligations to
follow the GATT rules governing trade.
30International Trade Restrictions
- In 1994, the United States became party to the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA),
under which trade barriers between Canada, Mexico
and the United States are being lowered. - The European Union (EU) is an organization of
European countries that have agreed to eliminate
trade barriers among them. - The Asia-Pacific Economic group (APEC) is another
agreement to reduce trade barriers among East
Asian countries, including China.
31International Trade Restrictions
- How Tariffs Work
- Tariffs increase the price that consumers of the
importing country must pay for imported goods or
services. - Figure 33.6 uses the Farmland and Mobilia example
to illustrate the effects of a tariff on car
imports into Farmland.
32International Trade Restrictions
- The supply of cars to Farmland decreases because
the tariff must be added to the price at which
Mobilia is willing to supply a given quantity. - The price rises, the quantity falls, and the
government collects the tariff revenue.
33International Trade Restrictions
- The supply curve shifts leftward and the vertical
distance between the free-trade supply curve and
the new supply curve equals the amount of the
tariff. - The price of a car in Farmland rises.
- The quantity of cars imported by Farmland
decreases. - The Farmland government collects tariff revenue.
- Resources use is inefficient.
- The value of exports changes by the same amount
as the value of imports and trade remains
balanced.
34International Trade Restrictions
- Nontariff Barriers
- There are two main types of non-tariff barriers
to trade. - A quota is a quantitative restriction on the
import of a particular good, which specifies the
maximum amount of the good that may be imported
in a given period of time. - A voluntary export restraint (VER) is an
agreement between two governments in which the
government of the exporting country agrees to
restrain the volume of its own exports.
35International Trade Restrictions
- How Quotas and VERs Work
- Figure 33.7 uses the Farmland and Mobilia example
to illustrate the effects of a quota on
automobiles imported into Farmland.
36International Trade Restrictions
- The quota limits the quantity that may be
imported. - At the quota quantity, buyers are willing to pay
more than the price that sellers are willing to
accept. - Importers profit by buying at a lower price than
the price at which they sell.
37International Trade Restrictions
- A quota can generate the same price, quantity,
and inefficiency as a tariff but with a quota,
the importer makes an economic profit equal to
what the government receives as tariff revenue
with a tariff. - A VER is similar to a quota except that the
exporter captures the economic profit.
38The Case Against Protection
- Despite the fact that free trade promotes
prosperity for all, trade is restricted. - It is often argued that international trade
should be restricted to - Protect national security
- Protect infant industries
- Punish dumping
- None of these arguments bear scrutiny.
39The Case Against Protection
- Other fatally flawed arguments for protection are
that it - Saves jobs
- Allows us to compete with cheap foreign labor
- Brings diversity and stability to our economy
- Penalizes nations with lax environmental
standards - Protects national culture
- Prevents rich nations from exploiting poor ones
40The Case Against Protection
- The National Security Argument
- The national security argument is that a country
must protect domestic industries that make
defense equipment and armaments, and those
industries that provide the raw material
necessary for defense production. - The argument is flawed for two reasons (1) In
time of war, there is no industry that does not
contribute to national defense, so it is a plea
for economic isolation. (2) It is less
inefficient to subsidize defense than to restrict
trade with a tariff.
41The Case Against Protection
- The Infant Industry Argument
- The infant-industry argument is that it is
necessary to protect a new industry from import
competition to enable it to grow into a mature
industry that can compete in world markets. - This argument is based on the concept of dynamic
competitive advantage, which can arise from
learning-by-doing.
42The Case Against Protection
- Learning-by-doing is a powerful engine of
productivity growth, but this fact does not
justify protection. - Government action is needed to encourage
learning-by-doing only when its benefits spill
over to other parts of the economy. - And even in this case, it is more efficient to
subsidize an infant industry than to protect it
by restricting trade.
43The Case Against Protection
- The Dumping Argument
- Dumping occurs when foreign a firm sells its
exports at a lower price than its cost of
production. - Dumping is seen as a justification for a tariff
to prevent a foreign firm driving domestic firms
out of business and then raising its price. - This argument is flawed because
- It is virtually impossible to determine a firms
costs - If there was a natural global monopoly, it would
be more efficient to regulate it than to impose a
tariff against it.
44The Case Against Protection
- Saves Jobs
- The idea that buying foreign goods costs domestic
jobs is wrong. - It destroys some jobs and creates other better
jobs. - It also increases foreign incomes and enables
foreigners to buy more domestic production. - Protection to save particular jobs is very costly.
45The Case Against Protection
- Allows us to Compete with Cheap Foreign Labor
- The idea that a high-wage country cannot compete
with a low-wage country is wrong. - Low-wage labor is less productive than high-wage
labor. - And wages and productivity tell us nothing about
the source of gains from trade, which is
comparative advantage.
46The Case Against Protection
- Brings Diversity and Stability
- The idea that protection brings diversity of
production and greater stability of income is
wrong. - A nation can achieve diversity and stability
through its international investments
47The Case Against Protection
- Penalizes Lax Environmental Standards
- The idea that protection is good for the
environment is wrong. - Free trade increases incomes and poor countries
have significantly lower environmental standards
than rich countries. - These countries cannot afford to spend as much on
the environment as a rich country can and
sometimes they have a comparative advantage at
doing dirty work, which helps the global
environment achieve higher environmental
standards.
48The Case Against Protection
- Protects National Culture
- The idea that trade restrictions protect the
national culture is wrong. - This argument is not heard in the United States
as much as it is heard in Canada and European
countries. - Many countries are afraid of the
Americanization of their culture through the
prominence of American films, television
programs, art, literature, and even cuisine in
world markets.
49The Case Against Protection
- Protecting cultural industries is a form of
rent seeking, using cultural identity to
eliminate competition from other culturally
related goods and services. - The surest way to eliminate a culture is to
impoverish a nation.
50The Case Against Protection
- Prevents Rich Countries from Exploiting Poorer
Countries - The idea that trade restrictions prevent rich
countries from exploiting poorer countries is
wrong. - Free trade is the best way of raising wages and
improving working conditions in poor countries.
51The Case Against Protection
- The most compelling argument against protection
is that it invites retaliation. - We saw retaliation to the Smoot-Hawley Act in the
United States during the Great Depression. - And we see it today as the world reacts to high
U.S. tariffs on steel and agriculture.
52Why Is International Trade Restricted?
- The two key reasons why international trade is
restricted are - Tariff revenue
- Rent seeking
53Why Is International Trade Restricted?
- Tariff Revenue
- It is costly for governments to collect taxes on
income and domestic sales. - It is cheaper for governments to collect taxes on
international transactions because international
trade is carefully monitored. - This source of revenue is especially attractive
to governments in developing nations.
54Why Is International Trade Restricted?
- Rent Seeking
- Rent seeking is lobbying and other political
activities that seek to capture the gains from
trade. - Despite the fact that protection is inefficient,
governments respond to the demands of those who
gain from protection and ignore the demands of
those who gain from free trade because protection
brings concentrated gains and diffused losses.
55Why Is International Trade Restricted?
- Compensating Losers
- The gains from free trade exceed the losses, and
sometimes free trade agreements address the issue
of the distribution of gains from trade by
compensating those who lose from free trade. - For example, under NAFTA, a 56 million fund was
created to support and retrain workers who lot
their jobs from foreign competition resulting
from the agreement.
56THE END