Title: Developing countries in the Doha Round
1Developing countries in the Doha Round
- Lecture 26
- Economics of Food Markets
- Alan Matthews
2- Effects of further agricultural trade
liberalisation on developing countries
3Developing countries harmed by OECD agricultural
subsidies
- Many studies purport to show
- Large gains from agricultural trade
liberalisation - Large share of gains accruing to developing
countries - All developing countries share in these gains
- Examples
- IMF 2002 128 billion, of which 30 billion to
DCs - Goldin et al 2003 364 billion, of which 176
billion to DCs - Anderson 2003 165 billion, of which 43 billion
to DCs - World Bank 2004 400-900 billion from total
trade liberalisation, more than half of which to
DCs, of which agriculture would account for 70
4Developing countries harmed by OECD agricultural
subsidies
- These numbers have been picked up by NGOs and
contribute to the widespread view that
protectionist agricultural policies in OECD
countries are mainly responsible for preventing
developing countries from benefiting from world
trade. - Cotton issue
5Revisionist views
- PE models (ATPSM) have always been more ambiguous
- Panagariya 2002
- The presumption that such liberalization will
broadly benefit the poor countries, implicit in
the allegations that agricultural subsidies in
the rich countries hurt the poor in developing
countries, is unlikely to be supported by closer
scrutiny in its unqualified form. - Charlton and Stiglitz 2004
- The existence of net losses for developing
countries in some areas of reform should not
imply that no reform is requiredrather it
suggests that a selective approach is needed.
6Recent World Bank estimatesAnderson, Martin, Van
der Mensbrugge, June 2005
USD billion 2015 Base case 2001 Scaled dynamics 2001 Compara-tive static GTAP elasticities GTAP elas fixed land
World 287.3 156.4 127.4 88.5 77.8
Dev countries 85.7 43.9 23.7 10.6 2.0
Sub Saharan Africa 4.8 2.8 0.7 0.2 -0.1
South Africa 1.3 0.8 0.7 0.5 0.4
Selected SSA countries 1.0 0.6 0.3 0.4 0.3
Rest of SSA 2.5 1.4 -0.2 -0.6 -0.8
7Impact of Doha Round agreement(Bouet et al.,
2004)
Change in production Agri-food exports Agri-food imports Returns to land Change in welfare
EU25 -1.57 2.7 12.8 -15.01 0.14
US -1.05 0.8 2.8 -0.21 0.07
Asia developed -2.08 11.8 9.6 -1.79 0.06
Cairns developed 3.66 12.8 2.8 1.08 0.04
Mediterranean 0.73 8.8 -1.5 0.77 -0.16
Cairns developing 1.25 10.4 -0.7 0.60 -0.07
China 0.01 13.2 10.1 0.30 0.15
RoW 0.64 6.8 -0.7 1.15 -0.08
South Asia -0.01 6.4 7.8 -0.10 0.15
SSA 0.76 4.7 -0.8 0.22 -0.05
World -0.39 6.1 6.0 - 0.09
8Achterbosch et al. 2004(dynamic GTAP model)
Million 1997 USD Million 1997 USD Million 1997 USD Per cent of GDP Per cent of GDP Per cent of GDP
Little Modest Full Little Modest Full
North Africa 67 625 1775 0.0 0.3 0.9
SSA -540 -502 704 -0.3 -0.2 0.3
South Africa -132 93 1223 -0.1 0.1 0.9
9Estimates of costs of OECD country agricultural
protectionism for developing countries
- Anderson 2001 12 billion
- Diao et al 2004 4-8 billion
- Tokarick 2003 4 billion
- Francois et al 2003 1-3.5 billion (from 50
liberalisation) - Anderson and Martin 2006 26 billion
- Hertel and Keeney 2005 9.5 billion
- Compare to net ODA flows of around 60 billion
10Channels of impact
- Main impact is through terms of trade effect
- Net exporters gain, net importers lose
- More generally, farmers gain and consumers lose
- Depends on degree of market integration
- Presumption that trade liberalisation is pro-poor
- Picture complicated by the role of preferences
for net exporting countries
11FAO World Agriculture Towards 2015/2030
12Impact of different agricultural support measures
- Message that market access matters is largely
valid, but - ..for some sub-Saharan African countries,
domestic subsidies may be more important (cotton,
tobacco, peanuts) - ..the unimportance of subsidies is influenced by
the Green Box status of various forms of direct
payments. If some trade distortion results from
such payments, impacts would be bigger
13Impact of different agricultural support measures
- On other hand, export subsidies (despite NGO
criticisms) now only important in dairy and sugar - Yes, such subsidies have iniquitous competition
effects, and are counter to WTO rules, but
overall positive impact on developing countries
of their elimination will be very limited
14Conclusions from empirical work
- Multilateral liberalisation in agriculture is an
important objective to pursue, but implications
for developing countries are more nuanced - The adverse effects of developed country
agricultural protection can be overstated,
particularly for least developed countries - For middle income countries, faced with high
protection, liberalisation means strong prospects
for competitive export sectors - For poorer countries, rising import prices,
preference erosion and more onerous standards
darken picture considerably, particularly under
partial reforms - Danger that crucial factors which will prevent
many of the poorest countries from benefiting
have not been properly addressed
15- The role of preferences and preference erosion
16The role of preferences
- Winters poisoning the debate
- Systemic criticisms
- Divert trade between developing countries
- Undermine support for multilateral system
- Preferences have no value
- Poorly utilised (restrictive rules of origin)
- Come attached with conditions
- Uncertain, subject to frequent changes
- Delay growth-promoting reforms
17Average applied bilateral tariffs, agricultural
sector, per cent, 2001
Tariffs applied by ? Applied to ? EU25 US Asia developed Cairns developed
EU25 - 5.8 22.2 15.7
US 16.2 - 28.9 5.1
Asia developed 12.5 3.7 - 6.2
Cairns developed 25.9 3.4 24.9 -
Mediterranean 7.3 4.0 14.1 3.7
Sub Saharan Africa 6.7 3.0 12.0 0.7
Cairns developing 18.3 3.8 24.0 5.9
China 13.5 5.1 21.7 8.7
South Asia 14.4 1.8 33.7 1.8
Rest of World 15.1 2.1 17.4 2.6
Average 16.7 4.7 22.5 10.8
18In fact, preferences are well utilisedEU
agri-food imports under various regimes, 2002
Regime Eligible regime imports 000 Euro Actual regime imports 000 Euro Apparent utilisation rate Effective utilisation rate Share of actual imports
Non-reciprocal preferential agreements 18,610 12,292 89 18.5
Cotonou 5,927 5,500 93 95 8.3
GSP regular 8,755 4,385 50 86 6.6
EBA 1,682 294 17 96 0.6
Reciprocal preferences
Med, CEECs, EEA 11,381 8,728 77
Non-preferential
Duty-free MFN 21,714 32.6
MFN tariff gt 0 4,200 6.3
Total EU imports 66,558 100
19In fact, preferences are well utilisedUS
agri-food imports under various regimes, 2002
Regime Eligible imports under regime 000 USD Actual imports under regime 000USD Apparent utilisation rate Effective utilisation rate Share of actual imports
Non-reciprocal preferential agreements 4,137 3,607 87 6.2
AGOA 162 137 85 85 0.2
GSP regular 2,456 1,415 58 94 2.4
Reciprocal preferences
NAFTA 11,616 11,531 99 19.8
Non-preferential
Duty-free MFN 29,047 49.8
MFN tariff gt 0 14,039 24.1
Total US imports 58,368 100
20and quite effective
- Mixed evidence from statistical studies
- Ozden and Reinhardt 2003, Stockel and Borrell,,
2001 argue preferences have no value - But number of studies argue the opposite
- Stevens and Kennan (2004)
- Wainio and Gehlhar (2004)
- Romalis (2003)
- Criticism of preferences driven by their systemic
effects risks depriving some developing countries
of something of real benefit to them
21Who loses from preference erosion in agriculture?
- Bulk of losses fall on a narrow set of highly
preferred countries with exports concentrated in
a handful of highly protected sectors bananas,
sugar, meat - Big losers are mostly small islands and most
sub-Saharan African states - Possibility that MFN trade liberalisation or
additional preferences could provide some
offsetting gains - Necessity of compensation package to ensure
balanced outcome to the Round?
22Where does the problem lie?
- Northern agricultural protectionism not a
significant explanation of the problems facing
the poorest countries to integrate into
international trade - Lack of regional integration (South-South
barriers) may be as/more important - Technical/SPS barriers which often prevent any
trade at all (EU restrictions on fish/shellfish
exports, new EU SPS controls, affect food as well
as primary produce)
23The Aid for Trade debate
- Aid for trade covers
- Trade policy formulation
- Trade facilitation
- Trade adjustment
- Trade-related infrastructure
- Various initiatives underway
- IMF Trade Integration Facility
- WTO and others, Integrated Framework
- Proposals for preference erosion fund
- Now part of the Doha Agenda
24- Should SDT be more differentiated?
25Why greater differentiation of special treatment
in agriculture?
- Negotiation demands
- US/EU joint proposal August 2003
- (please correct in written paper)
- Zoellick letter Jan 2004
- Lamy/Fischler letter May 2004
- Mandelson speech Feb 2005
- Main elements
- More competitive DCs should forego SDT
- Deeper SDT for wider range of DCs (G-90)
- More competitive DCs should also offer SDT to DCs
26Why greater differentiation of special treatment
in agriculture?
- Economic arguments
- One size does not fit all
- SDT should fit the purpose it is designed to
serve - More restrictive SDT will also be more generous
- Trade policy may be second best development
instrument - Example of dealing with price drop
- Targeting SDT reduces the negative externalities
of rule exemptions for system as a whole
27Why greater differentiation of special treatment
in agriculture?
- The argument for differentiation is that it will
lead to more generous SDT - Recent IPC proposal
- Least developed countries
- Lower middle income
- Upper middle income
- Possibility of appeal to move to lower category
28The status of the differentiation debate in
agriculture
- Developing countries opposed
- Despite variety of developing country groups
representing different interests - No mention in July 2004 Framework Agreement
- But can arise in negotiating any of the
individual modalities of the agriculture agreement
29Criteria for differentiation
- Country-based criteria
- Income per capita as proposed by the
International Policy Council - Food security-based criteria
- Classification of developing countries into
food-insecure and food-secure not a simple
technical issue - different indicators give different results
30Criteria for differentiation
- Swedish Board of Agriculture typology
- Food insecure (including LDCs)
- Developing countries with special need for rural
development - High income advanced developing countries with
low dependence on agriculture - Significant net food exporting countries
- (Brazil, Argentina, China, Thailand)
31Where greater differentiation would apply
- Market access issues
- Tariff reduction formula
- Special products
- Special Safeguard Mechanism
- Expanding Tariff Rate Quotas
- Domestic support disciplines
- Export competition disciplines
- Market access for least developed and other
developing countries
32Targeting food-insecure beneficiaries
- Focus on food security crops and
low-income/resource poor (LI/RP) farmers - Allow self-definition of food security crops on a
negative list approach within broad parameters - Great difficulty of defining LI/RP farmers and
monitoring whether policies are directed to these
farmers although it is an AoA recognised group
33Conclusions
- Doha Round meant to be a development round
- Developing countries dissatisfied with outcome of
Uruguay Round - Developing countries have conflicting interests
in the outcome - Can sufficient flexibility be offered to
developing countries while ensuring sufficient
negotiating gains for developed countries?