Macroeconomics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Macroeconomics

Description:

Has There Been a British House Price Bubble? Evidence from a regional panel Thursday 3 November 2005 Anthony Murphy John Muellbauer Gavin Cameron trends in real long ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:59
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 43
Provided by: GavinC4
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Macroeconomics


1
Has There Been a British House Price Bubble?
Evidence from a regional panel
Thursday 3 November 2005
Anthony Murphy John Muellbauer Gavin Cameron
2
trends in real long-term interest rates
  • World monetary policy has been extraordinarily
    relaxed since 2000, with interest rates falling
    to around 0 in Japan, 1 in the USA and 2 in
    Euroland.
  • But short-term interest rates have now rising in
    the UK, USA, Australia and Canada, with the
    markets predicting further monetary tightening
    over the next two years.
  • Meanwhile, in Japan and Europe, limited signs of
    economic recovery and some inflationary pressure
    have not yet led to any decisive moves in
    monetary policy.
  • Real long-term interest rates remain low 10
    year US Treasury securities yield 4.57 in
    nominal terms, and 10 year indexed yields are 2.
  • Possible explanations for continue low long-term
    rates global saving glut global investment
    shortfall excess liquidity heightened appetite
    for risk (qv. the Greenspan put).

3
Source Nickell (2005).
4
real house prices since 1970
  • Source BIS Quarterly Review, March 2004.

5
a view from the top
  • Thus, this vast increase in the market value of
    asset claims is in part the indirect result of
    investors accepting lower compensation for risk.
    Such an increase in market value is too often
    viewed by market participants as structural and
    permanent. To some extent, those higher values
    may be reflecting the increased flexibility and
    resilience of our economy. But what they perceive
    as newly abundant liquidity can readily
    disappear. Any onset of increased investor
    caution elevates risk premiums and, as a
    consequence, lowers asset values and promotes the
    liquidation of the debt that supported higher
    asset prices. This is the reason that history has
    not dealt kindly with the aftermath of protracted
    periods of low risk premiums, Alan Greenspan,
    August 2005.

6
bubbles in theory
  • Many theoretical arguments have been advanced to
    justify rational bubbles in asset markets,
    although this is not the focus of our paper. For
    example
  • The survival of noise traders in financial
    markets limits to arbitrage prevent rational
    traders from driving noise-traders out of the
    market (De Long, Shleifer, Summers, Waldmann,
    1990).
  • Asset markets are micro-efficient but
    macro-inefficient (Samuelson, 1998).
  • Global games dissatisfaction with common
    knowledge assumptions leads to games of
    incomplete information whose type space is
    determined by the players each observing a noisy
    signal of the underlying state. Differences
    between public and private information can drive
    selection between multiple equilibria (Morris and
    Shin, 2002).

7
features of good regional house price models
  • Regional house price models useful to address
  • The ripple effect from Greater London and the
    South East to the rest of Britain
  • Housing affordability in different regions
  • Policy issues relating to housing supply and
    migration.
  • Meen and Andrews (1998) suggest these features
  • Data-consistency, economic interpretation
  • Spatial lags, errors, coefficient heterogeneity
  • Plausible estimates of income and price
    elasticities
  • Clear implications for housing market efficiency
  • Explanation of the ripple effect and
    demographics.

8
preview of the model
  • We estimate an annual econometric model of
    regional house prices for the 9 regions of Great
    Britain between 1972 and 2003. The model is a
    system of inverted demand equations with the
    predetermined housing stock as an explanatory
    variable along with regional income, real and
    nominal interest rates, demographics and other
    demand shifters.
  • Our approach contrasts somewhat with two other
    recent approaches (structural time-series
    modelling, focussing on unit roots and
    cointegration and models of house price to
    rental ratios).
  • Our model can be viewed as an equilibrium-correcti
    on model with positive effects from recent rises
    in house prices (the so-called bubble-builder
    effect) and negative effects from high levels of
    real house prices relative to their fundamentals
    (the so-called bubble-burster effect).

9
the Nickell version
  • This discussion leads us to conclude that there
    has probably been a substantial rise in the
    equilibrium house price to earnings ratio since
    the mid-1990s. Of course, there is a good deal
    of uncertainty here, but it is clear that it may
    be legitimately argued that there has been no
    housing bubble whatever, speech to the B.A.
    September 2005.
  • Equilibrium level of UK house prices has risen
    for four reasons
  • Strong income growth (more two-earner households,
    more income inequality)
  • Low elasticity of housing supply response
  • Strong population growth and net household
    formation
  • Low real interest rates and the disappearance of
    front-end loading.

10
Source Nickell (2005).
11
Source Council of Mortgage Lenders (2005).
12
The ABC of house price determination
  • An inverted demand equation suppose real house
    prices adjust to equate log demand with log of
    end of previous period supply, h(-1).
  • Let log housing demand be given by h -?rp y
    z , rp log house price and y log real
    income and z other demand shifters. The own
    price elasticity of demand is -? and we assume
    the income elasticity is 1. Solving yields
  • rp (y h(-1) z)/ ?.
  • Note log (income per house) restriction.
  • Consensus that ? is approx 2.
  • z will include interest rates, demographics,
    expectations of rate of return or user cost, etc.

13
Modelling Regional House Prices
  • We model real house prices in eight regions of
    Great Britain the North (NT), Yorkshire and
    Humberside (YH), East Midlands (EM), West
    Midlands (WM), Greater London (GL), the South
    (ST), the South West (SW), Wales (WW) and
    Scotland (SC).
  • The choice of regions is determined by the need
    for consistent regional boundaries since the
    government switched from Standard Statistical
    Regions (SSRs) to Government Office Regions
    (GORs) in the mid 1990s.

14
  • The regions experienced broadly comparable long
    run movements. Greater London is considerably
    more expensive than the other regions.

15
  • The heterogeneity in house price inflation is
    more obvious.
  • The leading role of Greater London house prices
    and the tendency of house prices in the North to
    lag further behind those in the West Midlands are
    clear.
  • So called ripple effect.

16
Modelling
  • We estimate a reasonably standard system of
    inverted housing demand equations.
  • We use SUR to take account of contemporaneous
    spatial correlations.
  • The equations are non-linear with many
    cross-equation restrictions, because of common
    parameters, and interaction terms.
  • Some spatial coefficient heterogeneity is allowed
    for.
  • We use annual data from 1972 to 2003.
  • Details of the model used and the SUR parameter
    estimates are set out in the Appendices to paper.

17
Long Run Effects
  • The long-run solution is for lrhpr, the real log
    level of house prices in region r.
  • The key element in the long-run solution is the
    log of real personal disposable non-property
    income per house, the same as in Geoff Meens
    work.
  • For region r, we call this lrynhsr defined as
  • log(real non-property income) - log(housing
    stock)-1 - 0.7log(rate of owner-occupation)-1 in
    region r.
  • The owner-occupation term implies a modest
    spill-over from non-owner occupied supply onto
    the owner-occupied housing market.

18
  • lrynhsr is really a combination of three terms.
  • The log per capita (or household) income and
    housing stock terms have equal but opposite
    signs.
  • Population (or the number of households) is
    implicit in this formulation it just cancels
    out on both sides.
  • All regions are influenced not just by the own
    region value of income per house lrynhsr but also
    by the GB value, lrynhsGB,with weights 0.3 and
    0.7 respectively
  • The long-run effect of log real income per house
    on the log real house price is 2 in line with
    previous studies.
  • The speed of adjustment is 0.25, meaning that
    about three quarters of the adjustment to an
    income shock is completed within four years.

19
Other Long Run Levels Effects
  • Region specific intercepts and (small positive )
    time trends.
  • The log price of house prices in London relative
    to GB (rlhpGL) which we allow to vary by region.
    This has a positive effect in the regions
    adjoining Greater London, capturing some of the
    role of London as the driver of UK house prices.
  • An index of credit conditions (cci) which
    measures credit supply to UK households.
  • The interaction of cci with both the log nominal
    mortgage rate (labmr) and the real mortgage rate
    (rabmr).
  • The interest rate effect are consistent with
    findings for mortgage demand by
    Fernandez-Corugedo and Muellbauer (2005).

20
Other Long Run Levels Effects
  • A reduction of rates from 5 to 4 has a stronger
    effect on house prices than a reduction from 10
    to 9.
  • Nominal interest rate effects are also a little
    stronger in London and the South.
  • We proxy downside risk using rrhnegr the average
    value over the previous 4 years of the negative
    return in the regions housing market. rrhnegr is
    significant which means that a history of
    negative returns depresses house prices for some
    time to come.
  • Possessions not significant given rrhnegr.

21
Some Short Run Effects
  • Short run effects include house price and income
    dynamics as well as changes in nominal interest
    rates, the housing stock, population structure
    inter alia.
  • There is persistence in house price inflation.
    The estimated coefficient on the previous years
    house price growth rate is about 0.45.
  • We allow the relative weight attached to house
    price inflation in the own region (?lrhpr,-1), in
    contiguous regions (?clrhpr,-1) and in Greater
    London (?lrhpGL,-1) to vary by region.
  • Generally speaking, regions closer to London have
    the largest weights on London house price growth,
    reflecting the ripple effect emanating from
    London.

22
  • Income dynamics are important.
  • Outside London and the South East, the estimated
    coefficient on current rate of growth of national
    disposable non-property income (?lrpdin) is about
    0.66.
  • In London and the South East the estimated income
    growth coefficients are higher.
  • As expected, the effect decline over time as
    credit conditions (proxied by cci) have improved.
  • The previous years income growth rate
    (?lrpdin-1) has an estimated coefficient of about
    0.56.
  • Region specific income growth rates have little
    explanatory power.
  • Surprising? Common trends. Regional A/Cs income
    data very poor.

23
  • The question of stock and flow equilibrium
    effects on house price determination is
    important.
  • The stock equilibrium effect enters through the
    log income per house variables, lrynhsr and
    lrynhsGB, discussed above.
  • A flow equilibrium can be examined through the
    effects of housing stock changes and population
    changes.
  • The idea is that short term increases in the
    housing stock relative to population lead to
    short-term local excess supply, with downward
    pressure on local prices.
  • We measure this effect by including
    ?log(wpopr/hsr,-1) in each regions equation.
  • We find a significant effect, suggesting that a 1
    percent rise in working age population relative
    to the housing stock has a short run effect of
    the order of 1.5 to 2 percent on the regions
    house price index.

24
  • Stock market or financial wealth effects? We
    failed to find a positive levels effects unlike
    earlier national studies.
  • Reason? Probably because no regional wealth data.
  • The rate of growth of the FTSE index in real
    terms (?lrftse) has significant positive effects,
    especially in Greater London and the South.
  • Also looked at a simple measure of downside risk
    for the stock market. ?lrftseneg, which equals
    ?lrftse if this is negative and zero otherwise,
    is important in Greater London and the South
    only.
  • The two stock market effects together suggest
    that, for example, a 20 stock market downturn
    has a much smaller (absolute) effect on house
    price inflation in Great London and the South
    than a 20 upturn.

25
  • We investigated whether the growth in the
    regional population proportion in the main ages
    for first time buyers (20 to 39) had any effect.
    The estimated effect of this ?pp2039 variable is
    statistically significant and positive.
  • We include dummy variables for 1988, 1989 and
    2001.
  • In 1988 it became clear that domestic rates would
    be abolished in England and Wales and replaced by
    the Poll Tax. It also marked the March
    announcement that from August 1st, tax relief for
    mortgage interest would be restricted to one per
    property.
  • The 2001 dummy reflects 9/11 and stock market
    turmoil effects, likely to have been more severe
    in London

26
Checks on Model Adequacy
  • Overall the model fits well, although there is
    some evidence of mild autocorrelation in a couple
    of equations.
  • The stability of the model was checked by
    estimating it on different sub-samples.
  • In particular, there is no evidence that we over
    fitted the recent house price boom.
  • The specification was checked against quarterly
    house prices equations for the UK and the North
    and South of Britain and consistent results were
    obtained.

27
Some Caveats
  • We checked for income distribution effects, since
    space is a luxury good, and property tax effects
    (domestic rates, council tax) since variations in
    tax rates over time and over regions should have
    effects on prices.
  • Income distribution changes are trend like and so
    are hard to detect.
  • Despite pain-staking work constructing regional
    tax data back to 1975, the estimated tax effects
    were insignificant. The use of 1988 and 1989
    dummies probably picks up much of the effects of
    the tax switches of the time.
  • Further work on the issue desirable, although
    handling expectations of tax changes will always
    be difficult.
  • It seems likely that property taxes linked more
    closely to house prices could have damped the
    market and had some long run effects.

28
Caveats (Contd)
  • No frenzy effects of the kind used by Hendry
    (1984) and Muellbauer and Murphy (1997) in the
    model.
  • No income expectation terms, though expectations
    effects are likely to be reflected in the
    interest rate and income dynamics which are in
    the model.

29
  • Figure 3 shows the estimated long-run effect of
    the credit conditions index (cci), real and
    nominal mortgage rates interacted with cci and
    inflation volatility. Relative to the 1970s, the
    estimated effects of cci, in terms of its direct,
    positive effect on real house prices, is roughly
    canceled out by the effect of the rise in real
    interest rates.

30
  • Figure 4 shows the effects of downside risk,
    clearly a lagged endogenous variable, measured as
    if it were a long run effect.
  • It suggests that the depth of the early 1990s
    housing market recession had much to do with the
    negative rates of return (and probably the
    associated payment difficulties and possessions
    problems faced by homeowners).
  • This was so especially in Greater London, where
    the effect only began to lift after 1995.

31
  • Figure 5 shows the effect of changes in the
    proportion of the working age population aged
    20-39, an approximate I(1) varable.
  • It plays a considerable role in explaining the
    out-performance of Greater London house prices in
    the late 1990s and early 2000s.
  • It also helps explain why house prices were
    apparently slow to respond to the interest rate
    rises of 1988-90 - the changing age structure was
    still supporting the market as well the weak
    market conditions between 1992 and 1997.

32
  • Figure 6 suggests that, before 1997 or so, the
    rate of house building broadly matched rises in
    real incomes and working age populations (and
    implicitly household formation).
  • Since then, the latter have greatly outpaced the
    rate of house building, especially in Greater
    London. In Greater London, this was the result
    both of higher per capita income growth and of
    population growth, driven by net foreign
    immigration.
  • The composite effect explains most of the rise in
    real house prices since around 1997, thus
    confirming the relevance of the Barker Inquiry on
    Housing Supply (Barker, 2004).
  • .

33
  • Figure 7a shows one version of an error
    correction term including income per house,
    Greater London catch up, credit, interest rate
    and inflation volatility effects.
  • The change in age structure and the rate of
    change in population per house, two near I(1)
    variables in our data, are excluded from this
    figure.
  • Figure 7a suggests that, given interest rates,
    incomes, population and housing stock, Greater
    London was only moderately overvalued in 2003,
    while the West Midlands and the North were
    substantially undervalued

34
Base scenario
  • Forecast period 2004 to 2010
  • Growth rate of real non property income-
  • 0.021 0.015 0.015 0.020 0.023 0.025 0.025
  • Inflation rate-
  • 0.013 0.021 0.027 0.028 0.026 0.024 0.022
  • Mortgage interest rate-
  • 0.050 0.055 0.055 0.055 0.050 0.050 0.050
  • Growth rate of real FTSE index-
  • 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
  • CCI constant.

35
Base scenario contd
  • Regional population projections from Govt
    Actuaries Dept.
  • Shows decline in growth of working age population
    over next 7 years.
  • Further decline of proportions aged 20-39, with
    largest decline around 2006, then tailing off a
    little.
  • Rate of growth of regional housing stocks
    average of last 7 years.
  • Relative per capita regional earnings, tax
    factors, and employment rates unchanged.
  • Growth of owner-occupation average of previous
    7 years.

36
Results
  • No house price bubble if this is plausible
    scenario.
  • Increase rate of growth of housing stock by 50
    house price growth only marginally lower, though
    level effect accumulates.
  • What could go wrong? Economy turning sour.

37
Scenario B
  • Growth rate of real non property income-
  • 0.021 0.012 0.005 0.005 0.010 0.015 0.020
  • Inflation rate-
  • 0.013 0.025 0.03 0.028 0.028 0.026 0.024
  • Mortgage interest rate-
  • 0.050 0.055 0.065 0.060 0.055 0.055 0.050
  • Growth rate of real FTSE index-
  • 0.09 0.08 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05

38
(No Transcript)
39
(No Transcript)
40
(No Transcript)
41
(No Transcript)
42
Conclusions
  • UK base scenario suggests there has been no
    bubble.
  • If REITS and SIPPS valuation effects are
    significant, could be upturn.
  • If economy turns sour and no REITS, SIPPS
    valuation effects, could see moderate nominal
    falls in 2006-7, esp. in London and South.
  • System response is important for answering
    question if consumption, income, exchange rate
    feedbacks are large, could be self-reinforcing,
    but temporary, downturn.
  • Exposure to debt, high house prices in
    Anglo-Saxon economies is high, so global interest
    rate environment will remain kind.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com