Title: The Natural Resource Curse and How to Avoid It
1The Natural Resource Curse and How to Avoid It
Part I Channels of the commodity curse Part
II Policies institutions to avoid the pitfalls
Jeffrey Frankel
- MPA/ID extra lecture, Dec. 18, 2013
2The Natural Resource CursePart I Channels
- Some seminal references
- Auty (1990, 2001, 2007)
- Sachs Warner (1995, 2001),
- By now there is a large body of research,
- which I have surveyed (2011, 2012a, b).
3- Many countries that are richly endowed with oil,
minerals, or fertile land have failed to grow
more rapidly than those without. - Example
- Some studies find a negative effect of oil in
particular, on economic performance - including Kaldor, Karl Said (2007) Ross
(2001) Sala-i-Martin Subramanian (2003) and
Smith (2004). - Some oil producers in Africa the Middle East
have relatively little to show for their
resources.
4- Meanwhile, East Asian economies achieved
western-level standards of living despite having
virtually no exportable natural resources - Japan, Singapore, Hong Kong, Korea Taiwan,
- rocky islands or peninsulas
- followed by China.
5Growth falls with fuel mineral exports
6Are natural resources necessarily bad?
No, of course not.
- Commodity wealth need not necessarily lead to
inferior economic or political development. - Rather, it is a double-edged sword, with both
benefits and dangers. - It can be used for ill as easily as for good.
- The priority should be on identifying ways
- to sidestep the pitfalls that have afflicted
commodity producers in the past, to find the
path of success.
7- Some developing countries have avoided the
pitfalls of commodity wealth. - E.g., Chile (copper)
- Botswana (diamonds)
- Some of their innovations are worth emulating.
- The 2nd half of the lecture will offer some
policies institutional innovations to avoid the
curse - especially ways of managing price volatility.
- Some lessons apply to commodity importers too.
- Including lessons of policies to avoid.
8- But, 1st How could abundance of commodity
wealth be a curse? - What is the mechanism
- for this counter-intuitive relationship?
-
- At least 5 categories of explanations.
95 Possible Natural Resource Curse Channels
- Volatility
- Crowding-out of manufacturing
- Autocratic Institutions
- Anarchic Institutions
- Procyclicality including
- Procyclical capital flows
- Procyclical monetary policy
- Procyclical fiscal policy.
10- (1) Volatility in global commodity prices
arises because supply demand are inelastic in
the short run.
11Commodity prices have been especially volatile
over the last decade
Source UNCTAD
12Effects of Volatility
- Volatility per se can be bad for economic growth.
- Hausmann Rigobon (2003), Blattman, Hwang,
Williamson (2007), and Poelhekke van der Ploeg
(2007). - Risk inhibits private investment.
- Cyclical shifts of labor, land capital back
forth across sectors may incur needless costs. - gt role for government intervention?
- On the one hand, the private sector dislikes risk
as much as government does takes steps to
mitigate it. - On the other hand the government cannot entirely
ignore the issue of volatility - e.g., exchange rate policy.
12
132. Natural resources may crowd out manufacturing,
- and manufacturing could be the sector that
experiences learning-by-doing - or dynamic productivity gains from spillover.
- Matsuyama (1992), van Wijnbergen (1984) and Sachs
Warner (1995). - So commodities could in theory be a dead-end
sector. - My own view a country need not repress the
commodity sector to develop the manufacturing
sector. - It can foster growth in both .
- E.g. Canada, Australia, Norway Now Malaysia,
Chile, Brazil
14Econometric findings that oiland other
point-source resources lead to poor
institutions
- Isham, Woolcock, Pritchett, Busby (2005)
- Sala-I-Martin Subramanian (2003)
- Bulte, Damania Deacon (2005)
- Mehlum, Moene Torvik (2006)
- Arezki Brückner (2009).
The theory is thought to fit Mideastern oil
exporters well.
15What are poor institutions?
- A typical list
- inequality,
- corruption,
- rent-seeking,
- intermittent dictatorship,
- ineffective judiciary branch, and
- lack of constraints to prevent elites
politicians from plundering the country.
16An example, from economic historians Engerman
Sokoloff (1997, 2000, 2002)
- Why did industrialization take place in North
America, - not the South?
- Lands endowed with extractive industries
plantation crops developed slavery, inequality,
dictatorship, and state control, - whereas those climates suited to fishing small
farms developed institutions of individualism,
democracy, egalitarianism, and capitalism. - When the Industrial Revolution came, the latter
areas were well-suited to make the most of it. - Those that had specialized in extractive
industries were not, - because society had come to depend on class
structure authoritarianism, rather than on
individual incentive and decentralized
decision-making.
174. Anarchic institutions
- Unsustainably rapid depletion of resources
- Unenforceable property rights
- Civil war
See Appendix 2 for elaboration on each.
17
18(5) Procyclicality
- The Dutch Disease describes unwanted
side-effects of a commodity boom. - Developing countries are historically prone to
procyclicality, - especially commodity producers.
- Procyclicality in
- Capital inflows Monetary policy
- Real exchange rate Nontraded Goods
- Fiscal Policy
18
19The Dutch Disease 5 side-effects of a commodity
boom
- 1) A real appreciation in the currency
- 2) A rise in government spending
- 3) A rise in nontraded goods prices
- 4) A resultant shift of production out of
manufactured goods - 5) Sometimes a current account deficit
19
20The Dutch Disease The 5 effects elaborated
- 1) Real appreciation in the currency
- taking the form of nominal currency appreciation
if the exchange rate floats - or the form of money inflows, credit inflation
if the exchange rate is fixed - 2) A rise in government spending
- in response to availability of tax receipts or
royalties.
20
21The Dutch Disease 5 side-effects of a commodity
boom
- 3) An increase in nontraded goods prices
relative to internationally traded goods
- 4) A resultant shift out of non-commodity traded
goods, - esp. manufactures,
- pulled by the more attractive returns in the
export commodity and in non-traded goods.
21
22The Dutch Disease 5 side-effects of a commodity
boom
- 5) A current account deficit,
- as booming countries attract capital flows,
- thereby incurring international debt that is
hard to service when the boom ends. - Manzano Rigobon (2008) the negative
Sachs-Warner effect of resources on growth rates
during 1970-1990 was mediated through
international debt incurred when commodity prices
were high. - Arezki Brückner (2010a, b) commodity price
booms lead to higher government spending,
external debt default risk in autocracies, - but do not have those effects in democracies.
22
23Procyclical capital flows
- According to intertemporal optimization theory,
capital flows should be countercyclical - net capital inflows when exports are doing badly
- and net capital outflows when exports do well.
- In practice, it does not always work this way.
Capital flows are more procyclical than
countercyclical. - Gavin, Hausmann, Perotti Talvi (1996)
Kaminsky, Reinhart Vegh (2005) Reinhart
Reinhart (2009) and Mendoza Terrones (2008). - Invalidates much of existing theory,
- though certainly not all.
- Theories to explain this involve capital market
imperfections, - e.g., asymmetric information or the need for
collateral.
24Procyclical monetary policy
- If the exchange rate is fixed,
- surpluses during commodity booms lead to rising
reserves and money supply. - possibly delayed by sterilization attempts.
- Example Gulf States during recent oil booms.
- Floating can help, accommodating trade shock.
- But,
- under pure floating appreciation can be
excessive. - under IT CPI rule says to tighten money
appreciate when import commodity price goes up
(or other adverse supply shock). - Thats backwards. (E.g., oil importers in
2008.) - Should appreciate when export commodity price
goes up.
25Procyclical real exchange rateCountries
undergoing a commodity boom experience real
appreciation of their currency
- taking the form of nominal currency appreciation
- for floating-rate commodity exporters, Colombia,
Kazakhstan, Russia, S.Africa, Chile, Brazil. - or the form of money inflows inflation
- for fixed-rate commodity exporters, Saudi Arabia
UAE.
OK. But real appreciation adds to boom in NTGs.
26Procyclical fiscal policy
- Fiscal policy has historically tended to be
procyclical in developing countries - especially among commodity exporters
- Cuddington (1989), Tornell Lane (1999),
Kaminsky, Reinhart Vegh (2004), Talvi Végh
(2005), Alesina, Campante Tabellini (2008),
Mendoza Oviedo (2006), Ilzetski Vegh (2008),
Medas Zakharova (2009), Gavin Perotti
(1997). -
- Correlation of income spending mostly positive
- particularly in comparison with industrialized
countries.
27- The procyclicality of fiscal policy
-
- A reason for procyclical public spending
receipts from taxes royalties rise in booms.
The government cannot resist the temptation to
increase spending proportionately, or more. - Then it is forced to contract in recessions,
- thereby exacerbating the swings.
27
28Two budget items account for much of the
spending from oil booms
- (i) Investment projects.
- Investment in practice may be white elephant
projects, - which are stranded without funds for completion
or maintenance when the oil price goes back
down. - Gelb (1986).
- (ii) The government wage bill.
- Oil windfalls are often spent on public sector
wages. - Medas Zakharova (2009)
- Arezki Ismail (2010) government spending
rises in booms, but is downward-sticky.
Rumbi Sithole took this photo in Bayelsa
Statein the Niger Delta,in Nigeria. The state
government received a windfall of money and
didn't have the capacity to have it all absorbed
in social services so they decided to build a
Hilton Hotel. The construction company did a
shoddy job, so the tower is leaning to its right
and its unsalvageable..
28
29Correlations between Gov.t Spending
GDP 1960-1999
procyclical
Adapted from Kaminsky, Reinhart Vegh (2004)
countercyclical
G always used to be pro-cyclical for most
developing countries.
30The procyclicality of fiscal policy, cont.
- An important development -- some developing
countries, including commodity producers, were
able to break the historic pattern in the most
recent decade - taking advantage of the boom of 2002-2008
- to run budget surpluses build reserves,
- thereby earning the ability to expand fiscally
in the 2008-09 crisis. - Chile is the outstanding model.
- Also Botswana, China, Indonesia, Korea
30
31Correlations between Government spending GDP
2000-2009
procyclical
Frankel, Vegh Vuletin (2012)
In the last decade, about 1/3 developing
countries switched to countercyclical fiscal
policyNegative correlation of G GDP.
countercyclical
32Summary of Part I
- Five broad categories of hypothesized channels
whereby natural resources can lead to poor
economic performance - commodity price volatility,
- crowding out of manufacturing,
- autocratic institutions,
- anarchic institutions, and
- procyclical macroeconomic policy, including
- capital flows,
- monetary policy and
- fiscal policy.
- But the important question is how to avoid the
pitfalls, - to achieve resource blessing instead of resource
curse.
3333
34Appendix 1 I exclude a 6th channel, The
Prebisch-Singer (1950) Hypothesis
- that commodities supposedly suffer a long-run
downward relative price trend. - Theoretical reasoning world demand for primary
products is inelastic with respect to income. - Vs. persuasive theoretical arguments that we
should expect commodity prices to show upward
trends in the long run - Malthus (esp. for food)
- Hotelling (for depletable resources).
35- The up trend idea goes back to Malthus (1798) and
early fears of environmental scarcity - Demand grows with population (geometrically),
- Supply does not.
- What could be clearer in economics
- than the prediction that price will rise?
36Hotelling (1931)
- Firms choose how fast to extract oil or minerals
- King Abdullah of Saudi Arabia, with interest
rates 0 in 2008,apparently believed that the
rate of return on oil reserves was higher if he
didn't pump than if he did - "Let them remain in the ground for our children
and grandchildren..." - Arbitrage gt
- expected rate of price increase interest rate.
37The empirical evidence
- With strong theoretical arguments on both sides,
either for an upward trend or for a downward
trend, it is an empirical question. - Terms of trade for commodity producers had
- a slight up trend from 1870 to World War I,
- a down trend in the inter-war period,
- up in the 1970s,
- down in the 1980s and 1990s,
- and up in the first decade of the 21st century.
38What is the overall statistical trend in
commodity prices in the long run?
- Some authors find a slight upward trend,
- some a slight downward trend. 1
- The answer depends on the date of the end of the
sample. - 1 Cuddington (1992), Cuddington, Ludema
Jayasuriya (2007), Cuddington Urzua (1989),
Grilli Yang (1988), Pindyck (1999), Reinhart
Wickham (1994), Hadass Williamson (2003),
Kellard Wohar (2005), Balagtas Holt (2009),
Cuddington Jerrett (2008), and Harvey, Kellard,
Madsen Wohar (2010).
39 4.1 Unsustainably rapid
depletion
Appendix 2 Elaboration on Anarchyinsufficient
protection of property rights
- When exhaustible resources are in fact
exhausted, the country may be left with
nothing. - Three concerns
- Protection of environmental quality.
- A motivation for a strategy of economic
diversification. - The need to save for the day of depletion
- Invest rents from exhaustible resources in other
assets. - Hartwick (1977) and Solow (1986).
39
40The example of Nauruphosphate mining
414.2 Unenforceable property rights
- Depletion would be much less of a problem if
full property rights could be enforced, - thereby giving the owners incentive to conserve
the resource in question. - But often this is not possible
- especially under frontier conditions.
- Overfishing, overgrazing, over-logging are
classic examples of the tragedy of the commons.
- Individual fisherman, ranchers, loggers, or
miners, have no incentive to restrain
themselves, while the fisheries, pastureland or
forests are collectively depleted.
41
42Madre de Dios region of the Amazon rainforest in
Peru, the left-hand side stripped by illegal
gold mining.
http//indiancountrytodaymedianetwork.com/2011/02/
27/amazon-gold-rush-laying-waste-to-peruvian-rainf
orestE28099s-madre-de-dios-20021
434.3 War
- Where a valuable resource such as oil or diamonds
is there for the taking, factions will likely
fight over it. - Oil minerals are correlated with civil war.
- Fearon Laitin (2003), Collier Hoeffler
(2004), Humphreys (2005) and Collier (2007). -
- Chronic conflict in places such as Sudan comes
to mind. - Civil war is, in turn, very bad for economic
development.
43
44Appendix 3The NRC SkepticsWhich comes first,
oil or institutions?
- Some question the assumption that oil discoveries
are exogenous and institutions endogenous. - Oil wealth is not necessarily the cause and
institutions the effect, rather than the other
way around. - Norman (2009) the discovery development of
oil is not purely exogenous, but rather is
endogenous with respect to the efficiency of the
economy.
45in which case it is put to use for the national
welfare, instead of the welfare of an elite.
The important determinant is whether the country
already has good institutions at the time that
oil is discovered,
- Mehlum, Moene Torvik (2006),
- Robinson, Torvik Verdier (2006),
- McSherry (2006),
- Smith (2007) and
- Collier Goderis (2007).
46Skeptics argue that commodity exports are
endogenous.
- On the one hand, basic trade theory saysA
country may show a high mineral share in exports,
not necessarily because it has a higher
endowment of minerals than others (absolute
advantage) but because it does not have the
ability to export manufactures (comparative
advantage). - This could explain negative statistical
correlations between mineral exports and economic
development, - invalidating the common inference that minerals
are bad for growth. - Maloney (2002) and Wright Czelusta (2003, 04,
06).
47Commodity exports are endogenous, continued.
- On the other hand, skeptics also have plenty of
examples where successful institutions and
industrialization went hand in hand with rapid
development of mineral resources. - Countries that were able to develop efficiently
their resource endowments as part of strong
economy-wide growth include - the USA during its pre-war industrialization
period - David Wright (1997).
- Venezuela from the 1920s to the 1970s, Australia
since the 1960s, Norway since 1969 oil
discoveries, Chile since adoption of a new
mining code in 1983, Peru since a privatization
program in 1992, and Brazil since lifting
restrictions on foreign mining participation in
1995. - Wright Czelusta (2003, pp. 4-7, 12-13, 18-22).
48Commodity exports are endogenous, continued.
- Examples of countries that were equally
well-endowed geologically but that failed to
develop their natural resources efficiently
include - Chile Australia before World War I,
- and Venezuela since the 1980s.
- Hausmann (2003, p.246) Venezuelas growth
collapse took place after 60 years of expansion,
fueled by oil. If oil explains slow growth, what
explains the previous fast growth?
49Addendum Countries with high resource rents (as
of GDP) tend to have lower student math
performance(statistically significant at the
.003 level)
Source OECD education data featured in
Knowledge and skills are infinite oil is not
by Andreas Schleicher.
50Part II
Policies institutions to avoidpitfalls of
the Natural Resource Curse
- Some that are not recommended
- Institutions that try to suppress price
volatility. - Recommended
- Devices to hedge risk.
- Ideas to reduce macroeconomic procyclicality.
- Institutions for better governance.
51The Natural Resource Curse should not be
interpreted as a rule that commodity-rich
countries are doomed to fail.
- The question is what policies to adopt
- to avoid the pitfalls and improve the chances of
prosperity.
- A wide variety of measures have been tried by
commodity-exporters cope with volatility. - Some work better than others.
52 Many of the policies that have been intended to
suppress commodity volatility do not work out so
well
- Producer subsidies
- Stockpiles
- Marketing boards
- Price controls
- Export controls
- Blaming derivatives
- Resource nationalism
- Nationalization
- Banning foreign participation
53Devices to share risks
7 recommendations for commodity-exporting
countries
- 1. Index contracts with foreign
companies(royalties) to the world commodity
price. - 2. Hedge commodity revenues in options markets
- 3. Link debt to the commodity price
54Countercyclical macroeconomic policy
7 recommendations for commodity producers
continued
- 4. Allow some currency appreciation in response
to a commodity boom, but not a free float. - - Accumulate some forex reserves first.- Raise
banks reserve requirements, esp. on
liabilities. - 5. If the monetary anchor is to be Inflation
Targeting, consider using as the target, in place
of the CPI, a price measure that puts weight on
the export commodity (Product Price Targeting). - 6. Emulate Chile to avoid over-spending in boom
times, allow deviations from a target surplus
only in response to permanent commodity price
rises.
PPT
55Good governance institutions
7 recommendations for commodity producers,
concluded
- 7. Manage commodity funds professionally.
- Invest them abroad
- like Norways Pension Fund,
- Reasons
- (1) for diversification,
- (2) to avoid cronyism in investments.
- but insulated from politics
- like Botswanas Pula Fund.
- Professionally managed, to optimize financially.
56Elaboration on two proposals to reduce the
procyclicality of macroeconomic policy for
commodity exporters
- I) To make monetary policy less procyclical
Product Price Targeting - II) To make fiscal policy less procyclical
emulate Chile.
PPT
57I) The challenge of designinga currency regime
for countries where terms of trade shocks
dominate the cycle
- Fixing the exchange rate leads to procyclical
monetary policy credit expands in commodity
booms. - Floating accommodates terms of trade shocks.
- But volatility can be excessive
- also floating does not provide a nominal anchor.
- Inflation Targeting, in terms of the CPI,
- provides a nominal anchor
- but can react perversely to terms of trade
shocks. - Needed an anchor that accommodates trade shocks
58Product Price Targeting
PPT
- Target an index of domestic production prices
1 - such as the GDP deflator
- Include export commodities in the index and
exclude import commodities, - so money tightens the currency appreciates
when world prices of export commodities rise - accommodating the terms of trade --
- not when world prices of import commodities
rise. - The CPI does it backwards
- It calls for appreciation when import prices
rise, - not when export prices rise !
- 1 Frankel (2011, 2012).
59Appendix II Who achieves counter-cyclical
fiscal policy?
Countries with good institutions
On Graduation from Fiscal Procyclicality 2013,
Frankel with C.Végh G.Vuletin J.Dev.Economics.
60What, specifically, are good institutions?
The example of Chile since 2000
-
- 1st rule Governments must set a budget target,
- set 0 in 2008 under Pres. Bachelet.
- 2nd rule The target is structural Deficits
allowed only to the extent that - (1) output falls short of trend, in a recession,
or - (2) the price of copper is below its trend.
- 3rd rule The trends are projected by 2 panels
of independent experts, outside the political
process. - Result Chile avoids the pattern of 32 other
governments, - where forecasts in booms are biased toward
over-optimism. - Chile ran surpluses in the 2003-07 boom,
- while the U.S. Europe failed to do so.
61Appendiceson recommendations for dealing with
the natural resource curse
-
- Appendix 4 Policies not recommended
- Appendix 5 Elaboration on proposal to make
monetary policy less procyclical PPT, using GDP
deflator to set annual inflation target. - Appendix 6 Elaboration on proposal to make
fiscal policy less procyclical emulate Chile,
setting structural targets with independent
fiscal forecasts
62 Appendix 4 Policies that have been triedbut
that are not recommended
- Blaming derivatives
- Resource nationalism
- Nationalization
- Banning foreign participation
- Producer subsidies
- Stockpiles
- Marketing boards
- Price controls
- Export controls
63Unsuccessful policies to reduce commodity price
volatility
- 1) Producer subsidies to stabilize prices at
high levels, - often via wasteful stockpiles protectionist
import barriers. - Examples
- The EUs Common Agricultural Policy
- Bad for EU budgets, economic efficiency,
international trade consumer pocketbooks. - Or fossil fuel subsidies
- which are equally distortionary budget-busting,
- and disastrous for the environment as well.
- Or US corn-based ethanol subsidies,
- with tariffs on Brazilian sugar-based ethanol.
64Unsuccessful policies, continued
- 2) Price controls to stabilize prices at low
levels - Discourage investment production.
- Example African countries adopted commodity
boards for coffee cocoa at the time of
independence. - The original rationale to buy the crop in years
of excess supply and sell in years of excess
demand. - In practice the price paid to cocoa coffee
farmers was always below the world price. - As a result, production fell.
65Microeconomic policies, continued
- Often the goal of price controls is to shield
consumers of staple foods fuel from increases.
- But the artificially suppressed price
- discourages domestic supply, and
- requires rationing to domestic households.
- Shortages long lines can fuel political rage
as well as higher prices can. - Not to mention when the government is forced by
huge gaps to raise prices. - Price controls can also require imports, to
satisfy excess demand. - Then they raise the world price even more.
66Microeconomic policies, continued
- 3) In producing countries, prices are
artificially suppressed by means of export
controls - to insulate domestic consumers from a price rise.
- In 2008, India capped rice exports.
- Argentina did the same for wheat exports,
- as did Russia in 2010.
- India banned cotton exports in March 2012.
- Results
- Domestic supply is discouraged.
- World prices go even higher.
67An initiative at the G20 meetings in France in
2011 deserved to succeed
- Producers and consuming countries in grain
markets should cooperatively agree to refrain
from export controls and price controls. - The result would be lower world price
volatility. - One hopes for steps in this direction, perhaps
working through the WTO.
68An initiative that has less merit
- 4) Attempts to blame speculation for volatility
- and so to ban derivatives markets.
- Yes, speculative bubbles sometimes hit prices.
- But in commodity markets,
- prices are more often the signal for
fundamentals. - Dont shoot the messenger.
- Also, derivatives are useful for hedgers.
69An example of commodity speculation
- In the 1955 movie version of East of Eden, the
legendary James Dean plays Cal. - Like Cain in Genesis, he competes with his
brother for the love of his father. - Cal goes long in the market for beans, in
anticipation of a rise in demand if the US
enters WWI.
70An example of commodity speculation, cont.
- Sure enough, the price of beans goes sky high,
Cal makes a bundle, and offers it to his father,
a moralizing patriarch. - But the father is morally offended by Cals
speculation, not wanting to profit from others
misfortunes, and tells him he will have to
give the money back.
71An example of commodity speculation, cont.
- Cal has been the agent of Adam Smiths famous
invisible hand - By betting on his hunch about the future, he has
contributed to upward pressure on the price of
beans in the present, - thereby increasing the supply so that more is
available precisely when needed (by the Army). - The movie even treats us to a scene where Cal
watches the beans grow in a farmers field,
something real-life speculators seldom get to see.
72The overall lesson for microeconomic policy
- Attempts to prevent commodity prices from
fluctuating generally fail. - Even though enacted in the name of reducing
volatility income inequality, their effect is
often different. - Better to accept volatility and cope with it.
- For the poor well-designed transfers,
- along the lines of Oportunidades or Bolsa Familia.
73Resource nationalism
- Another motive for commodity export controls
- 5) To subsidize downstream industries.
- E.g., beneficiation in South African diamonds
- But it didnt make diamond-cutting competitive,
- and it hurt mining exports.
- 6) Nationalization of foreign companies.
- Like price controls, it discourages investment.
74Resource nationalism continued
- 7) Keeping out foreign companies altogether.
- But often they have the needed technical
expertise. - Examples declining oil production in Mexico
Venezuela. - 8) Going around locking up resource supplies.
- China must think that this strategy will protect
it in case of a commodity price shock. - But global commodity markets are increasingly
integrated. - If conflict in the Persian Gulf doubles world oil
prices, the effect will be pretty much the same
for those who buy on the spot market and those
who have bilateral arrangements.
75The overall lesson for microeconomic policy
- Attempts to prevent commodity prices from
fluctuating generally fail. - Even though enacted in the name of reducing
volatility income inequality, their effect is
often different. - Better to accept volatility and cope with it.
- For the poor well-designed transfers,
- along the lines of Oportunidades or Bolsa Familia.
76Appendix 5 Product Price Targeting
- Each of the traditional candidates for nominal
anchor has an Achilles heel. - The CPI anchor does not accommodate terms of
trade changes - IT tightens M appreciates when import prices
rise - not when export prices rise,
- which is backwards.
- Targeting core CPI does not much help.
776 proposed nominal targets and the Achilles heel
of each
Vulnerability
IT
Professor Jeffrey Frankel
78Why is PPT better than a fixed exchange ratefor
countries with volatile export prices?
PPT
- Better response to trade shocks
(countercyclical) - If the price of the export commodity goes up,
the currency automatically appreciates, - moderating the boom.
- If the price of the export commodity goes down,
the currency automatically depreciates, - moderating the downturn
- improving the balance of payments.
79Why is PPT better than CPI-targetingfor
countries with volatile terms of trade?
PPT
- Better response to trade shocks (accommodating)
- If the price of imported commodity goes up,
CPI target says to tighten monetary policy
enough to appreciate the currency. - Wrong response. (E.g., oil-importers in
2007-08.) - PPT does not have this flaw .
- If the price of the export commodity goes up,
PPT says to tighten money enough to appreciate.
- Right response. (E.g., Gulf currencies in
2007-08.) - CPI targeting does not have this advantage.
80Empirical findings
- Simulations of 1970-2000
- Gold producers Burkino Faso, Ghana, Mali, South
Africa - Other commodities Ethiopia (coffee), Nigeria
(oil), S.Africa (platinum) - General finding Under Product Price Targets,
their currencies would have depreciated
automatically in 1990s when commodity prices
declined, - perhaps avoiding messy balance of payments
crises.
Sources Frankel (2002, 03a, 05), Frankel Saiki
(2003)
81Price indices
- CPI GDP deflator each include
- an international good
- import good in the CPI,
- export good in GDP deflator
- And the non-traded good,
- with weights f and (1-f), respectively
- cpi (f)pim (1-f)pn ,
- p (f)px (1-f) pn .
82Estimation for each country of weights in
national price index on 3 sectors non tradable
goods, leading commodity export, other tradable
goods
A Comparison of Product Price Targeting and
Other Monetary Anchor Options, for
Commodity-Exporters in Latin America," Economia,
vol.11, 2011 (Brookings), NBER WP 16362.
Argentina is relatively closed
Mexico is relatively open.
The leading export commodity usually has a
higher weight in the countrys PPI than in its
CPI, as expected. (Jamaicans dont eat
bauxite.)
83In practice, IT proponents agree central banks
should not tighten to offset oil price shocks
- They want focus on core CPI, excluding food
energy. - But
- food energy ? all supply shocks.
- Use of core CPI sacrifices some credibility
- If core CPI is the explicit goal ex ante, the
public feels confused. - If it is an excuse for missing targets ex post,
the public feels tricked. - Perhaps for that reason, IT central banks
apparently do respond to oil shocks by
tightening/appreciating, - as the following correlations suggests.
84LAC Countries Current Regimes and Monthly
Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local
currency) with Import Price Changes
Table 1
Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes Table 1 LACA Countries Current Regimes and Monthly Correlations of Exchange Rate Changes (/local currency) with Dollar Import Price Changes
Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil. Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil. Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil. Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil. Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil. Import price changes are changes in the dollar price of oil.
Exchange Rate Regime Monetary Policy 1970-1999 2000-2008 1970-2008
ARG Managed floating Monetary aggregate target -0.0212 -0.0591 -0.0266
BOL Other conventional fixed peg Against a single currency -0.0139 0.0156 -0.0057
BRA Independently floating Inflation targeting framework (1999) 0.0366 0.0961 0.0551
CHL Independently floating Inflation targeting framework (1990) -0.0695 0.0524 -0.0484
CRI Crawling pegs Exchange rate anchor 0.0123 -0.0327 0.0076
GTM Managed floating Inflation targeting framework -0.0029 0.2428 0.0149
GUY Other conventional fixed peg Monetary aggregate target -0.0335 0.0119 -0.0274
HND Other conventional fixed peg Against a single currency -0.0203 -0.0734 -0.0176
JAM Managed floating Monetary aggregate target 0.0257 0.2672 0.0417
NIC Crawling pegs Exchange rate anchor -0.0644 0.0324 -0.0412
PER Managed floating Inflation targeting framework (2002) -0.3138 0.1895 -0.2015
PRY Managed floating IMF-supported or other monetary program -0.023 0.3424 0.0543
SLV Dollar Exchange rate anchor 0.1040 0.0530 0.0862
URY Managed floating Monetary aggregate target 0.0438 0.1168 0.0564
Oil Exporters Oil Exporters
COL Managed floating Inflation targeting framework (1999) -0.0297 0.0489 0.0046
MEX Independently floating Inflation targeting framework (1995) 0.1070 0.1619 0.1086
TTO Other conventional fixed peg Against a single currency 0.0698 0.2025 0.0698
VEN Other conventional fixed peg Against a single currency -0.0521 0.0064 -0.0382
Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999. Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999. Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999. Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999. Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999. Chile declared an inflation target as early as 1990 but it also had an exchange rate target, under an explicit band-basket-crawl regime, until 1999.
IT coun-tries show correl-ations gt 0.
85The 4 inflation-targeters in Latin Americashow
correlation (currency value in , import prices
in )
- gt 0
- gt correlation before they adopted IT
- gt correlation shown by non-IT Latin American
oil-importing countries.
86Why is the correlation between the import price
and the currency value revealing?
- The currency of an oil importer should not
respond to an increase in the world oil price by
appreciating, to the extent that these central
banks target core CPI . - When these IT currencies respond by appreciating
instead, it suggests that the central bank is
tightening money to reduce upward pressure on
headline CPI.
87Appendix 6 Chilean fiscal policy
- In 2000 Chile instituted its structural budget
rule. - The institution was formalized in law in 2006.
- The structural budget deficit must be zero,
- originally BS gt 1 of GDP, then cut to ½ , then
0 -- - where structural is defined by output copper
price equal to their long-run trend values. - I.e., in a boom the government can only spend
increased revenues that are deemed permanent
any temporary copper bonanzas must be saved.
88The crucial institutional innovation in Chile
- How has Chile avoided over-optimistic official
forecasts? - especially the historic pattern of
over-exuberance in commodity booms? - The estimation of the long-term path for GDP
the copper price is made by two panels of
independent experts, - and thus is insulated from political pressure
wishful thinking. - Other countries might usefully emulate Chiles
innovation - or in other ways delegate to independent agencies
estimation of structural budget deficit paths.
89The Pay-off
- Chiles fiscal position strengthened immediately
- Public saving rose from 2.5 of GDP in 2000 to
7.9 in 2005 - allowing national saving to rise from 21 to 24
. - Government debt fell sharply as a share of GDP
and the sovereign spread gradually declined. - By 2006, Chile achieved a sovereign debt rating
of A, - several notches ahead of Latin American peers.
- By 2007 it had become a net creditor.
- By 2010, Chiles sovereign rating had climbed to
A, - ahead of some advanced countries.
- gt It was able to respond to the 2008-09
recession - via fiscal expansion.
90- In 2008, with copper prices spiking up, the
government of President Bachelet had beenunder
intense pressure to spend the revenue. - She Fin.Min.Velasco held to the rule, saving
most of it. - Their popularity ratings fell sharply.
- When the recession hit and the copper price came
back down, the government increased spending,
mitigating the downturn. - Bachelet Velascos popularity reached
historic highs in 2009.
91Evolution of approval and disapproval of four
Chilean presidents
Presidents Patricio Aylwin, Eduardo Frei, Ricardo
Lagos and Michelle BacheletData CEP, Encuesta
Nacional de Opinion Publica, October 2009,
www.cepchile.cl. Source Engel et al
(2011).
925 econometric findings regarding bias toward
optimism in official budget forecasts.
- Official forecasts in a sample of 33 countries
on average are overly optimistic, for - (1) budgets
- (2) GDP .
- The bias toward optimism is
- (3) stronger the longer the forecast horizon
- (4) greater in booms
- (5) greater for euro governments under SGP budget
rules
93 (4) The optimism in official budget forecasts is
stronger at the 3-year horizon, stronger
amongcountries with budget rules,
stronger in booms.
Frankel, 2012, A Solution to Fiscal
Procyclicality The Structural Budget
Institutions Pioneered by Chile.
94(4) Official budget forecasts are biased more if
GDP is currently high especially at longer
horizons
Budget balance forecast error as of GDP,
Full dataset
(1) (2) (3)
One year ahead Two years ahead Three years ahead
GDP relative to trend 0.093(0.019) 0.258(0.040) 0.289(0.063)
Constant 0.201 0.649 1.364
(0.197) (0.231) (0.348)
Observations 398 300 179
33 countries
Variable is lagged so that it lines up with the
year in which the forecast was made. plt0.01
Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered
by country.
95Budget balance forecast error as a of GDP,
Full Dataset
(5) Official budget forecasts are more
optimistically biasedin countries subject to a
budget deficit rule (SGP)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
One year ahead Two years ahead One year ahead Two years ahead
SGPdummy 0.658 0.905 0.407 0.276
(0.398) (0.406) (0.355) (0.438)
SGP dummy (GDP - trend) 0.189(0.0828) 0.497(0.107)
Constant 0.033 0.466 0.033 0.466
(0.228) (0.248) (0.229) (0.249)
Observations 399 300 398 300
33 countries
plt0.01, plt0.05, plt0.1 Robust standard
errors in parentheses, clustered by country.
965 more econometric findings regarding bias
toward optimism in official budget forecasts.
- (6) The key macroeconomic input for budget
forecasting in most countries GDP. In
Chile the copper price. - (7) Real copper prices revert to trend in the
long run. - But this is not always readily perceived
- (8) 30 years of data are not enough
- to reject a random walk statistically 200 years
of data are needed. - (9) Uncertainty (option-implied volatility) is
higher when copper prices are toward the top of
the cycle. - (10) Chiles official forecasts are not overly
optimistic.It has apparently avoided the
problem of forecasts that unrealistically
extrapolate in boom times.
97In sum, institutions recommended to make fiscal
policy less procyclical
- Official growth budget forecasts tend toward
wishful thinking - unrealistic extrapolation of booms 3 years into
the future. - The bias is worse among the European countries
supposedly subject to the budget rules of the
SGP, - presumably because government forecasters feel
pressured to announce they are on track to meet
budget targets even if they are not. - Chile is not subject to the same bias toward
over-optimism in forecasts of the budget, growth,
or the all-important copper price. - The key innovation that has allowed Chile to
achieve countercyclical fiscal policy - not just a structural budget rule in itself,
- but rather the regime that entrusts to two panels
of experts estimation of the long-run trends of
copper prices GDP.
98Application to other countries
- Any country could adopt the Chilean mechanism.
- Suggestion give the panels more institutional
independence - as is familiar from central banking
- laws protecting them from being fired.
- Open questions
- Are the budget rules to be interpreted as ex ante
or ex post? - How much of the structural budget calculations
are to be delegated to the independent panels of
experts? - Minimalist approach they compute only 10-year
moving averages. - Can one guard against subversion of the
institutions (CBO) ?
99(No Transcript)
100References by the author
- Project Syndicate,
- Escaping the Oil Curse, Dec.9, 2011.
- "Barrels, Bushels Bonds How Commodity
Exporters Can Hedge Volatility," Oct.17, 2011. - The Natural Resource Curse A Survey of
Diagnoses and Some Prescriptions, 2012,
Commodity Price Volatility and Inclusive Growth
in Low-Income Countries , R.Arezki Z.Min, eds..
HKS RWP12-014. High Level Seminar, IMF Annual
Meetings, DC, Sept.2011. - "The Curse Why Natural Resources Are Not Always
a Good Thing, Milken Institute Review, vol.13,
4th quarter 2011. - The Natural Resource Curse A Survey, 2012,
Chapter 2 in Beyond the Resource Curse, B.Shaffer
T. Ziyadov, eds. (U.Penn. Press) proofs
notes Summary. CID WP195, 2011. - How Can Commodity Exporters Make Fiscal and
Monetary Policy Less Procyclical? Natural
Resources, Finance Development, R.Arezki,
T.Gylfason A.Sy, eds. (IMF), 2011. HKS RWP
11-015. - On Graduation from Procyclicality, 2012, with
C.Végh G.Vuletin J. Dev. Economics. - Chiles Solution to Fiscal Procyclicality,
2012, Transitions blog, Foreign Policy. - A Solution to Fiscal Procyclicality The
Structural Budget Institutions Pioneered by
Chile, in Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic
Performance, 2012. Central Bank of Chile WP
604, 2011. - "Product Price Targeting -- A New Improved Way
of Inflation Targeting," in MAS Monetary Review
Vol.XI, issue 1, April 2012 (Monetary Authority
of Singapore). - A Comparison of Product Price Targeting and
Other Monetary Anchor Options, for
Commodity-Exporters in Latin America," Economia,
vol.11, 2011 (Brookings), NBER WP 16362.