Title: FNCE 4070 Financial Markets and Institutions
1FNCE 4070Financial Marketsand Institutions
- Lecture 5 Part 2
- Forecasting With the Term Structure of Interest
Rates - (1) Forecasting Business Cycle Turning Points (A
Recession) - (2) Forecasting Future Interest Rates
(Estimating Forward Rates) - (3) Estimating Future Rates of Inflation (Using
TIPS)
2Downward Sweeping or Inverted Yield Curve And
Economic Activity
- Inverted Yield Curve An interest rate
environment in which long-term debt
instruments have a lower yield than short-term
debt instruments of the same credit quality. - This type of yield curve is the rarest of the
three main curve types and is considered by some
to be a predictor of an economic recession (i.e.,
business cycle turning point). - Why An inverted yield curve signals a future
fall in interest rates which is consistent with a
recession.
3Interest Rates and Business Cycles 1969 1983
4Interest Rate Spreads and Business Cycles 1969 -
1983
5Interest Rates and Business Cycles 1987 2011
6Interest Rate Spreads and Business Cycles 1987 -
2011
7Evidence from Australia
8Evidence From the U.K.
9Yield Curves and Recessions The Evidence
- Since the late 1980s, many researchers have
provided evidence that the yield curve, or
specifically the spread between long term and
short term interest rates, has been a predictive
signal of future recessions. They include - Arturo Estralla and Fredric Mishkin (June 1996),
The Yield Curve as a Predictor of U.S.
Recession (http//www.newyorkfed.org/research/cur
rent_issues/ci2-7.pdf), found that the yield
curve outperformed other financial and economic
indicators in predicting recessions, especially 2
to 3 quarters into the future. - Arturo Estrella and Mary R. Trubin July/August
2006 The Yield Curve as a Leading Indicator
Some Practical Issues http//www.newyorkfed.org/r
esearch/current_issues/ci12-5.pdf. Analyzed the
yield spreads for six recessions from 1970 to
2001. - Glenn D. Rudebusch and John C. Williams (July
2008), Forecasting Recessions The Puzzle of the
Enduring Power of the Yield Curve, found that a
simple model for predicting recessions that uses
only real-time yield curve information would have
produced better forecasts of recessions than
professional forecasters
10Using Probit Analysis to Test the Probability of
a Recession (Estrella and Trubin)
11Using Probit Analysis to Test the Predictive
Value of the Yield Curve (Estralla and Mishkin)
12The Yield Curve and Interest Rate Forecasting
- Two of the yield curve theories are especially
relevant for forecasting future interest rates.
They are - Pure Expectations Theory
- Which assumes no liquidity premium for longer
term debt instruments. - Liquidity Preference Theory
- Which incorporates a liquidity premium for longer
term debt instruments. - Both of these theories involves the role of
forward rates in setting spot rates. - Thus we can arrange their formulas to calculate
implied forward rates for any future period of
time.
13Forecasting with The Expectations Theory
- Recall that the Expectations Theory assumes that
the current long term spot interest rate is
comprised of - Current (spot) short term interest rate (iss) and
- Expected, future (forward) short-term interest
rates (ie). - If we assume the long term spot rate (ils) is an
average of short term rates (iss and ie), it is
possible to derive the expected forward rate
(ie), on a one-period bond for some future time
period (n-t) through the following formula
14Forecasting With The Expectations Model Example
1
- Assume the following
- Current 1 year spot (iss1) 5.0
- Current 2 year spot (ils2) 5.5
- Use the formula on the previous slide to
calculate the implied forward rate, or the 1year
rate, 1 year from now
15Yield Curve For Example 1
- The calculated forward rate of 6.00 is the
markets expected 1 year interest rate one year
from now. - This rate of 6.00 becomes our forecasted
interest rate using the pure expectations model.
- interest rate
- 6.0 oie
- 5.5 oils2
- 5.0 oiss1
- 1y 2y
- Term to Maturity
16Forecasting With The Expectations Model Example
2
- Assume the following
- Current 1 year spot (iss1) 7.0
- Current 2 year spot (ils2) 5.0
- Use the formula on the previous slide to
calculate the implied forward rate, or the 1year
rate, 1 year from now
17Yield Curve For Example 2
- The calculated forward rate of 3.04 is the
markets expected 1 year interest rate one year
from now. - This rate of 3.04 becomes our forecasted
interest rate using the pure expectations model.
- interest rate
- 7.0 oiss1
- 5.0 oils2
- 3.0 oie
- 1y 2y
- Term to Maturity
18Using the Current Yield Curve Data to Forecast
Interest Rates
- Bloomberg Data U.S. Treasuries, Feb 24, 2011
- What is the yield curve telling us about the
markets expectation regarding future interest
rates - Going up or going down? Can you approximate some
forward rates? - 3 month rate, 3 months from now?
- 1 year rate, 1 year from now?
COUPON MATURITY PRICE/YIELD
3-Month 0.000 05/26/2011 0.11 / 0.12
6-Month 0.000 08/25/2011 0.15 / 0.15
12-Month 0.000 02/09/2012 0.23 / 0.23
2-Year 0.625 02/28/2013 99-28 / 0.73
3-Year 1.250 02/15/2014 100-02 / 1.22
5-Year 2.125 02/29/2016 99-11 / 2.18
7-Year 2.625 01/31/2018 98-20 / 2.84
10-Year 3.625 02/15/2021 101-17 / 3.44
30-Year 4.750 02/15/2041 103-17½ / 4.53
19Forecasting with the Liquidity Premium Theory
- Recall that the liquidity premium theory modifies
the expectations theory formula to take into
account liquidity premiums (Ln), or - Where, Ln is the liquidity premium for holding a
bond of n maturity. - Furthermore, Ln will always be positive.
- Given the addition of a liquidity premium an
observed yield curve will always have an upward
bias. - So even if forward interest rates are expected to
stay the same, the yield curve will slope upward.
20Predictions ofFuture Interest Rate Moves with
the LP ModelNote Solid yield curve is
observed and broken line is taking out positive
LP. (a) Implied increase in forward rate
greater than LP.(b) Implied increase in
forward rate equal to LP .(c) Implied decrease
in forward rate slightly greater than LP.(d)
Implied decrease in forward rate much greater
than LP.
21Forecasting Forward Rates with the Liquidity
Premium Theory
- The liquidity premium theory formula for
calculating forward rates is as follows - Therefore, in order to forecast an actual forward
rate we need some estimate as to the liquidity
premium (Ln), which insert into the above
formula.
22Estimating the Liquidity Premium (Ln)
- U.S. Government Securities
- 1993 2007 data
- Mean Returns
- 3 month 3.96
- 6 month 4.13
- 1 year 4.28
- 2 year 4.60
- 5 year 5.07
- 10 year 5.42
- 20 year 5.92
- Liquidity Spreads (in basis points)
- 3 months -----
- 6 months 17
- 1 year 32
- 2 year 64
- 5 year 111
- 10 year 146
- 20 year 196
23Forecasting with the Liquidity Premium Theory
Example 1
- Assume the following
- Current 1 year spot (iss1) 5.0
- Current 2 year spot (ils2) 5.5
- Liquidity premium (Ln) for 2 year debt 32 basis
points (64-32). - Use the liquidity premium formula to calculate
the implied forward rate, or the 1year rate, 1
year from now
24Forecasting with the Liquidity Premium Theory
Example 2
- Assume the following
- Current 1 year spot (iss1) 7.0
- Current 2 year spot (ils2) 5.0
- Liquidity premium (Ln) for 2 year debt 32 basis
points (64-32). - Use the liquidity premium formula to calculate
the implied forward rate, or the 1year rate, 1
year from now
25Comparing Expectations and Liquidity Premium
Forecasts
- 1 year rate 7.0
- 2 year rate 5.0
- Expectations Forecast 3.04
- Liquidity Premium Forecast 2.41
- Note Expectations model understated forecast for
falling interest rates.
- 1 year rate 5.0
- 2 year rate 5.5
- Expectations Forecast 6.0
- Liquidity Premium Forecast 5.36
- Note Expectations model overstated forecast for
rising interest rates.
26An Actual Interest Rate Forecast
- Using interest rate data from March 9, 2011
Bloomberg site as follows -
- 1 year T-Bills 0.24
- 2 year T-Bills 0.69
-
- And assuming liquidity premium of 32 basis points
for 2 year Treasury debt (see slide 22). -
- Using the liquidity premium forecasting model,
calculate the 1 year rate, 1 year from now -
-
27Market Segmentations Theory
- Observation Near the end of a business expansion
(period before shaded areas) short term interest
rates (blue line) exceed long term interest
rates. - Thus, during this period we would observe a
downward sloping yield curve.
28Market Segmentations Theory Explaining the Yield
Curve Near the End of a Business Expansion
- Why is there an inverted yield curve at this
time? - Interest rates have risen during the expansionary
period and are now relatively high. - Borrowers realizing that rates are relatively
high, finance in the short term (not wanting to
lock in long term liabilities at high interest
rates). - Lenders realizing that rates are relatively high,
lend in the long term (wanting to lock in long
term assets at high interest rates) - Note Both borrowers and lenders move away from
their natural tendencies.
29Market Segmentations Yield Curve Near the End of
an Expansion
- i rate
- o Lenders supplying
longer - term funds (pushes down
rates) -
-
- Borrowers demanding shorter
o - term funds (pushes up rates)
-
- (st) Term to Maturity (lt)
30Forecasting with the Market Segmentations Theory
- The Market Segmentations Theory CANNOT be used to
forecast future spot rate (forward rates). - The Market Segmentations Theory can be used to
identify (signal) turning points in the movement
of interest rates (and in the economy itself)
based on the shape of the curve. - Downward sweeping curve suggests a fall in
interest rates, the end of an economic expansion,
and a future economic (business) recession. - Severe upward sweeping curve suggests a rise in
interest rates, the end of an economic recession,
and a future economic (business) expansion.
31Summary of Yield Curves and Business Cycles
32Estimating Future Rates of Inflation
- Using the TIPS market to determine the
breakeven inflation rate. - Assumption
- Conventional Treasury rate includes both real
rate and inflation premium. - TIPS rate is simply the real rate.
- Breakeven inflation rate Yield to maturity on
conventional Treasuries Yield to maturity on
TIPS. - Important Use similar maturities.
- Difference is the markets annual inflation
expectation over the maturity period.
33U.S. Treasury Yield Curve Site for Observing
Breakeven Rate of Inflation
- Link to the U.S. Treasury site below for the
nominal and TIPS yield curve. - http//www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart
-center/interest-rates/Pages/Historic-Yield-Data-V
isualization.aspx - From this site, one can observe the breakeven
inflation rate. - What is the most recent data telling you about
the markets expectation regarding inflation? - Set the date for January 2, 2009 and observe the
breakeven rate. - What is this date telling you about the markets
expectation regarding inflation? - From this site, one can also download the actual
data. - Note The most recent 5-year TIPS yield curve
data point is incorrect (however, the actual data
is correct). - According to the Treasury Department, the
graphing function is flawed.
34Appendix 1
- Why Do Markets Care about Yield Curves?
- The following is from Bonds on Line and
summarizes why yield curves are important.
http//www.bondsonline.com/Corporate_Bond_Yield_In
dex.phpwhy
35Using Yield Curves
- The shape of the yield curve is closely followed
by bond investors. It provides information about
the yields of short term compared to long term
fixed-income investments. Investors analyze and
interpret the yield curve shape to give some
insights on the future direction of rates and the
economy. - A yield curve normally has an upward sloping
shape. That is, in a normal yield curve,
shorter-term yields are lower than longer-term
yields, with yields generally increasing as years
to maturity increase. The yields are higher on
securities with longer maturities because these
securities are more vulnerable to price changes
caused by changes in interest rates over time.
Investors in longer-term securities are typically
rewarded with a higher yield for taking the risk
that interest rates could rise and cause the
prices of their securities to fall. - Investors pay attention to both the current shape
of the yield curve, whether it is steep or flat,
and yield curve movements. That is, investors
will look at whether the entire curve is shifting
up or down in a parallel fashion which suggests
that rates across the maturity spectrum are
changing by the same magnitude or, alternatively,
the shape or slope of the curve is becoming
flatter or steeper. For example, when Federal
Reserve monetary policy is more accommodative and
reduces short term rates, the yield curve
generally steepens, and flattens when monetary
policy tightens the Fed raises short term rates.
36Using Yield Curves
- When the yield curve is steep, that is when the
difference between short-term and long-term
yields is large, the market often expects
interest rates to rise, though there are a number
of variables, including the rate of economic
growth and inflationary expectations, that go
into interest rate analysis and forecasting the
risk at the long end of the maturity range is
therefore greater, and so is the return or
yield. When the yield curve is relatively flat,
the difference between short-term yields and
long-term yields is not that great. When this
happens, the market is not rewarding investors
for taking the risk of a longer maturity,
possibly because the market believes interest
rates will decline, causing bond prices to rise
and yields to fall. Investors holding securities
with longer maturities tend to benefit more from
a declining interest rate trend. - There have been brief and unusual periods of time
when the there has been what is known as an
inverted yield curve shape, where, at certain
points along the maturity spectrum, short-term
yields have been higher than long-term yields.
Inversely sloped yield curves are not sustainable
either short term yields will eventually fall
or long term yields rise. An inverted yield curve
is considered an omen of recession as well as
lower interest rates.
37Appendix 2
- Ben Bernanke and the 2006 Yield Curve.
- Shortly after Bernanke became Chair of the Fed
(Feb 1, 2006) he spoke before the Economic Club
of New York. The presentation to that group was
given on March 20, 2006. The yield curve which
had been upward sweeping in 2004 (and thus
normal) began to flatten in 2005 through 2006 and
was approaching almost flat by the time Bernanke
spoke. The following is a direct quote from
Bernankes presentation regarding the flattening
yield curve in 2006.
38Ben Bernanke Discusses the 2006 Yield Curve
- Although macroeconomic forecasting is fraught
with hazards, I would not interpret the currently
very flat yield curve as indicating a significant
economic slowdown to come, for several reasons.
First, in previous episodes when an inverted
yield curve was followed by recession, the level
of interest rates was quite high, consistent with
considerable financial restraint. This time, both
short- and long-term interest rates--in nominal
and real terms--are relatively low by historical
standards. Second, as I have already discussed,
to the extent that the flattening or inversion of
the yield curve is the result of a smaller
liquidity term premium, the implications for
future economic activity are positive rather than
negative. Finally, the yield curve is only one of
the financial indicators that researchers have
found useful in predicting swings in economic
activity. Other indicators that have had
empirical success in the past, including
corporate risk spreads, would seem to be
consistent with continuing solid economic growth.
In that regard, the fact that actual and implied
volatilities of most financial prices remain
subdued suggests that market participants do not
harbor significant reservations about the
economic outlook. -
39Appendix 3
- Central Bankers
- Bank of England
- ECB
- Bank of Japan
- Federal Reserve
40Mervyn Allister KingGovernor, Bank of England
- Mervyn King is Governor of the Bank of England
and is Chairman of the Monetary Policy Committee.
He was previously Deputy Governor from 1998 to
2003, and Chief Economist and Executive Director
from 1991. Mervyn King was a non-executive
director of the Bank from 1990 to 1991. - Born in 1948, Mervyn King studied at Kings
College, Cambridge, and Harvard (as a Kennedy
Scholar) and taught at Cambridge and Birmingham
Universities before spells as Visiting Professor
at both Harvard University and MIT. From October
1984 he was Professor of Economics at the London
School of Economics where he founded the
Financial Markets Group. - Mervyn King is a Fellow of the British Academy,
an Honorary Fellow of Kings and St Johns
Colleges, Cambridge and holds honorary degrees
from Birmingham, City of London, Edinburgh,
London Guildhall, London School of Economics,
Wolverhampton, Cambridge and Helsinki
Universities. He is a Foreign Honorary Member of
the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, is on
the Advisory Council of the London Symphony
Orchestra, is Patron of Worcestershire County
Cricket Club and is a Trustee of the National
Gallery.
41Jean-Claude TrichetPresident, ECB
- Jean-Claude Trichet was born December 20, 1942 in
Lyon, France. A graduate of the University of
Paris in Economics, Trichet also holds degrees in
mining engineering and worked in the private
sector before joining the French civil service. - In the early 1970s, Trichet was named the General
Inspectorate of Finance, eventually becoming the
Director of the Treasury Department in 1987. In
1993, Trichet accepted the position of Governor
of the Banque de France and was reappointed to
the same position in 1999. - After serving as a member of the Council of the
European Monetary Institute, Trichet was named to
the Governing Council of the European Central
Bank in 1998. On November 1, 2003, Jean-Claude
Trichet was named President of the European
Central Bank.
42Masaaki ShirakawaGovernor, Bank of Japan
- Governor Masaaki Shirakawa became the 30th
Governor of the Bank of Japan in April 2008. He
joined the Bank in 1972, after graduating from
the University of Tokyo with a B.A. degree in
Economics. He also received an M.A. in Economics
from the University of Chicago. - Mr. Shirakawa assumed jobs with increasing
responsibility throughout his career. He has held
a number of senior positions. In 1990-1993, he
served as Director, Head of Financial System
Division at the Financial and Payment System
Office. In 1993-1994, he headed the Planning
Division of the Policy Planning Office. In
1994-1996 he served as General Manager for Oita
Branch and General Manager for the Americas. - In 1996-1997, Mr. Shirakawa was Deputy
Director-General of the Institute for Monetary
and Economic Studies and of the International
Department. Since 1997, he served as Adviser to
the Governor at Credit and Market Management
Department, Financial Markets Department and
Policy Planning Office. He was appointed
Executive Director in 2002. - In addition to his policy work with the Bank of
Japan, Mr. Shirakawa worked in academia, as
Professor at the Kyoto University School of
Government in 2006-2008.
43Ben S. Bernanke,Governor, Federal Reserve
- Ben S. Bernanke began a second term as Chairman
of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System on February 1, 2010. Dr. Bernanke also
serves as Chairman of the Federal Open Market
Committee, the System's principal monetary
policymaking body. He originally took office as
Chairman on February 1, 2006, when he also began
a 14-year term as a member of the Board. His
second term as Chairman ends January 31, 2014,
and his term as a Board member ends January 31,
2020. - Before his appointment as Chairman, Dr. Bernanke
was Chairman of the President's Council of
Economic Advisers, from June 2005 to January
2006. - From 1994 to 1996, Dr. Bernanke was the Class of
1926 Professor of Economics and Public Affairs at
Princeton University. He was the Howard Harrison
and Gabrielle Snyder Beck Professor of Economics
and Public Affairs and Chair of the Economics
Department at the university from 1996 to 2002.
Dr. Bernanke had been a Professor of Economics
and Public Affairs at Princeton since 1985. - Before arriving at Princeton, Dr. Bernanke was an
Associate Professor of Economics (1983-85) and an
Assistant Professor of Economics (1979-83) at the
Graduate School of Business at Stanford
University. His teaching career also included
serving as a Visiting Professor of Economics at
New York University (1993) and at the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology (1989-90). - Dr. Bernanke has published many articles on a
wide variety of economic issues, including
monetary policy and macroeconomics, and he is the
author of several scholarly books and two
textbooks. He has held a Guggenheim Fellowship
and a Sloan Fellowship, and he is a Fellow of the
Econometric Society and of the American Academy
of Arts and Sciences. Dr. Bernanke served as the
Director of the Monetary Economics Program of the
National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and
as a member of the NBER's Business Cycle Dating
Committee. In July 2001, he was appointed Editor
of the American Economic Review. Dr. Bernanke's
work with civic and professional groups includes
having served two terms as a member of the
Montgomery Township (N.J.) Board of Education. - Dr. Bernanke was born in December 1953 in
Augusta, Georgia, and grew up in Dillon, South
Carolina. He received a B.A. in economics in 1975
from Harvard University (summa cum laude) and a
Ph.D. in economics in 1979 from the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology.