Title: Horizontal Mergers
1Horizontal Mergers
23.3.3. Mergers (Concentrations)
- We consider mergers between firms acting on the
same market horizontal mergers if the firms
operate at the same production stage and vertical
mergers between firms acting at different stages.
Mergers between firms in different markets
(clothing and beer...) are less likely to afect
competition and will not be adressed. - Mergers may have very different sources
- small firms trying to increase their rate of
growth - One management group convinced it can enhance the
value of a competitor - Firms with complementary assets trying to
increase their efficiency - Firms trying to increase their market power
33.3.3 Horizontal Mergers
- An horizontal merger should be evaluated on the
basis of its - unilateral effects, or reinforcment of its single
firm dominance and - pro-collusive effects or or joint dominance
(coordinated effects) effects. - We have seen that collusion is always harmful to
consumers and social welfare. - In the case of mergers, the implications to
welfare are less clear in fact, usually a merger
increases the market power or the dominant
position of the merging firms, being detrimental
to consumers and social welfare. But it may also
happen that it increases efficiency
43.3.3 Unilateral effects of horizontal mergers
- Unilateral effects or reinforcement of single
dominance occurs when the merged firm does not
coordinate its behaviour with its rivals firms
behave non-cooperatively, both before and after
the merger (art 12 of Law 18/2003) - Unilateral effects are of two types
- Mergers tends to increase the market power of the
merging firms, leading to an increase in prices
and a decrease in consumers surplus and welfare.
This has distributional and allocative negative
consequences - This negative effect may be partially or totally
offset by efficiency gains
53.3.3.Increase in market power
- There is a decrease in the nº of participants,
whose impact on the competitiveness of the market
depends on the nº of competitors, on the
dimension of the merging firms, on their
strategies... - If firms compete on prices, (Bertrand) the merge
leads to an increase on the price of the merged
firm and of its rivals. Consumers welfare
decreases. - If firms compete on quantities, (Cournot) then
the output of the merged firm decreases (it
raises its price) but the output of the rivals
increase (reduce their price). However, overall,
the effect on consumers surpluse is also negative
63.3.3.Increase in market power
- As to profits, in general the merger should
increase the profits of the merging firms, and - The profits of outside firms do increase, too. In
fact, outsiders can gain even more than the
merging firms themselves. (That is probably the
reason why outsiders rarely complain of projected
mergers) - Producers surplus unambiguously increases
- However, it can be shown that welfare decreases,
if there are no efficiency gains associated with
the merger
73.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
- Concentration
- the larger the of firms after the merger, the
less detrimental it is - The lower the market shares of merging firms, the
less detrimental to welfare the merger is and
even without efficiency gains, a merger between
two small firms may increase welfare. But mergers
that increase the size of the largest firm or
that create a new largest firm always decrease
welfare - The relative productive capacities of all the
participants if the rivals are not able to
satisfy additional demand, the market power of
the merged firm increases. Otherwise it
decreases.
83.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
- - Remember the Concentration Index of
Herfindahl-Hirschman (HHI) - More than the level of concentration, one should
look at its change US agencies consider that
mergers leading to values of HHI lower than 1000
do not harm competition. - If post merger HHI is between 1000 and 1800
(moderate concentration), the merger is allowed
unless the increase in the value of HHI is larger
than 100.
93.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
- If the value of the HHI exceeds 1800 after the
merger, this will be allowed iif this values
increase is not larger than 50. - Another indicator of the effect on competition
of a merger between firms A and B is the change
in the elasticity of the residual demand function
e A,A e A,B this measures the effect on
Ademand of a 1 percent increase in As price
minus the effect on As demand of the same
increase in the price of B. This difference
expresses the market power of A, ie, when A and B
coordinate their strategy and increase prices
simultaneously, firm A will loose the consumers
going to other firms minus those that would have
gone to firm B
103.3.3. Increase in unilateral market power
- Another relevant indicator of the market power of
the merging firms is the diversion ration
dAeAB/eAA the proportion of lost sales that is
captured by product B when As prices increase,
or the proportion of consumers that consider B
their second best alternative to A - This ratio measures the intensity of pre-merger
competition between A and B a small value of d
means that A and B are not close competitors and
the merge should not have a significant effect on
market power - Under some conditions dAmB/1-mA meaning that
the probability that B is the second best option
to A equals the market share of B relative to the
market share of all the participants with the
exception of A
113.3.3. Other factors affecting the unilateral
impact of a merger
- Entry the easier and less costly entry is, the
lower the market power enjoyed by merging firms - Potential entrants that anticipated negative
profits at the pre-merger price may become
profitable after the merger this possibility may
restrain the merging firm from increasing prices - The countervailing buyers power strong buyers
limit the sellerss market power - This is true but does not imply that the lower
prices are passed to consumers if the buyers
market is in itself non-competitive ...
123.3.3. Other factors affecting the unilateral
impact of a merger
- Switching costs increase market power
- The failing firm defence a merger between two
firms, one of which was comdemned anyway, does
not hurt competition - If production depends on the availability of
essential inputs, the access of rivals to those
inputs is relevant. - Techonological innovation
- The structure of the distribution networks
133.3.3. Efficiency Gains
- Efficiency gains may outweight the increase in
market power of merging firms and result in
higher welfare (lower prices). These may be due
to - Rationalisation savings from reallocating output
from one facility to another, without changing
joint output. (Marginal costs may be different,
prior to the merger, due to different amounts os
physical capital, different levels of knowledge,
different output levels) - Economies of scale and scope
- long-run economies of scale in production, RD
and marketing and distribution). Notice that
exploitation of economies of scale may imply a
decrease in product diversity
143.3.3. Efficiency Gains
- short-run economies of scale (due to elimination
of indivisibilities in inputs, like billing,
purchases of materials) this implies a decrease
in fixed costs. - Technological Progress either process
innovations or product innovations or quality
improvements - Diffusion of know-how (either one way or two way)
- Incentives for R D (too much competition could
destroy the incentives for research, and a merger
coul help the internalisation of benefits
153.3.3. Efficiency Gains
- Purchasing Economies
- If factor markets are imperfectly competitive
the merger can increase welfare - The merger can have quantity discounts
- Slack
- Disciplining power of the capital market (threat
of entry and a strict merger policy...) - When a merger has efficiency gains, and an
overall positive effect on welfare, outside firms
will always lose profits. Then, a possible test
for expected efficiency gains associated with an
announced merger is to look at competitors shares
value
163.3.3.Efficiency Gains
- if these decrease, economic analist predict an
increase in efficiency of the merged firms (of
course, these changes can also be due to wrong
predictions, to speculation, to external shocks,
to expectations relative to the competition
authority decision -if CA is expected to prohibit
the merger, even when it has efficiency gains,
rivals' shares might even increase, due to the
regulatory costs incurred by the merging
firms...). - If outside firms complain about the
anti-competitive effects of a merger, CA should
treat those complaints with great scepticism
(they can mean that they anticipate significant
efficiency gains, that is, that the merger is
welfare increasing).
173.3.3. Efficiency Gains
- Notice that efficiency gains decreasing variable
costs are more likely to affect welfare through
price reductions and increases in consumers
welfare, while efficiency gains affecting only
fixed costs will not lead to price changes, but
impact profits only. - Farrell and Shaphir argue that CA should consider
only efficiency gains obtained by synergies ,
intimate integration of the firmss unique, hard
to trade assets while no-synergies efficiency
gains, like those derived from mere
reorganization of production among facilities,
should be disregarded
183.3.3. Efficiency Gains
- A problem with the consideration of efficiency
gains is that they are usually hard to calculate
and completely dependent on information
exclusively hels by the firm - In assessing efficiency gains of a merger it is
very important to show that these efficiency
improvements could not have taken place in the
absence of the merger - Efficiency gains should be computed net of costs
193.3.3.Pro-collusive effects of horizontal mergers
- A merger may reinforce the incentives for
collusion, or joint dominance, (coordinated
effects). - The effect of efficiency gains in joint dominance
is more difficult to analyse. In general, if
efficiency gains result in lower costs or higher
capacity, incentives to deviate increase (and the
stability of collusion decreases). But if
symmetry increases, incentives to form stable
collusive agreements increase, the overall impact
on welfare may be negative.
203.3.3.Remedies
- The decision of competition Authorities
concerning mergers can be Yes, No, or Yes But,
imposing remedies for the merger to be allowed. - Remedies can be of two broad types
- Structural, which change the ownership of
property rights, i.e., may oblige the merging
firms to sell part of their holdings (usually
applied in network industries where the merger
may create regional monopolies) - Behavioural impose some restrictions on the
behaviour of the merging firms, in particular
concerning the practice of foreclosure
213.3.3. Structural Remedies
- Divestitures
- If the merger is expected to have
anti-competitive consequences on some
geographical markets or product markets, the CA
may order a divestment of assets - These assets can be acquired by an existing
competitor or by a new firm, but the CA should
require that the buyer is enabled with the
conditions to become an active competitor all
the elements required ...to act as a viable
competitor..tangible (.RD, production,
distribution, sales and marketing activities) and
intangibles (such as intellectual prperty rights
and goodwill) assets, personnel, supply and sales
agreements, customer lists.....and so forth
(Commission Notice on remedies, page 46)
223.3.3. Structural Remedies
- Divestitures
- The authority may also order divestiture of
assets that do not represent an anti-competitive
thereat, if there are economies of scale or
network egffects - Problems with divestitures
- Incentives of the sellers to decrease the value
of the divested business, and to choose a
non-effective competitor - Informational assymetries between seller and
buyers the seller does not sell all of the
inputs required for competition to materialise - Empirical studies have shown that if the buyer
must continue to have a relationship with the
seller, either they will collude or the buyer
neves becomes an efective competitor - Buyers that intend to collude in the future will
be willing to pay more for the assets have a
larger probability of getting them - If symmetry increases, the outcome may be
collusion
233.3.3. Behavioural Remedies
- Commitments to guarantee a level-playing field on
the use of assets, technologies, inputs
(vertical firewalls, obligation of the merged
firms to sell a technology or an essential input
to entrant competitors ...) - A problem with these remedies is that they
require a continuous monitoring and enforcement.
Further, they are usually easy to evade, given
that the CA lacks sufficiently detailed knowledge
of the industry
243.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- Most empirical studies analysed the evolution of
profitability accounting profits or shares
prices. If these increase, either market power
increased or there were efficiency gains, or a
combination of the two. This type of evidence can
not discriminate between the two effects. - Additional evidence on consumer prices, on the
prices of the shares of the competing firms (if
these increase, reinforcement of market power
dominated) can help the distinction between these
effects - There are also some empirical studies that tried
to directly quantify efficiency gains
253.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- Limits
- The nº of studies is very small
- The evidence on company performance is
contradictory - The majority of the studies concern
manufacturing, in the 60s and 70s and in the USA
263.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- The empirical evidence on the profitability of
mergers shows very clearly that the potential
benefits from mergers are usualy exagerated and
that its costs are often undervalued the market
overestimates the ability of bidders to manage
other companies assets - Mergers as managerial discipline the idea that
mergers improve efficiency because less efficient
managers tend to be substituted for more
efficient ones has not been clearly proved by
empirical analysis, too. Further , according to
Matusaka (93) the market prefers bidders who do
not replace the management of the acquired
companies
273.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- Empirical analysis of the mergers on the US
airline industry between 1985 and 1988 shows that
merged firms tended to price higher than the
others, suggesting that eventual inctreases in
efficiency that might have taken place were
outweighted by the reinforcment of market power,
leading to overall welfare decreases. - Conclusions
- Horizontal mergers seem to increase market power
- There is no support for a general presumption
that mergers create efficiency gains - In particular cases, however, there were
segnificant efficiency gains
283.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- Profit flows studies mergers have but modest
effects on the profitability of merging firms - If market power increases then the merger
increases inefficiencies - Outsiders may gain more than merging firms dont
have to reduce quantity and profit from the
increase in prices - Studies of share prices The most puzzling result
of this literature is the fact that, while
profits decrease, share prices increase. The
pre-emptive merger motive? The merger decreases
profits compared to the status quo, but increases
profits compared with the relevant alternative
293.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- The US Competition authorities have been quite
strict in analysing mergers requiring
extraordinarily large efficiency gains to allow
it when there are potential adverse competitive
effects. - The EU Merger Guidelines recognizes the role of
efficiency gains on the appraisal of a merger,
but the Commission until now has followed a more
ambiguous approach. Indeed in same cases,
efficiency gains were even considered a minus, in
that they would hurt rivals. - However, in its present formulation, the approval
of non competitive mergers on the grounds that
they could create national champions, like France
wanted, has not passed.
303.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- Criteria for (not) considering efficiency
increases - Redistributive gains should not be considered
saving in costs due to discounts from suppliers - Cost savings associated with quantity reductions
- If the criteria is consumers surplus, cost
savings in fixed costs, like administrative
costs, should not be considered - Effects on other markets in Germany, the UK, and
Portugal are considered while US courts do not
313.3.3.Empirical evaluation of mergers
- There are 3 basic approaches to the appraisal of
a merger - Case-by-case analysis high informational costs
- General presumption model, using general
structural indicators high uncertainty costs,
because empirical studies show that particular
circumstances may have large impact on the result
of a given concentration - Sequential approach in a first step, structural
indicators are used to arrive at an initial
decision. In a second phase an efficiency
defence with a a more detailed investigation,
is allowed
323.3.3. Summing-up
- In the analysis of a prospective Merger, the CA
must evaluate - Its anti-competitive effects
- Eventual increases in efficiency
- In general, mergers increase the welfare of the
merging firms, but decrease overall welfare. - In the appraisal of the effects of a merger,
attention must be taken with the problems of
information asymmetry between the merging units
and the authority - A possible solution is to look only at the
effects of the operation on the welfare of
consumers and outside firms, assuming that its
effect on the welfare of the proponent is always
positive
33Vertical Restraints and Vertical Integration
343.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Often a product goes through different stages of
production and comercialization before reaching
the final consumer - Vertical restraints are agreements and
contractual provisions betweeen vertically
related firms. These may be aimed at - Reducing transactions costs
- Guarantee availability and security of supply...
- Coordination...
- These vertical restraints can take many different
forms and in some circumstances they may have
differentiated impact on welfare -
353.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Vertical mergers have in common with vertical
restraints the fact that they both aim at solving
coordination problems - However these two problems receive a different
treatment under Competition Law. In the EU,
vertical mergers fall under the Mergers
Regulation, while vertical restraints can be the
object of art 81 (agreement between firms ) or of
art 82 if the firm has a dominant position
363.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Example Consider a manufacturer and a retailer.
- Due to an horizontal externality, the effort of
the retailer associated with the sale of the
output tends to be sub-optimal in fact, unless
the retailer has the monopoly of the sale, his
investments on the promotion of the good has a
public good characteristic - This horizontal externality arises because the
seller shares with other retailers the benefits
of its efforts to increase sales, while the costs
remain concentrated. Unless the manufacturer
devises a mechanism to increase the benefits of
the retailer, this ones investment will be
sub-optimal
373.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- In order to lead the retailer to increase its
efforts on the promotion of its sales, the
manufacturer may pursue a set of possible
policies such as - Give the retailer the exclusive of the sale, so
that it has incentives to advertise the product
without the fear of creating externalities to
rivals - Practice non-linear pricing (a two-part tariffs
including a fixed fee for access to the product
plus a variable (low) price per unit sold this
scheme is common in several brands of clothes
383.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Other possible policies are
- Give the retailer quantity discounts or
progressive rebates - Require the sale of a minimum amount or of a
maximum amount (in this case not to allow for
price decreases) - Lead the retailer not to sell competing brands,
by exclusivity clauses - Practice resale price maintenance of several
forms (RPM) (fixed, price ceiling, price floor) - Create exclusive territorial schemes
- Adopt selective distribution policies (forbid the
sale in supermarkets , for fear of decreasing the
image)
393.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- These policies need not be available at the same
time and their respective usefulness depends on
the particular circumstances for instance, if
the final price paid by consumers is not easily
observable by the manufacturer, then RPM is not
adequate... - If arbitrage is easy, these vertical restraints
may be impossible to set. Arbitrage in turn
depends on the relative costs of search, on
transaction costs, on transport costs - Low transport costs eliminate the efectiveness of
exclusive territory clauses... - An alternative is a vertical merger
403.3.3.Vertical Integration
- Vertical integration involves the firm
undertaking itself the various stages of the
production/distribution process the integrated
firm substitutes internal operations and
transfers for what would otherwise be market
transactions - Williamson stressed that a firm may have several
motives other than reinforcment of market power
to vertically integrate - Minimize the negative effects of uncertainty
- Reduce the dependency of the firm on outside
suppliers or buyers, particularly relevant if a
particular production stage requires specific
assets - Easen the solution of conflicts, that remain
within the firm
413.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- The welfare effects of vertical restraints depend
on whether the vertical relations are intra-brand
or inter-brand - Intra-brand competition refers to markets where
retailers sell the same product or brand - Vertical restraints affecting intra-brand
competition are usually welfare-increasing they
allow a better coordination of the vertical chain
and do not harm competition - If there is a monopoly at each stage then
vertical integration avoids double
marginalization and is welfare increasing, in
that it allows the internalization of this
vertical externality
423.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Double Marginalization and vertical integration
- Demand is qa-p
- Firm U (upstream), the manufacturer, has unit
production cost of c and sells to a retailer,
firm D (downstream) - Firm D buys product from firm U at a cost w. Its
comercialization cost is equal to zero and sells
to final consumers at p - First firm U chooses the wholesale price, w
- Second Firm D chooses p, given w
433.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- The problem of the downstream firm, under
vertical separation, is - Max PD(p-w)q (p-w).(a-p)
- FOC are p(aw)/2
- (1) q(a-w)/2
- PD(a-w)2/4
- Now, firm U knows that the quantity of q it sells
depends on w. So it chooses w such as - Max PU(w-c)(a-w)/2
- FOC is w(ac)/2
443.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Substituting back in (1) one gets
- psep(3ac)/2
- PDsep (a-c)2/16
- PUsep (a-c)2/8
- PDsep PDsep 3(a-c)2/16
453.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Under Vertical integration, firm U sells directly
to consumers. So it chooses p so that - Max Pvi(p-c)(a-p)
- FOCgtpvi(ac)/2
- qvi (a-c)/2
- Pvi (a-c)2/4
- gtVertical integration is unambiguously better
- Prices are lower, since agtc or the market would
not exist - Quantities are larger, because cltwgt
- Consumer surplus increases
- Profits are larger, too firm U can pay firm D at
least the profit it has under separation - Overall welfare must increase
463.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- If a vertical merger is not possible, several
alternative and equivalent vertical restraints
can solve this vertical externality - A. Resale price maintenance, RPM
- Imposing the final price ppvi(ac)/2, vertical
profits are maximized. Their distribution between
the 2 firms depends on the wholesale price, w. If
firm U is stronger, it will set wpvi(ac)/2 and
will keep all the profits. The higher is w, the
higher the share of profits that goes to the
upstream firm. The same will hold if the upstream
firm sets a price ceiling p(ac)/2
473.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- B. Quantity Fixing, QF
- Firm U may oblige firm D to buy qvi(a-c)/2, or
qgtqvi. Again, the level of w, which determines
the relative distribution of profits, depends on
the bargaining power of the 2 parties - C. Franchise Fee, FF
- Firm U makes firm D pay Fwq, and sets wc. Then,
firm Ds problem is - Max PDff(p-c)(a-p)-F
- The solution is ppvi(ac)/2, qqvi, because F
does not affect FOC. - The distribution of profits depends on F, as PUff
F, and PDff (a-c)2/4-F. If firm U has all the
bargaining power it will set F(a-c)2/4
483.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Under uncertainty, this equivalence disappears.
Suppose that the retailer is risk-averse. Then, - if uncertainty refers to demand, RPM is a perfect
insurance mechanism for the retailer, and - if uncertainty affects costs, non-linear pricing
improves his situation - Summing-up
- Under double marginalization -a vertical
externality- vertical mergers, RPM, QF, FF lead
to higher welfare - When competition at the retail level increases,
the price-margin at this level deceases and
welfare improves Policies that decrease
competition at the retail level, like ET or
exclusive retailers aggravates the double
marginalization problem
493.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Horizontal Externality
- free riding on the provision of services like
advertising may lead to the under provision of
these services, which is sub-optimal for firm U
and for consumers. Again vertical integrationa
and some vertical restrictions can help solve the
problem - Exclusive territories decresases the probability
that each consumer visits several shops - Fix resale prices or setting price floors may
allow retailers to recoup their investments - Vertical integration can again solve the problem
503.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Conclusions
- Vertical integration and vertical restraints
equivalent to it, (which lead to the same
outcome) reduces prices and increases output
welfare increases - Different types of restrictions are equivalent
hence choice between them should depend on the
particular circumstances (RPM is ineffective when
prices are non-observable, ET is irrelevant if
transport costs are too low...) - Then competition policy should not prohibit some
of these practices while allowing the others
513.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Effect upon variety
- Consider now that n is variable
- under vertical integration there will be less
stores an integrated firm when deciding whether
or not to open a new store, will consider its
effect upon the profits of the pre-existing
stores - Consumer surplus will be lower, but overall
welfare may still be higher because the fixed
cost of the marginal firm is saved. (Too much
competition can lead to excessive differentiation)
523.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- So vertical integration decreases prices, but
decreases variety, too. But most models conclude
that, under plausible assumptions regarding
preferences increasing preference for variety-
welfare increases - The main point is that vertical and horizontal
externalities create an opportunity for welfare
increasing vertical restraints - No prohibition per se should exist a rule of
reason is more appropriate - When the two types of externalities are present,
the internalization of both externalities
requires the use of at least two instruments. An
example is Exclusive territories ET Franchise
fee FF
533.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- ETFF
- ET eliminates the pecuniary horizontal
externality. (There is no fear of a rival
undercutting the price) and the non-linear
contract FF solves the double marginalization
problem (ET QF does also solve the vertical
externality) - If competition is scarce, vertical restraints can
also reduce welfare in order to attract new
customers, a vertically integrated monopolist can
over-invest in quality, for instance. Infra
marginal consumers (who do not value extra
effort) may be harmed and overal consumerss
welfare may decrease
543.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Other efficiency reasons for vertical restraints
and vertical mergers - Quality certification by some retailers has a
value. If other firms can undercut these firms
prices, no certification will occur Hence RPM or
selective distribution policies may be welfare
increasing - Exclusive contracts because of free-riding
between products, can increase the level of
service by retailers - Exclusive dealing may also increase competition
- Restraints that promote specific investments
long-term contracts may avoid opportunistic
behaviour (a firm jumping out of the relationship
after the other has done specific investments...
553.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Negative Effects of Welfare Restraints
- The Commitment Problem if vertical restraints
help a manufacturer to commit to high prices,
they will be welfare decreasing - Consider a manufacturer who auctions a franchise.
He would get the monopoly profit, P, if
canditates believed they would remain the sole
sellers in the area. But after having sold that
right for P, the manufacturer has incentives to
auction a second license, by P/2 anticipating
this, no one will offer him P on the 1st stage - Most Favoured Nation clauses, MFN, make a
commitment credible. Notice that EC
anti-discrimination policies are equivalent to
enforcement of MFN.
563.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Conclusions
- Vertical restraints can deteriorate welfare if
contracts are non-observable, the monopolist has
incentives to renegotiate them and anticipating
this, a retailer would not set a contract, which
deprives the monopolist of its market power. ET
and RPM can solve this commitment problem and
decrease welfare. - Imposing non discrimination or transparency
clauses solves the commitment problem
573.3.3.Vertical Restraints
- Vertical restraints that affect only intra-brand
competition are mostly welfare-enhancing they
can solve the vertical externality problem and
increase profits. In most cases they will
increase consumers surplus, too - However, vertival restraints can decrease
welfare, if they lead to an excessive production
of services or when they solve the commitment
problem (to high prices) of the monopolist - If the market-power of the firms upstream is not
large, its effect is not serious
583.3.3.Inter-brand competition
- Consider now several manufacturers and several
retailers. Vertical restraints may play an
anti-competitive role, detrimental to social
welfare. Inter brand competition can be affected
by vertical restrainst in different ways - 1-. Strategic effects of vertical restraints (it
may be used to relax competition and increase
profits) - 2- It may favour collusion RPM increases
observability and may be used to sustain
collusive agreements - 3- It may foreclose efficient entry or deny
access to essential inputs - efficiency (double marginalization avoided) and
competition may be affected in opposite
directions and the net effect needs to be
evaluated on a case by case.
593.3.3.Leverage and foreclosure
- Exclusive dealing Since the 50s the Chicago
school contested the possibility that exclusive
contracts lead to foreclosure - Posner and Brock arguments
- Consider 1 incumbent monopolist, a buyer and a
potential entrant the buyer will not sign an
exclusive dealing agreement with the incumbent
unless it expects to gain. It may gain either
because the incumbent is more efficient than
potential entrants and sets lower prices or
because it is compensated by the incumbent.
Posner and Brock show that there will exist a
compensation that leads the buyer to accept the
contract only if the incumbent has lower marginal
cost than the entrant.
603.3.3. Exclusive Dealing
- The largest compensation that the incumbent will
pay amount to area cipMAC, the lost monopoly
profit - the minimum compensation required by the buyer
will be area cipMAC, the loss in consumer surplus - gt If exclusive contracts are signed, they must
entail efficiency gains, and should not be
prohibited
A
pM
M
B
C
ci
ce
613.3.3.Leverage and foreclosure
- Post Chicago School arguments
- Exclusive dealing may have anti-competitive
effects if by excluding a more efficient entrant
the incumbent makes profit M and is able to
increase its market power in other markets (a
possible reason is to enjoy economies of scope,
unavailable to the entrant) he could convince the
buyer to accept the deal and use these to
foreclosure the market - Other models stress other possible channels
whereby a less efficient incumbent can
foreclosure the market (a large number of
uncoordinated buyers, for example)
623.3.3.Policy implications
- Vertical restraints may be welfare-enhancing
- Thus it is not desirable to have a fixed rule vs
vertical arranjements a case by case analysis
(rule of reason) should be used - Properly designed vertical agreements and
contracts can lead to the same results as
vertical mergers. - This implies that these practices should be seen
as substitutes and given the same tratment under
competition law enforcment
63Predation and other Exclusionary abuses
643.3.3.Exclusionary abuses art 82
- Exclusionary abuses behaviour by dominant firms
that have a foreclosure effect on the market,
i.e. which are likely to completely or partially
deter entry or force the exit of
rival.(monopolisation in the US, art 82 in
Europe) - Foreclusure may
- Discourage entry
- Limit expansion
- Encourage the exit of rivals from the market
- That is, it does not require that exit actually
takes place
653.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Exclusion of rivals may be pursued through the
practice of low prices, with the aim of deterring
entry, by decreasing rivals anticipated
revenues. - Predation can also assume the form of non-pricing
predatory strategies, pursued by a firm with the
objective of increasing rivalss costs.
Over-investment, tying and bundling,
incompatibility decisions, refusal to supply,
exclusive dealing are examples of such mechanisms - This type of non-price predatory behaviour may be
pursued by non-dominant firms, too
663.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Foreclosure or predation may assume different
forms - Horizontal foreclusure
- Predatory pricing
- Single branding rebates
- Tying and bundling
- Vertical foreclosure
- Refusal to supply
- Examples of equivalent behaviours
- Contractual tying vs. a pricing strategy of high
stand-alone prices in comparison with low bundled
price for 2 products - Contractual exclusive branding vs. high rebates
in single branding
673.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Refusal to supply vs. high upstream price and low
downstram (near to final consumers) prices
(margin squeeze) - Predation
- The theory of predatory pricing assumes that a
dominant firm lowers its prices for a
sufficiently long period to induce competitors to
leave the market and/or to deter entry. - To be efective, the predatory strategy must imply
significant losses to the rivals - If the entrants are as efficient as the
incumbent, then this one will suffer losses, too. - Notice dominant firms may be kept from lowering
prices, to avoid problems with the CA)
683.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- For predation to be a profitable strategy,
incumbents must have a reasonable expectation of
gaining exploitable market power in the future - To start a predatory behaviour, incumbents must
also have conditions to survive to its
competitors, either through greater cash reserves
(deeper pockets), easiest access to capital
markets or cross subsidization from other markets
or other products. - In some conditions, predation in one product or
geographic market can have profitable effects on
other markets, through the enforcement of the
reputation of being a tough competitor
693.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- This effect can be enforced by the realization of
investments in (over)capacity in the period
immediately before entry occurs excess capacity
lowers prices and these investments could be seen
as a credible commitment to fight. - In short, for the practice of a low price to be a
predatory strategy, and not the result of fierce
competition it must be shown that - The firm is dominant
- It has the intention to exclude rivals
- It is profitable to lower prices, because gains
in the long rum will outweigh present losses
703.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- According to the theory, price predation, to be
effective, should be difficult to identify. In
fact, for it to be a rational strategy, the
victim must be unsure that predation is occurring
-otherwise it will not leave the market, knowing
that prices will increase in the future. - Because of this, predation is hard to prove
- There are some empirical papers trying to
investigate predatory pricing behaviour McGee
(1958) studied the Standard Oil Trust behaviour
at the turn of the century, Burns studied the
tobbaco trust in the US (1891-1906) Salop and
White analysed antitrust litigation . Usually
these analysis show that price predation is very
hard to prove
713.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- The theory of predatory pricing has been
criticized by some authors, that argued that
predation is an irrational strategy. - In particular, McGee and Easterbrook argued
that, given the incumbents market share,
predation would be more costly to him than to his
rivals, and that his costs would increase with
the success of the predatory strategy. - Their main point is that this fact makes
predation non- credible to competitors. The
losses associated with the predatory strategy
must be weighted against future and uncertain
gains.
723.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Those future gains are uncertain because there
are a of factors that may render the strategy
of deterring entry unsucessful the entrant may
have celebrated long-term contracts with
customers that will not allow it to disappear, or
it may shut down and waite for the increase in
prices.... And if the entrant in fact gives up
entry, in the future other firms may come
in..(but entry and exit have sunk costs..). - According to McGee, predatory pricing is
irrational becauses a merger (if allowed) would
be a better solution.
733.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- And why wouldnt a small firm, even if
financially constrained, be able to explain the
predatory strategy to its lenders, thus obtaining
the necessary funds? - However note that for future acquisition, a
strategy of predatory pricing aimed at lowering
the acquisition price could be a good solution
predation for mergers
743.3.3.Predation
- Theoretical Explanations for predatory behaviour
Imperfect Information - A. Reputation models (for future contacts) an
incumbent may set prices below cost to signal
that he is a strong competitor - B. Signalling models (limit-pricing), an
incumbent may set prices below cost to to
manipulate the beliefs of rivals and convince
them that he is more efficient than he really is
or to damage the market information available to
the entrants (signal jamming) - C. Imperfect Financial Markets models financial
distress increases the risk, and lenders know
that the larger the distress the larger is the
probability that owners and managers will engage
in excessively risky stategies
753.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Non-price predation, or raising rivals costs,
concerns the abuse of judicial and/or
administrative procedures in order to raise
rivals costs - If prices stay constant, the predator gains
market share, as the rival restricts output. If
prices increase, the predators margin increases. - Predation can occur through an abuse of
governnment procedures, including litigation and
the misuse of licensing or regulatory
authorities. - Creation of standards, government regulations,
exclusionary rights to inputs or sales network
(vertical restrictions), the denial of access to
essential facilities, bundling and tie-in sales...
763.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- In all these cases the dominant firm is able to
spread its costs over a larger output than its
rivals increasing disproportionately their costs - Unlike predatory pricing, non-pricing predation
does not presuppose a dominant position of the
predator nor that it develops its activity in
multiple markets - Advertising and innovation might also be used
with a predatory objective. - Several of the strategies that may be of a
predatory nature can also be the outcome of a
vigorous competition from an efficient supplier.
It is very important to distinguish these
situations.
773.3.3.Exclusionary abuses
- Mistaking predation for competitive pricing
(false positive) is as problematic as mistaking
competitive pricing for predation (false
negative). Both errors create problems and
inhibit competition - To prove a predatory pricing strategy it is
necessary - To prove that costs are below a certain cost
standard (marginal cost? Other?) - To prove the intention to exclude rivals
- To prove the capacity of the predator to recoup
the losses in the future
783.3.3.Tests of Predatory Pricing the Areeda
Turner
- In 1975 Areeda and Turner, proposed, in the
Harvard Law Review, a test to be used by courts
on the definition of predatory prices, ie, on the
proof that prices are below a cost standard - The test reflects the view of its authors that
predation is rare and that should not be confused
with vigorous and healthy competition. In fact we
will see that under this test predation is hard
to prove. - The test aims at protecting only firms that are
as efficient as the incumbent. - The test focuses on short-term efficiency, rather
than long-run.
793.3.3.Tests of Predatory Pricing the Areeda
Turner
- Its first standard is marginal-cost, but
recognizing that it is usually difficult to
measure marginal costs, they use average variable
costs as a proxy. (the relevant time period, is
the duration of the low pricing episode) - Hence, according to the Areeda Turner test,
prices at or above reasonably anticipated average
variable costs should be presumed legal, and
prices below average variable costs cost should
be illegal. Prices above full costs should be per
se legal. - In addition, costs associated with promotional
spending designed at meeting competition, should
not be included .
803.3.3.Tests of predatory pricing Posner and ATC
- This test raised a number of criticism ...(this
rule) produces a defendants paradise, a
monopolists heaven - Posner argued that the long-run is the relevant
period of analysis hence prices should be
compared with long-run marginal costs. Given the
unavailability of these, the test should use full
average cost based on the operators records - The demonstration of a predatory pricing
strategy would require the test that prices were
below ATC, plus the demonstration of predatory
motivation (sometimes on press statements of
company officials ...), plus the existence of
some pre-requisites.
813.3.3.Output Restriction rule
- Pre-requisites are an initial showing by the
plaintiff of the market availability to
predation the predator works in more markets
that the plaintiffs, markets are concentrated,
entry is slow, fringe firms are few, the product
is homogeneous... - Williamson argued that predatory pricing should
be seen as a long run business strategy hence
the marginal cost-based tests proposed by Areeda,
although correct, are incomplete, because they do
not take into account the post-predatory period.
823.3.3.Output Restriction rule
- For instance if a dominant firm anticipates that
entry may occur and that it will be subject to
the average variable cost rule, it can over
invest in the period prior to entry, expanding
output and lowering prices without violating the
rule. - These side effects of anti-predatory prices
should be taken into account when designing
policy. Otherwise equally efficient entrants
could be forced out
833.3.3.Output Restriction rule
- So he proposed to prohibit dominant firms to
expand output in the 12 to 18 months after entry
occurs.. This time should be sufficient for
entrants to gain experience and customers. During
this period, price could not fall below average
variable cost, too. It it did, the firm would
have to decrease output in order to increase
price. - Besides proving that this rule would be better in
terms of welfare, he also considered that it
would be easier to implement, because it wouldnt
require estimating average and marginal costs. - In general prices should cover long-run average
costs,
843.3.3.Baumol and strategic predation
- While Williamson focused on controlling output
increases in response to entry, Baumol looked at
price increases after the entrant has been driven
out the market. He proposed that any price cut
made in response to entry should continue after
exit, for some 5 years. This way, he eliminates
the incentives of the predator to suffer losses
in the first period anticipating monopoly profits
in the second period - This rule dispenses any cost accounts and would
allow equally efficient firms to survive.
853.3.3. Scherer rule-of reason tests
- Scherer argues that long-run allocative
efficiency can not be guaranteed by a simple
short-run cost-based test. He proposes a
wide-ranging inquiry into the predators conduct
and intentions. - He stands that long-run welfare may be maximised
with prices above or below marginal costs,
depending on the circumstances that depends on
the relative efficiencies of the firms, the
minimum efficient scale... - This proposal, of a wide ranging inquiry into the
particular conditions of the market intentions...
has regained attention in the EU
863.3.3.Phlips
- He states that the Williamson and Baumol
approaches could facilitate collusion, and that
the Areeda Turner test is under-inclusive and
difficult to apply he defended the idea of the
inquiry. - The benchmark, ie, the normal competitive price
would be the non-collusive profit maximising
oligopoly price (The Cournot Nash solution) - The inquiry should aim at determining wether the
conduct of the alleged predator had turned a
positive entry valueinto a negative one
873.3.3. Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
- Joskow and Klevorick in a 1979 article proposed a
two stage approach to predatory pricing. The idea
is that the first thing to do is to assess wether
predation is a workable strategy in the market
where it allegedly occurred. This first phase
should eliminate harassment suits and decrease
the risks of false positive cases, ie, confusing
competition with predation. - This initial analysis should comprise the
analysis of - Short-run monopoly power (predators market
share, larger than 60, and the elasticity of
demand for its products)
883.3.3.Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
- Conditions of entry (capital requirements,
consumers loyalty, learning curves, quality of
information about the risks of entry) - Dynamic effects of competitors and entry (stable
markets pose more problems than fast growing
markets, incumbents very innovative are less
problematic, prices responsive to changes in
demand or supply condition are also less likely
to induce predatory behaviour) - If this first phase analysis leads to the
conclusion that predation is not likely to occur,
no pricing rule should be applied
893.3.3. Two-tier Rule of Joskow and Klevorick
- In the second stage, a broad inquiry into pricing
should be conducted - Prices below average variable costs should be
deemed predatory - Prices between average variable costs and
average costs should be presumed predatory - Prices above total costs are presumed legal
unless a price cut in response to entry was
reversed within two years without a cost or
demand based reason - The probability of recouping present losses in
the future should also be taken into consideration
903.3.3.Conclusions
- The predator should have some market power before
predation takes place - There must be some cost-based measures against
which prices are evaluated short run or lung
run? Variable or total cost? - Most people agree that RD, advertising,
management and all other cost should be included
excluded are only capital costs atributable to
Investment in land, plant or equipment, property
taxes and depreciation on land. - When there is excess capacity due to a drop in
demand, below full cost pricing is to be allowed - Intention to exclude is also important
913.3.3. Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
- A full treatment is very difficult and there is a
strong suspicion that these claims are used to
support competitors more than competition - Several things are required an assessment of the
costs and financial resources of the incumbent,
of entry barriers (tangible and intangible), the
viability of the entrant, the actual conduct of
the incumbent. In particular if there are no
barriers to entry, a predatory pricing strategy
is not credible - Recent antitrust experience shows that actual
cases are relatively rare, or at least are
difficult to prove. (In the EU there have only
been a small of Commission decisions on Article
82
923.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- The Commission issued in December 2005 a
discussion paper setting out a framework for the
analysis of exclusionary abuses under Article 82
and inviting comments by 31 March 2006. - Depending upon the results of the public
consultation, guidelines may eventually emerge . - The main objective is to give an economic content
to the discussion of exclusionary abuses,
recognizing that Application of Article 82 in a
form-based way may lead to the prohibition of
behavior undertaken by dominant firms that may be
pro-competitive for example, it may lead to
lower prices or increase inter-brand competition.
933.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- The Commission is giving priority to exclusionary
abuses, as this type of abuse is seen as
particularly harmful to competition. It intends
to review its approach to exploitative abuses,
such as excessive pricing - sets out a general framework for analysis of
exclusionary abuses. This analysis is then
applied to four of the most common types of
abuse - 1) predatory pricing
- 2) single branding and rebates
- 3) tying and bundling and
- 4) refusal to supply.
943.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- The Commissions approach is based on the
following benchmarks - Pricing below average avoidable costs (AAC)
will lead to a presumption of an abuse and the
Commission will not need to further justify its
finding of abuse. The dominant firm may present
arguments to rebut this presumption, based on
lack of foreclosure effect, lack of predatory
intent and inability to recoup losses. Note
however, that, in most cases, the AAC will
coincide with the AVC.
953.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
PgtATC no PltAAC Yes Or PltLRAIC yes (to be
used instead of AAC, in sectors with high fixed
costs ATCgtPgtLRAIC ?? losses are recovered, entry
barriers...
MC
ATC
LRAIC
AAC
AVC
963.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- Pricing above AAC, but below average total costs
(ATC) Such behavior will be an abuse where
there is evidence that the pricing is part of a
strategy to eliminate competition. Both direct
and indirect evidence will be taken into account
to evaluate the likelihood of a foreclosure
effect in view of the scale, duration and
continuity of the low prices. - The Commissions position is that it is not
necessary to show evidence of actual recovery of
losses incurred by the dominant firm. Barriers to
entry will normally be sufficiently high to
presume the ability to recoup.
973.3.3. The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- Pricing below long-run average incremental costs
(LAIC) LAIC (which will be higher than AAC or
AVC) may be used as a benchmark instead of AAC in
certain sectors or markets that have recently
been liberalized, where fixed costs tend to be
high and variable costs tend to be low. - Pricing above ATC This is not generally
considered to be an abuse because a dominant firm
that prices above its ATC should only eliminate
its less efficient rivals. An abuse will only
occur in exceptional circumstances where there is
a clear exclusionary strategy (for example, by
several collectively dominant firms).
983.3.3.The EC analysis of predatory pricing
- Single branding
- a dominant firm which uses single-branding
agreements in relation to a significant part of
its customer base will have a foreclosure effect.
- The Commission will apply a more effects-based
approach to single branding, and may consider
evidence that foreclosure effects will not arise
for example, if agreements are for a short
duration or depending on the termination rights
set out in the agreement. These arguments may
have particular weight where goods are homogenous
and other competitors have spare capacity.
993.3.3.Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
- RebatesThe Commission will look at the likely
foreclosure effects of a rebate program. The key
question for the Commission is whether an as
efficient operator would be able to compete in a
market where a rebate program is in place. - The Commission distinguishes between conditional
rebates (those granted as a reward for certain
purchasing behaviour) and unconditional rebates
(which are applied regardless of the buyers
purchasing requirements). - In relation to conditional purchases, the
Commission will apply the following analysis
1003.3.3.Empirical anlysis of predatory pricing
- The Commission will calculate the effective
price of the products given the level of
discount given to a buyer. The lower the
effective price as compared with the average
price of the dominant supplier, the stronger the
loyalty-enhancing effect. - If the effective price is above AAC,