Title: On Stiffness in Affine Asset Pricing Models
1On Stiffness in Affine Asset Pricing Models
- By Shirley J. Huang and Jun Yu
- University of Auckland
- Singapore Management University
2Outline of Talk
- Motivation and literature
- Stiffness in asset pricing
- Simulation results
- Conclusions
3Motivation and Literature
- Preamble
- around 1960, things became completely
different and everyone became aware that world
was full of stiff problems Dahlquist (1985)
4Motivation and Literature
- When valuing financial assets, one often needs to
find the numerical solution to a partial
differential equation (PDE) see Duffie (2001). - In many practically relevant cases, for example,
when the number of states is modestly large,
solving the PDE is computationally demanding and
even becomes impractical.
5Motivation and Literature
- Computational burden is heavier for econometric
analysis of continuous-time asset pricing models - Reasons
- Transition density are solutions to PDEs which
have to be solved numerically at every data point
and at each iteration of the numerical
optimizations when maximizing likelihood
(Lo1988). - Asset prices themselves are numerical solutions
to PDEs.
6Motivation and Literature
- The computational burden in asset pricing and
financial econometrics has prompted financial
economists econometricians to look at the class
of affine asset pricing models where the
risk-neutral drift and volatility functions of
the process for the state variable(s) are all
affine (i.e. linear).
7Motivation and Literature
- Examples
- Closed form expression for asset prices or
transition densities - Black and Scholes (1973) for pricing equity
options - Vasicek (1977) for pricing bonds and bond options
- Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (CIR) (1985) for pricing
bonds and bond options - Heston (1993) for pricing equity and currency
options
8Motivation and Literature
- Nearly closed-form expression for asset prices
in the sense that the PDE is decomposed into a
system of ordinary differential equations (ODEs).
Such a decomposition greatly facilitates
numerical implementation of pricing (Piazzesi,
2005). - Duffie and Kan (1996) for pricing bonds
- Chacko and Das (2002) for pricing interest
derivatives - Bakshi and Madan (2000) for pricing equity
options - Bates (1996) for pricing currency options
- Duffie, Pan and Singleton (2000) for a general
treatment
9Motivation and Literature
- If the transition density (TD) has a closed form
expression, maximum likelihood (ML) is ready to
used. - For most affine models, TD has to be obtained via
PDEs. - Duffie, Pan and Singleton (2000) showed that the
conditional characteristic function (CF) have
nearly closed-form expressions for affine models
in the sense that only a system of ODEs has to be
solved - Singleton (2001) proposed CF-based estimation
methods. - Knight and Yu (2002) derived asymptotic
properties for the estimators. Yu (2004) linked
the CF methods to GMM.
10Motivation and Literature
- AD Asset Price, TD Transition density, CF
Charateristic function
Affine Asset Pricing Models
AP is Obtained via ODE TD is Obtained via PDE CF
is Obtained via ODE
Closed Form AP Closed Form TD
Closed Form AP TD is Obtained via PDE CF is
Obtained via ODE
11Motivation and Literature
- The ODEs found in the literature are always the
Ricatti equations. It is generally believed by
many researchers that these ODEs can be solved
fast and numerically efficiently using
traditional numerical solvers for initial
problems, such as explicit Runge-Kutta methods.
Specifically, Piazzesi (2005) recommended the
MATLAB command ode45.
12Motivation and Literature
- Ode45 has high order of accuracy
- It has a finite region of absolute stability
(Huang (2005) and Butcher (2003)). - The stability properties of numerical methods are
important for getting a good approximation to the
true solution. - At each mesh point there are differences between
the exact solution and the numerical solution
known as error. - Sometimes the accumulation of the error will
cause instability and the numerical solution will
no longer follow the path of the true solution. - Therefore, a method must satisfy the stability
condition so that the numerical solution will
converge to the exact solution.
13Motivation and Literature
- Under many situations that are empirically
relevant in finance the ODEs involve stiffness, a
phenomenon which leads to certain practical
difficulties for numerical methods with a finite
region of absolute stability. - If an explicit method is used to solve a stiff
problem, a small stepsize has to be chosen to
ensure stability and hence the algorithm becomes
numerically inefficient.
14Motivation and Literature
- To illustrate stiff problems, consider
- with initial conditions
15Motivation and Literature
- This linear system has the following exact
solution - The second term decays very fast while the first
term decays very slowly. -
16Motivation and Literature
- This feature can be captured by the Jacobian
matrix - It has two very distinct eigenvalues, -1 and
-1000. The ratio of them is called the stiffness
ratio, often used to measure the degree of
stiffness.
17Motivation and Literature
- The system can be rotated into a system of two
independent differential equations - If we use the explicit Euler method to solve the
ODE, we have
18Motivation and Literature
- This requires 0lthlt0.002 for a real h (step size)
to fulfill the stability requirement. That is,
the explicit Euler method has a finite region of
absolute stability (the stability region is given
by 1zlt1). For this reason, the explicit Euler
method is not A-Stable.
19Motivation and Literature
- For the general system of ODE
- Let be the Jacobian matrix. Suppose
eigenvalues of J are - If
we say the ODE is stiff. R is the stiffness
ratio.
20Motivation and Literature
- The explicit Euler method is of order 1. Higher
order explicit methods, such as explicit
Runge-Kutta methods, will not be helpful for
stiff problems. The stability regions for
explicit Runge-Kutta methods are as follows -
21Motivation and Literature
22Motivation and Literature
- To solve the stiff problem, we have to use a
method which is A-Stable, that is, the stability
region is the whole of the left half-plane. - Dalhquist (1963) shows that explicit Runge-Kutta
methods cannot be A-stable. - Implicit methods can be A-stable and hence should
be used for stiff problems.
23Motivation and Literature
- To see why implicit methods are A-stable,
consider the implicit Euler method for the
following problem - The implicit Euler method implies that
24Motivation and Literature
- So the stability region is
-
25Motivation and Literature
- Higher order implicit methods include implicit
Runge-Kutta methods, linear multi-step methods,
and general linear methods. See Huang (2005).
26Stiffness in Asset Pricing
- The multi-factor affine term structure model
adopts the following specifications - Under risk-neutrality, the state variables
follows - The short rate is affine function of Y(t)
- The market price of risk with factor j is
-
27Stiffness in Asset Pricing
- Hence the physical measure is also affine
-
- Duffie and Kan (1996) derived the expression for
the yield-to-maturity at time t of a zero-coupon
bond that matures at in the Ricatti form, - with initial conditions A(0)0, B(0)0.
28Stiffness in Asset Pricing
- Dai and Singleton (2001) empirically estimated
the 3-factor model in various forms using US
data. - Using one set of their estimates, we obtain
- Using another set of their estimates, we obtain
29Stiffness in Asset Pricing
- The stiffness ratios are 9355.6 and 52.76
respectively. Hence the stiff is severe and
moderate. - However, in the literature, people always use the
explicit Runge-Kutta method to solve the Ricatti
equation.
30Stiffness in Parameter Estimation
- Based on the assumption that the state variable
Y(t) follow the following affine diffusion under
the physical measure - Duffie, Pan and Singleton (2000) derived the
conditional CF of Y(t1) on Y(t) - where
31Stiffness in Parameter Estimation
- Stiffness ratios implied by the existing studies
- Geyer and Pichler (1999) 2847.2.
- Chen and Scott (1991, 1992) 351.9.
- Dai and Singleton (2001) ranging from 28.9 to
78.9.
32Comparison of Nonstiff and Stiff Solvers
- Compare two explicit Runge-Kutta methods (ode45,
ode23), an implicit Runge-Kutta method (ode23s),
and an implicit linear multistep method (ode15s). - Two experiments
- Pricing bonds under the two-factor square root
model - Estimating parameters in the two-factor square
root model using CF
33Comparison of Nonstiff and Stiff Solvers
- The true model
- The parameters for market prices of risk are
- Hence
- The stiffness ratios are 3333.3 and 1200
respectively.
34Simulation Results
- Bond prices with 5, 10, 20, 40-year maturity
35Simulation Results
36Simulation Results
- Parameter estimation 100 bivariate samples, each
with 300 observations on 6-month zero coupon bond
and 300 observations on 10-year zero coupon bond,
are simulated and fitted using the CF method.
37Simulation Results
38Simulation Results
39Conclusions
- Stiffness in ODEs widely exists in affine asset
pricing models. - Stiffness in ODEs also exists in non-affine asset
pricing models. Examples include the quadratic
asset pricing model (Ahn et al 2002). - Stiff problems are more efficient solved with
implicit methods. - The computational gain is particularly
substantial for econometric analysis.