Demand for insurance - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 28
About This Presentation
Title:

Demand for insurance

Description:

Expected utility theory is the hard core of conventional theory of ... (x) is unique up to a positive affine transformation, i.e. the functions u(x) and ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:28
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 29
Provided by: srh9
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Demand for insurance


1
Demand for insurance
  • Lecture 1 - Economics of insurance
  • EOCN6053 Selected topic in financial economics
  • Raymond Yeung, PhD
  • Honorary Assistant Professor
  • 1 February 2007

2
Major learning point
  • Expected utility theory is the hard core of
    conventional theory of insurance economics
  • Based on EU theory, Mossins model (1968) implies
    that people buy full coverage only if premium
    equates its average loss (actuarial value)
  • The theory contradicts our observation that
    insurance companies impose a loading and yet
    people do demand for full insurance
  • Arrow (1971,1974) generalized the premium formula
    that includes a loading factor proportional to
    expected claims
  • Based on Arrows model, subsequent research
    studies the features of insurance demand e.g.
    changes initial wealth, risk aversion, accident
    probabilities etc.

3
1. Historical development of the theories
  • Insurance is a product in response to the
    presence of uncertainty
  • People demand for a contract involving prepaid
    elements ahead of the occurance of an event(s)
  • P the premium paid b the insured when the
    contract is concluded
  • x the compensation which the insured receives
    if specific events occur when the contract is in
    force
  • where F(x) is a probability distribution of the
    random variable x
  • If F(x) is unknown or does not exist, the
    insurance product cannot be priced

4
1. Historical development of the theories
  • Adam Smiths Wealth of Nation premium must be
    sufficient to compensate the common losses, to
    pay the expense of management, and to afford such
    a profit as might have been drawn from an equal
    capital employed in any common trade
  • Austrian School Eugen Bohm-Bawerk in 1881 shows
    that values, or certainty equivalents could be
    computed for contingent claims
  • Walras (1874) saw insurance a device to remove
    uncertainty inherent in all other economic
    activities, that can be interpreted as cost of
    capital in business economics
  • Marshall (1890) reckoned businessmen are willing
    to pay a value above the actuarial value of risk,
    pointing to the presence of risk aversion

5
2. Preference ordering of risk
  • An uncertain loss may be characterized as risk
    which can be described by a probability
    distribution
  • If a person covers a part of the whole of the
    risk by insurance priced at P, the actual
    distribution of x can be altered from F1 to F2
  • People can rank their preference of F1 to F2

6
2. Preference ordering of risk
  • For any distributions such that
    , and any scalar it follows
    that
  • With the assumptions of consistency, completeness
    of and continuity of preference ordering
  • (1) There exists a function u(x) such that
    implies
  • (2) The function u(x) is unique up to a positive
    affine transformation, i.e. the functions u(x)
    and
  • where Agt0 represent the same preference ordering

7
2. Demand for insurance
  • Consider a person with initial wealth W. Assume
    he is exposed to a risk of loss x with density
    f(x). He is willing to pay a premium P only if
  • There is clearly an upper limit to the premium,
    say so that the equality sign will hold
  • Recall Jensens inequality. If u(x) is concave,
    it follows that
  • For some , the buyer is willing to
    pay more than E(x) for insurance

8
1. Bernoulli principle
  • The fair value of a gamble was the mathematical
    expectation of the gain
  • St. Peterburg Paradox is an counter example by
    Bernoulli (1738) if the first head appears at
    the nth toss, a prize of 2n is paid

9
1. Bernoulli principle
  • Bernoulli argued there is a moral value to x, or
    ln(x)
  • In fact, any concave function u(x) will do. From
    Jensens inequality, it follows that a person
    will pay less than the mathematical expectation
    for the right to play a gamble
  • Bernoulli hypothesis was proved as a theorem only
    until 1947 by von Neumann and Morgenstern, and
    Arrows optimal allocation of risk bearing in 1953

10
2. Demand for insurance
  • The supply side consider now an insurer with
    utility u1(x) and initial wealth W1.
  • He is willing to assume a contract to cover the
    risk against a premium P only if
  • An insurance contract exists only if there are
    values P which are consistent with the conditions
    above

11
2. Mossin theory of partial cover
  • Assume a person can pay a premium qP and receive
    a compensation of qx. This is a fixed
    proportional contract without any loading.
  • The expected utility to the person is
  • The decision problem is to find the value of q
    which maximizes his expected utility. The FOC is

12
2. Mossin theory of partial cover
  • For full insuance (q1),
  • If E(x) lt P, U(1) is negative, violating the
    FOC. It appears full insurance is only observed
    if premium is set at actuarially fair rate.
  • The SOC is always satisfied (even when q1), as

13
2. Mossin theory of partial cover (cont)
  • But this result contradicts our observations.
    When a person insures his house, the sum insured
    is usually full rather than partial value of the
    property.
  • To explain this deviation, one may question
    whether expected utility theory is applicable to
    insurance analysis, or the assumption of concave
    u(.). However, we do observe the norm of risk
    aversion.
  • A simple way out is to add a loading factor in
    formulating the insurance contract P qE(x)
    c
  • Please work it out the FOC in the case with
    loading and its implications.

14
2. Mossin theory example
  • Assume an individual has initial wealth W0 and
    will suffer a loss L with probability p. She
    faces a prospect
  • An insurance is available with premium P pC,
    where p is premium rate and C is the level of
    coverage.
  • With insurance, the prospect becomes

15
2. Mossin theory example
  • In the case of full insurance, L C
  • The consumer will buy insurance if and only if a
    C exists such that the expected utility of being
    insured is higher than the expected utility of
    being uninsured

16
2. Mossin theory example
  • This problem is solved by
  • The FOC is that the probability-weighted marginal
    utility is equal for both states of the world

17
2. Mossin theory example
  • Suppose Bernoulli Principle holds premium rate
    is set at its actuarially fair level. It is
    easily to show that p p
  • The FOC becomes
  • The only condition that allows this to happen is
    CL, full coverage.

18
2. Demand function
  • Forget about our assumption on p at this moment.
    Assume log utility function, u(.) ln x. The FOC
    becomes
  • Let assume L 1 for simplicity. Solving this
    equation for C, the amount of coverage

19
2. Demand function
  • Effect of changes in initial wealth
  • If insurance is actuarially fair, changes initial
    wealth do not affect insurance demand. If there
    is a loading, the relationship is negative
    wealthier demand for less coverage

20
2. Demand function
  • Effect of changes in risk probability
  • The numerator is negative as WgtL. The denominator
    is negative. It means there is a positive
    relationship between risk factor and demand for
    coverage

21
2. Demand function
  • Effect of changes in loss severity
  • There is positive relationship between C and L

22
2. Demand function
  • What about price elasticity
  • If the numerator is positive, insurance would be
    a Giffen goods, depending on the relative
    strength of income and substitution effect

23
2. Arrows model Choice of contracts
  • The other way is to generalize the contract form
    into a contingent benefit function y(x) when
    event x occurs.
  • Premium P in turn depends on how claims are paid,
    i.e. P(y)
  • The buyers problem is then
  • Arrow (1963,1974) makes use of this format in
    analyzing insurance with loading and deductible

24
2. Arrows model Choice of contracts
  • Arrow (1963) assumes that
  • The solution is an insurance contract with
    deductible

25
2. Arrows model Choice of contracts
  • Assume the choices are P(D) with different D
  • The FOC is
  • Expected claim payment under this contract is

26
2. Arrows model Choice of contracts
  • If P is set in Mossin fashion with expense c,
  • The FOC is satisfied if D 0
  • The model above implies the optimal choice is
    either full cover, or no cover at all, depending
    on the size of c
  • How premiums are formulated affect the model
    solution but the presence of c seems critical to
    the existence of a solution

27
2. Arrows model Choice of contracts
  • With deductible D, the net premium is
  • The minimum premium which the company can quote
    to customers will then be
  • Hence the loading will be increasing with D

28
Class exercise
  • Suppose W0100, L50, p0.5, p0.5
  • Assume log utility functions, substitute the
    parameters to the FOC
  • Derive the demand for coverage
  • Work out the case of increasing loading to 0.6
  • Suppose an increase in wealth to 120 and p 0.6.
    What is C?
  • If L increases to 60, what is C?
  • Finally, suppose p0.6. What is C?
  • Discuss this case in relation to PC insurance
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com