Topic 10: BlackScholes

1 / 60
About This Presentation
Title:

Topic 10: BlackScholes

Description:

Our first concern is to develop a statistical model of how stock prices behave over time. ... The Roll, Geske, and Whaley model is more precise, but also ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:31
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 61
Provided by: belkcoll

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Topic 10: BlackScholes


1
Topic 10Black-Scholes
2
Introduction
  • In this lecture (or series of lectures) we will
    lay the basic foundation that you need to begin
    working with the standard continuous-time option
    pricing model, the Black-Scholes model.
  • This is really just an introduction to the
    mathematics of continuous-time finance, obviously
    in the Math 6202, 6203, and 6204 you will study
    this material in much greater detail.
  • This lecture begins with a quick tour through
    Hulls Chapter 11, and then moves into the
    Black-Scholes analysis itself, which comes from
    Hull Ch. 12.

3
Introduction
  • Our first concern is to develop a statistical
    model of how stock prices behave over time.
  • The term stochastic process simply means that the
    variable defined by it is random. 
  • Stochastic processes can be classified in several
    ways.
  • By time interval
  • continuous time changes can occur at any point
    in time ex. temperature
  • discrete time changes can only occur at specific
    points in time.
  • By change increment
  • Continuous variable can take on any value in
    range.
  • Discrete variable can take on only specific
    values.
  • Stocks are generally assumed to follow a
    continuous time, continuous variable stochastic
    process.

4
The Markov Property of Stocks
  • A Markov property is a particular type of
    stochastic process where only the present value
    of a variable is relevant for predicting the
    future. The past history of the variable and how
    it got to that point are irrelevant.
  • There is overwhelming evidence that stock prices
    are Markov. If they were not, then chartists
    could make money above and beyond the risk
    adjusted rate of return. They cannot, and if fact
    we kind of define the markets as being weak-form
    efficient this says the stock prices fully
    incorporate all public information. This is
    caused by competition.

5
Wiener Processes
  • A Wiener process is a particularly useful type of
    Markov process it has a mean change of zero and
    variance
  • The general format of a Wiener process is very
    adaptable. In fact it is its flexibility that
    makes it such a good candidate for describing
    many different phenomena, including stock prices.
  • Lets begin by defining a variable, z, which
    follows a Weiner process. Define ?t as a small
    length of time (nearly instantaneous) and define
    ?z as the change in z during time ?t.

6
Wiener Processes
  • A Wiener process, it will have these properties
  • Property 1 ?z is related to ?t by the equation
  • where e is a random draw from a standard normal
    distribution (i.e. eN(1,0)).
  • Property 2 The values of ?z for any two
    different short intervals are independent.
  • It follows from property 1 that ?z itself is
    distributed normally with mean 0 and variance ?t.
    Its standard deviation is (?t).5

7
Weiner Processes
  • What are the statistical properties of z during a
    non-short interval of time, T?
  • Denote this as z(T)-z(0). It is simply the sum
    of N small time intervals of length ?t, where N
    T/?t.
  • Thus,
  • Thus, since the mean of a sum of random variables
    is simply the sum of the means,
  • mean of z(T) - z(0) 0
  • Further, since the draws from e are independent,
    the variance of the sum of those draws are
    additive (another way of saying this is that they
    are uncorrelated).

8
Weiner Processes
  • Thus, s2 N?t T and hence s T.5.
  • So far we have dealt with a discrete time case.
    We are interested in a continuous time case.
    Basically nothing changes except we use
    continuous time notation

9
Generalized Wiener Process
  • So far we have dealt only with a simple Wiener
    process. It has a drift rate of 0 and a variance
    rate of 1.0. We can add non zero drift rates and
    non-unitary variance rates.
  • To get to such a process we build off of the
    basic Weiner process we already have
  • dx a dt b dz
  • where a and b are constants, and dz is our
    previously defined Weiner process.
  • To see this, consider the two components of this
    equation separately. Note that the first portion
    (a dt) is not random. It merely says that dx is
    generally drifting upward at some constant rate.

10
Generalized Wiener Process
  • Another way of looking at this is to ask the
    question, what if I divide through by dt? 
  • dx/dt a.
  • The second term, however, does contain a random
    component. What we have is the white noise
    process (dz) multiplied by some non-random
    constant.
  • Recall that the mean of the product of a random
    variable times a constant is the product of the
    mean of that random variable times the constant
    amount.
  • In this case, i.e. for
  • b dz
  • since dzN(0,1), the mean of this term is zero.
  • Thus the drift of the entire process, is simply
    (adt).

11
Generalized Wiener Process
  • Similarly, the variance of the product of a
    random variable times a constant is the variance
    of the random variable times the square of the
    constant.
  • So adding this all together we get dx N(a dt,
    b2 dt)
  • and hence the st. deviation of dx is given by b
    (dt).5.
  • Similarly over a non-small length of time T
  • Mean of change in x aT
  • variance of change in x is b2T
  • standard deviation of change in x is b T.5
  • If a and b are allowed to be functions of both x
    and t, then we have the most general Markov,
    stochastic process, the Ito process
  • dx - a(x,t) dt b(x,t) dz

12
The Process for Stock Prices
  • It is at first tempting to say that stocks follow
    a generalized Weiner process, that is, they have
    a constant drift and variance rate. However,
    this would not take into account that investors
    demand a rate of return that is independent of a
    stocks price.
  • That is, investors want a return based on the
    risk of a stock, regardless if it is worth 10 or
    100.
  • Because of this we cannot use the constant
    expected-drift rate, but rather have to have a
    constant proportional drift rate. This means
    that if S is the stock price, investors want a
    constant proportional return µS where µ is a
    constant.

13
The Process for Stock Prices
  • If a stock had a zero variance, this would imply
  • ds µS dt,
  • or, in another, more convenient, format
  • dS/S µ dt.
  • Thus,
  • ST S0 e µt.
  • Of course, stocks do exhibit volatility. A
    reasonable assumption (based on empirical
    observation) is that the variance is roughly
    constant over any relatively short time period.
    Define s2 as the variance rate of the
    proportional change in the stock price.
  • This means that s2 ?t is the variance of the
    proportional change in the stock price over time
    ?t while the variance of the actual change is s2
    S2 ?t. Thus the instantaneous variance rate of S
    is therefore s2 S2 (i.e. as ?t -gt 0).

14
The Process for Stock Prices
  • This leads us to represent S by an Ito process of
    the form
  • dS µS dt s S dz
  • or, in the more generally seen form
  • dS/S µ dt s dz
  • Generally µ is referred to as the stocks
    expected return, and s as its volatility.
  • It is really easy to build a simulation of this
    process.
  • Lets assume that the at stock priced at 50 had
    an expected return ( µ) of 10 and that the
    volatility of that stock (i.e. standard deviation
    of the return, i.e. s) was 20. Let us divided
    the year into increments of 1 week (i.e. dt1/52)
    and chart the movements over 3 years

15
The Process for Stocks
16
The Parameters
  • Now notice that we have defined a process for
    stock prices that only involve two parameters µ
    and s2. Those parameters are usually expressed
    in time units of one year.
  • What are the properties of those parameters?
  • µ Generally, investors demand a higher value of
    µ for riskier stocks. Historically, the
    average stocks µ has been 8 percentage points
    higher than the risk-free rate of return.
    Fortunately, we dont have to worry too much
    about this parameter, since the expected rate of
    return does not matter for pricing derivatives.
    (Recall that we can price based on arbitrage
    arguments.)
  • s This is an important parameter, and we will
    discuss how to estimate it from historical data
    later. It is important to note that s(T).5 will
    be approximately (but not exactly) the standard
    deviation of stock returns during the period T.

17
Itos Lemma
  • In the early 1950's Ito developed a method for
    describing how functions based on random
    variables evolve.
  • Assume that G is a function of time, t, and a
    random variable x, i.e. G(x,t). Let x be a
    general Ito process
  • dx a(x,t)dt b(x,t) dz
  • then Itos lemma states that
  • where dz is the typical Wiener process.

18
Itos Lemma
  • Thus G itself follows an Ito process with drift
    of
  • and variance rate of
  • Now, applying this to stocks, if a stock follows
    a proportional Ito process
  • dS µS dt s S dz 

19
Itos Lemma
  • with constant µ and s, a function G of S (such
    as a derivative) will follow
  • This is the key to pricing all derivatives.
    Notice that both S and G have one common (and
    sole) source of uncertainty dz. This is what
    allows us to price G in terms of S!

20
Application to a Forward Contract
  • To see how this works, lets look at a forward
    contract. From earlier in the book we defined a
    forward price F to be F Ser(T-t).
  • So we can define F as a function of S and t
    F(S,t), and then taking some standard
    derivatives

21
Application to a Forward Contract
  • Appling Itos lemma, F should evolve as dF,
  • which in this case will be
  • Since by definition F Ser(T-t), dF becomes
  • Note that this is basis for the notion that the
    growth rate in a stock index futures price is the
    excess return over the risk free rate.

22
Application to the Logarithm of a Stock Price
  • Now it turns out that in many cases we will want
    to work with the log of stock price, not with the
    stock price itself.
  • What process does ln S follow?
  • Again, define a function G(S,t) ln S.
  • Taking normal derivatives 
  • Substituting into equation Itos lemma
  •  

23
Application to the Logarithm of a Stock Price
  • So it has mean (over interval t,T)
  • (µ - s2/2)(T-t) 
  • and variance
  • s2(T-t)
  • Thus the change in the stock price is given by
  • ln ST - ln S0
  • and this is distributed
  • ln ST - ln S0 N(µ - s2/2)(T-t), s(T-t).5
  • or written slightly differently
  •   ln ST Nln S0(µ - s2/2)(T-t), s(T-t).5
  • The net effect is to show that ln ST is normally
    distributed. This means that a stocks price at
    time T, given its price today, is lognormally
    distributed, with standard deviation of s(T).5

24
The Lognormal Property of Stock Prices
  • What is neat (and convenient) is that our best
    evidence is that the lognormally distribution
    does a pretty decent job modeling real stock
    prices.
  • Indeed, Hull has a nice quote our uncertainty
    about the logarithm of the stock price, as
    measured by its standard deviation, is
    proportional to the square root of how far ahead
    we are looking.

25
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
  • If the previous section tells us about the
    properties of the stock price, we are also
    concerned with the statistical properties of the
    rate of return on the stock.
  • That is, if previously we were concerned with the
    way the price of the stock changed over time,
    here we are concerned with the way the rate of
    return of the stock changes over time.
  • Define ? as the annual continuously compounded
    rate of return realized between t and T.
  • By definition ST Se?(T-t) And ? 1/(T-t) ln
    (ST/S)
  • and since
  • ln(ST/S) f((µ-
    s2/2)(T-t),s(T-t).5)
  • this implies
  • ?f((µ- s2/2),s/(T-t).5).

26
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
  • Indeed, the last slide shows that our model
    assumes that stock returns are normally
    distributed.
  • It might be nice to have some validation that
    this is indeed what we see in the real world.
  • Short answer For most options pricing, it
    appears that stocks returns are normal-enough,
    although some researchers argue that real returns
    violate normality in two related ways
  • The tales of the distributions are too fat to be
    a true normal, they are closer to a logistic
    distribution.
  • There seems to be a higher probability of large
    downturns in price than upturns.

27
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
  • Let us examine the returns to two stocks to at
    least visually examine how they are distributed.
  • General Electric (GE) and the parent company of
    American Airlines (AMR).
  • Data collected from March 1994 through October
    2002.
  • First, lets look at prices over that time

28
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
29
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
  • Now, lets look at a histogram of returns for
    each of these firms.

30
The Distribution of the Rate of Return
31
Estimation of Volatility from Historical Data
  • Sometimes we want to estimate volatility from
    historical data. When we do this, we typically
    examine a series of closing prices. Lets adopt
    the following notation
  • n1 the number of observations of closing
    prices.
  • Si the stock price at the end of the ith
    interval.
  • t length of time interval in years.
  • Define µi ln (Si/Si-1) for i1,2,...,n.
  • By definition we have constructed a series of
    continuously compounded return values. The usual
    estimator that we get in stats class look like

32
Estimation of Volatility from Historical Data
  • Or
  • Of course we know from equation 11.1 that the
    standard deviation of µi is s(t.5), and so we
    must adjust our estimate of the standard
    deviation, we do this by dividing s by (t.5),
  • s s/(t.5)

33
Assumptions Behind the Black-Scholes Differential
Equation
  • Although the mathematics appear a bit more
    complex and a bit more intimidating, the basic
    idea behind the Black Scholes analysis is the
    same as in the binomial.
  • That is, if you can set up a portfolio that
    consists of the option and the stock, and that
    portfolio is perfectly risk-free, you can
    back-out the price of the option.
  • To get to this point we make a number of
    assumptions. Most of these assumption are not
    very binding.
  • The stock price follows the process developed in
    Chapter 10 with µ and s constant.
  • The short selling of securities is allowed.
  • There are not transactions costs or taxes, all
    securities are perfectly divisible.
  • There are no dividends during the life of the
    option.
  • There are not arbitrage opportunities.
  • Securities trade continuously.
  • The risk-free rate is constant.

34
Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential
Equation
  • Recall that we assume a stock price S which
    follows the process
  • dS µS dt sS dz
  • working with a discrete time version of this
  • ?S µS ?t sS ?z.
  • Let f represent the value of any derivative
    written on S. From Itos lemma, it must be the
    case that

35
Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential
Equation
  • Now clearly the only risk from this derivative
    security comes from the ?z term.
  • If I construct a portfolio consisting of -1
    shares of the derivative and (?f/?s) shares of
    the stock, will have an instantaneously riskless
    portfolio. To see this note that the value of
    the portfolio (?) is
  • and so the change in this portfolio is
  • which by substitution gives us

36
Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential
Equation
  • Notice that we have managed to remove all of the
    ?zs from the equation. As a result we know that
    it must grow at the risk-free rate. It follows,
    therefore, that
  • ?? r ? ?t
  • where r is the risk-free rate. Substituting back
    into previous equations gives
  • which leads us to the general equation

37
Derivation of the Black-Scholes Differential
Equation
  • Notice that f is ANY derivative based on S, not
    just a call or a put. In fact, to price any
    particular derivative, you must first impose upon
    this equation appropriate boundary conditions.
  • These literally specify the boundary values of S
    and t, and how the derivative behaves at those
    boundaries.
  • Fortunately, these boundary conditions are
    basically our payoff conditions
  • call option f max(S-X,0) when tT
  • put option f max(X-S,0) when tT

38
Risk-Neutral Valuation
  • Notice in the PDE that the drift rate of the
    stock does not appear. It has fallen out in all
    of the algebra.
  • Thus, how investors feel about µ are irrelevant
    when it comes to pricing the option f. We can
    choose to work in a world with any set of
    investor attitudes about µ that we want to, and
    values obtained in those worlds are valid in any
    other world.
  • This allows us to make a hugely simplifying
    assumption. Just assume that investors are
    risk-neutral. In such a world, all securities
    would grow at the risk-free rate because
    investors do not demand a premium to induce them
    to take risk.

39
Risk-Neutral Valuation
  • This provides us with a rather simple way of
    valuing a derivative in this world simply assume
    that the stock will grow at the risk free rate r
    until time T.
  • At that point see what would be the payoffs to
    the derivatives, and then discount those payoffs
    at the risk-free rate back to today. This is the
    value of the derivative in both the risk-neutral
    and risk-averse world.

40
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Lets start with the call option. As you know,
    the value of a call option at maturity in a
    risk-neutral world is Emax(ST-X,0)
  • where E represents the risk-neutral world. This
    means that the value of this option at time (T-t)
    is simply that payoff discounted back to time
    (T-t) at the risk free rate (just like any other
    discounted cash flow)
  • c e-r(T-t)Emax(ST-X,0)
  • So now, all we have to deal with is determining
    this expected value.

41
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • As we showed earlier, the rate of return on S in
    a risk-neutral world is r, not µ, therefore the
    distribution of ST is given by
  • we will avoid what Hull describes as tedious
    algebra and cut to the equation 
  • c SN(d1) - Xe-r(T-t)N(d2)
  • where

42
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • And
  • N(x) is the cumulative probability distribution
    function for a variable that is normally
    distributed with mean zero and a standard
    deviation of 1.
  • Note that we can re-write this equation as
  • c e-r(T-t)Ser(T-t) N(d1) - XN(d2).
  • Expressed this way you can see what this is
    really getting at, lets break it down

43
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • First, notice that Ser(T-t) is the expected value
    of ST in a risk-neutral world. Thus you can think
    of the term Ser(T-t)N(d1) as the expected payoff
    to a security which is worth ST is STgtX and zero
    otherwise.
  • So this is the first half of your option how
    much the asset on which you hold the option is
    worth at the end, and XN(d2) is the expected
    amount you have to pay for it times the
    probability of your making that payout.
  • So essentially this has two parts the value of
    the asset after the payment, and the cost of
    exercising the option. the e-r(T-t) is simply
    discounting it back to todays price.
  • Note I will provide you with tables for N(x) on
    the exam.
  • You can get a similar result for puts, but it is
    somewhat easier to use put-call parity
  • p Xe-r(T-t)N(-d2) - SN(-d1).

44
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Lets work an example. Lets say that you hold a
    European option with these parameters
  • S 42, K 40, r .10, s.2, and T-t.5.
  • What is the value of that option today?
  • First, lets calculate d1 and d2

45
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Obviously the next step is to calculate N(d1) and
    N(d2), and there are several ways you could do
    this
  • In Excel, use the function normsdist(),
  • Use a polynomial approximation, or
  • Use a table of normal values.
  • Lets look at each of these
  • In Excel simply enter
  • normsdist(0.7693) 0.7791normsdist(0.6278)
    0.7349
  • Hull presents a polynomial approximation on page
    248 of his book. This approximation is as
    follows

46
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Hulls approximation
  • For d1 0.7693, the approximate value for
    N(0.7693) works out to be 0.779142, and for
    d20.6278 the approximate value for N(0.6278)
    works out to be 0.734933.

47
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • If you look in the back of Hulls book you can
    see an example of a standard normal table similar
    to the one I have created here
  • To use it find the row/column combination that
    most closely equals your value of (x), and then
    interpolate between that value and the next
    closest one.

48
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • All three method give you approximately the same
    answer for N(d1) and N(d2)
  • The next step is to calculate Ke-r(T-t).
  • Ke-r(T-t) 40 e-.1(.5) 38.049.
  • If this is a call option that you hold, its value
    is given by
  • And if it is a put, its value is given by

49
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Notice that if you wanted to solve for the put
    value, you could have used put-call parity as
    well
  • p c Ke-r(T-t) S0
  • or
  • p 4.76 40e-.10(.5)- 42
  • p 4.76 38.049 42 0.81

50
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • McDonald presents the basic Black-Scholes
    equations in a slightly different format
  • In this case the parameter d is a continuous
    dividend yield. This is just a minor modification
    to Hulls Black-Scholes model. Note that this is
    in keeping with the idea of setting the total
    return to the risk-free rate as we have done in
    previous settings.

51
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • For a put the equations change to
  • Where again d is the continuous dividend yield.

52
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Clearly the two previous equations would be
    practical for use with stock index, but would
    not be particularly useful for most stocks that
    pay discrete dividends.
  • We can incorporate discrete dividends into the
    Black-Scholes equation in much the same way that
    we did for the binomial model remove the present
    value of the future dividends from the time 0
    stock price and then model that as the current
    stock price. (This obviously only applies to
    European options)
  • Technically we would have to estimate the
    volatility of the risky portion of the stock
    price, but this is not really an issue provided
    we are using implied volatilities they would be
    based upon this value.

53
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Example Suppose that you have a call option on a
    stock that will pay a 3 dividend in 1 month.
    This stock is currently priced at 41, and has a
    volatility of 30. The risk free rate is 8, and
    the option will expire in 3 months. The strike
    price is 40.
  • Begin by determining the present value of the
    dividend
  • I 3e-.08(.25) 2.98
  • Reset the stock price (S0) to (41-2.98)
    38.02, and then plug it into the Black-Scholes,
    first calculate d1 and d2

54
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Next, calculate N(d1) and N(d2)
  • N(-0.13011) 0.4482
  • N(-0.28011) 0.3897
  • Then determine Ke-rT
  • 40e-.08(.25)39.21
  • Finally, calculate the call value
  • c S0N(d1) Ke-rTN(d2)
  • c 38.02(0.4482) 39.21(0.3897)
  • c 1.76

55
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • But what about American options?
  • We know that in the presence of dividends it is
    sometimes optimal to exercise an American call
    option early. It was relatively easy to handle
    this within the binomial model, but how do we
    handle this within the Black-Scholes model?
  • Fortunately, Hull demonstrates that normally it
    is the case that only the final dividend date
    matters for the purposes of pricing (this may be
    violated if, for example there were an
    extraordinarily large early dividend followed by
    one or more much smaller dividends.) Thus, we can
    behave, in most cases, as if there were only one
    dividend, even when there are many.
  • Generally there are a couple of methods that are
    commonly used. The first is an approximation
    proposed by Black, and the second is an exact
    pricing formula known as the Roll, Geske, and
    Whaley model. We will briefly examine each of
    these.
  • The Black approximation is widely used in
    practice, and has the benefit of being extremely
    easy to implement.

56
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • The Black approximation is widely used in
    practice, and has the benefit of being extremely
    easy to implement.
  • Assume that a stock will pay a dividend at time
    tn, and that tngtT.
  • Price two calls using the Black-Scholes formula
    one with a maturity date of tn and one with T.
    Then assume that the American options value is
    the greater of the two. (Adjusting S0 for the
    intermediate dividends.)
  • The Roll, Geske, and Whaley model is more
    precise, but also significantly more complex to
    implement.

57
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • The RGW model is given by
  • Note that M(a,b?) is the cumulative probability
    in a standardized bivariate normal distribution
    that the first variable is less than a and the
    second variable is less than b, and the
    correlation coefficient between the two is ?.
    Also,

58
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • S is defined to be that value of the initial
    stock price that sets the option value exactly
    equal to the initial stock price plus the
    dividend less the strike price
  • c(S) S-D1-K
  • Technically the RGW model allows for only one
    dividend, although in most cases you can treat
    the last dividend as being the only dividend
    (adjusting S0 by the present value of all but the
    last dividend amount, of course) and then solving
    using this procedure.

59
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Finally, what about options on futures contracts?
  • The model for pricing futures options is normally
    referred to as Blacks model.
  • McDonald does a nice job presenting this from the
    standpoint of prepaid futures contracts. Recall
    that the time 0 value of a prepaid futures
    contract in a risk-neutral world is just the
    present value of the futures price Fe-rT.
  • The formula is given by

60
The Black-Scholes Pricing Formulas
  • Consider a European put futures option on crude
    oil, with the options maturity date in four
    months. The current futures price is 20, the
    exercise price is 20, the risk free rate is 9,
    and the volatility of the futures price is 25.
  • F020, K20, r0.09, T4/12, s.25.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)