Title: Biotechnology, Patents and Liability
1Biotechnology, Patents and Liability
- Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss
- Pauline Newman Professor of Law
- New York University School of Law
2Tomorrow Joint Inventorship and Authorship
- Real issue for both sessions
- Does the Intellectual Property Law of the
Industrial Age Meet the Needs of the Information
Age?
3Overview
- Theory of innovation
- Basics of patent protection
- Assumptions underlying the legal regime
- Characteristics of modern science
- Disparities as drags on intellectual production
- Proposals for change
4Theory of innovation Patterns of technological
advance
Vannevar Bush, Director of the Office of
Scientific Research and Development (1944) Linear
progression basic science applied
science technological development end products
5Economics (economists) of advancement
Zvi Griliches
F.M. Scherer
Fritz Machlup
6Economics
- Basic science conception
- - Mertonian ethos
- - nonmarket rewards professorships, Nobel
Prize - - spillover benefits
- RemainderR D, commercialization and
distribution - - need for market incentive for each end
product - - problem of free ride and appropriability
- - how much?
- - the innovation lottery
- - dry holes
- - balancing user and producer needs
-
-
7Basics of (US) patent protection
- Subject matter drawing the
- Utility patentability line
- Novelty and nonobviousness
- Disclosure
- Scope
- Defenses
- Immunities
8Subject matter
- OReilly v. Morse, 56 U.S. (15 How.) 62 (1853)
abstract principles (motive power of electric
current) not patentable - Funk Bros. Seed Co. v. Kalo Inoculant Co., 333
U.S. 127 (1948) products of nature (packets of
nitrogen-fixing bacteria) not patentable - basic science excluded
9Utility
- Brenner v. Manson, 383 U.S. 519 (1966) only
end-use utilities are patentable - (process for synthesizing a steroid of no known
use) - A patent is not a hunting license. It is not
a reward for the search, but compensation for its
successful conclusion. - research vs. end use
10Pyramid of Knowledge
where is the patentability line?
11Novelty and inventiveness
- Graham v. John Deere Co., 383 U.S. 1 (1966)
(flexible plow, sealed sprayer) - contents of prior art
- gap between this invention and prior art
- skill of person of ordinary skill in the art
(POSITA) - would the POSITA have bridged the gap?
- linear progression
12Disclosure
- (1) enablement does it teach POSITA?
- (2) written description possession
- (3) best mode
- (4) distinct claiming metes and bounds
- protect spillovers
13Scope of protection
- (1) literal infringement
- (2) infringement under the doctrine of
equivalents - Graver Tank Mfg Co. v. Linde Air Products
Co., 39 U.S. 605 (1950) whether persons
reasonably skilled in the art would have known of
the interchangeability of an ingredient not
contained in the patent with one that was - one product-one patent
14Scope of rights as defenses to infringement
- reverse doctrine of equivalents
- (2) general experimental use
- where it is made or used as an experiment,
whether for the gratification of scientific
tastes, or for curiosity - W. Robinson, The Law of Patents for Useful
Inventions - 898 (1890)
- (3) experimentation for purpose of FDA approval
- balancing user and producer needs
15Immunity from liability
- (1) prior user right runs in favor of one
developed an invention more than a year before
patent application filed by another, and
commercially used it from before filing dateonly
for methods (possibly, only business methods) - - covers activities of nonprofit research
laboratories such as universities, for use in the
lab and not for commercialization
16Immunity from liability (contd)
- (2) medical professionals performance of a
medical or surgical procedure on a human body or
an animal used in researchruns in favor of the
practitioner, and the health care entity in which
the activity was performed
17Immunity from liability (contd)
- (3) sovereign immunityruns in favor of state
institutions, such as universities, for monetary
damages (not injunctive relief) - Florida Prepaid Postsecondary Education Expense
Board v. College Savings Bank, 527 U.S. 627
(1999) - College Savings Bank v. Florida Prepaid
Postsecondary Education Expense Board, 527 U.S.
666 (1999) - balancing user and producer needs
18Assumptions underlying intellectual property law
- Linear progression
- Spillover benefits
- Discrete technologies one patent, one product
- End use OR research use
- 5. Sole inventor
- 6. Main economic problems
- a. striking the right producer/user balance
- b. encouraging commercialization
19Bayh Dole Act (1980)
- Runs mainly in favor of universities
- Permits these entities to acquire patent rights
in federally-funded research projects - these can be licensed out on exclusive basis
- Does NOT require patent procurement
- government retains right to patent instead
- Government retains march in rights
20Is this the right picture?
- 1. Linear progression now or ever?
- technology that develops without science (Thomas
Edison) - sciences that are driven by technology (Carnot
cycle discovered by observing steam engines) - technologies that include embedded science
- (Biotechnology)
21Is this the right picture (contd)?
- 2. Spillover benefits Universities as patent
holders - birth of technology transfer offices
- source of arguments to extend patents upstream
- source of negotiation problems
- exclusive licensing (Johns Hopkins,Baxter
Healthcare, Cell Pro) - potential competition
- e.g. Myriad Pharmaceuticals BRCA 12 test kits
22Is this the right picture (contd)?
- 3. Are all technologies discrete? (Merges
Nelson) - chemical technologies
- (special case or paradigm)
- cumulative technologies
- - one product, many patents
- - e.g. semiconductors (Hall and Ziedonis)
- defensive patenting
- cross licensing
- patent pools
23Is this the right picture (contd)?
- 4. Are all uses either end- or research-uses?
- - science-based technologies
- - eg biotechnology DNA, proteomics
- computer science algorithms
- - patents as covering product markets vs patents
that cover innovation markets
24Is this the right picture (contd)?
- 5. Sole inventors myth or reality?
- Industrial re-organization (Woody Powell)
- theory of the firm buy vs. integrate
- team-based research
- patents as signals and facilitators of knowledge
transfer
25PHARMA
BIO
Univ
B
UNIV
Bio
Pharma
Pharma
Pharma
B
Univ
Bio
Univ
U
Pharma
Bio
26PHARMA
BIO
Univ
B
UNIV
Bio
Pharma
Pharm
Pharma
B
Univ
Bio
Univ
U
Pharma
Bio
27Is this the right picture (contd)?
- 6. Main economic problems
- a. producer vs. user balance
- producers are users
- output as input
- universities as producers of a special sort
- capital resources
- patent resources
- human resources
28Is this the right picture (contd)?
- b. commercialization
- readily commercialized science
- e.g. proteomics
- (information on protein structures)
- distantly commercialized science
- e.g. Merck Genome Initiative (expressed sequence
tags (ESTs))
29The bottom line patents as a drag on innovation
in biotechnology
- The tragedy of the anticommons
- (Heller and Eisenberg)
- - pricing issues
- - stacking and reach-through royalties
- - thickets of rights raise transaction costs
- Patents on innovation markets
- - fundamental science as fundamental
- - no inventing around
- - strong rights as producing stalemates
-
303. Demise of the experimental use defense
Madey v. Duke University, 307 F.3d 1351
(Fed.Cir.2002)
- our precedent does not immunize any conduct
that is in keeping with the alleged infringer's
legitimate business, regardless of commercial
implications. For example, major research
universities, such as Duke, often sanction and
fund research projects with arguably no
commercial application whatsoever. However, these
projects unmistakably further the institution's
legitimate business objectives, including
educating and enlightening students and faculty
participating in these projects. These projects
also serve, for example, to increase the status
of the institution and lure lucrative research
grants, students and faculty.
31Where to go from here?
- Six proposals
- Subject matter carve-outs
- Redefine utility
- Tinker with novelty and nonobviousness
- Emphasize disclosure obligations
- Limit the scope of rights
- Create new immunity from liability
32Proposals
- Subject matter carve-outs
- John Barton proteomics as fundamental science
- Richard Epstein exclude upstream inventions
- Redefine utility
- no patents without (significant?) end uses
33Proposals (contd)
- 3. Tinker with novelty and nonobviousness
- worldwide standard of novelty
- change POSITA to TOSITA (team.)
- keep current with modern biotech
- In re Deuel, 51 F.3d 1552 (Fed. Cir. 1995)
- reject chemical technologies as paradigm for
biotech
34Proposals (contd)
- Emphasize disclosure obligations
- written description
- Fiers v Sugano, 984 F.2d 1164 (Fed. Cir. 1993)
- Regents of the University of California v. Eli
Lilly Co., 119 F.3d 1558 (1997) - enablement
- Genentech Inc. v. Novo Nordisk A/S, 108 F.3d 1361
(Fed. Cir. 1997)
35Proposals (contd)
- 5. Limit the scope of rights
- literal infringement defined by enablement
- limit the doctrine of equivalents
- broaden reverse doctrine of equivalents
- Scripps Clinic Research Found. v.
Genentech, 927 F.2d 1565 (Fed. Cir. 1991)
36Proposals scope (contd)
- institute a fair use defense
- (e.g. Maureen ORourke)
- (i) the nature of the advance represented by the
infringement - (ii) the purpose of the infringing use
- (iii) the nature the market failure
- (iv) the impact use on the patentees incentives
and social welfare - (v) the nature of the patented invention
37Proposals (contd)
- 6. Create a new immunity from liability for
universities and their employees if - 1) the patented materials they wish to utilize
are not marketed on reasonable terms - 2) the researcher agrees to publish the results
of the work and - 3) the researcher agrees to refrain from
patenting the results, or to patent the results
and then license them on a nonexclusive basis and
on reasonable terms (waiver)
38Advantages of immunity approach
- Avoids need to characterize invention or use, or
to price - Patents available to spur invention, facilitate
technology transfer - Recognizes differences between commercial and
noncommercial research - incentive structure
- monetary resources
- human capital
- patents for cross licensing
39Advantages of immunity approach (contd)
- Waiver
- enriches public domain
- softens effect of Bayh Dole by monetizing and
internalizing benefits of allowing the work to
fall into the public domain - restores Mertonian ethos
40Problems with immunity approach
- Devalues the product market
- BUT how much, given downstream nature of use
- Devalues the innovation market
- BUT how much, since these uses are not high
on the patentees own priority list - Who will have authority to waive?
- BUT same issue under College Savings Bank
- Tracing costs, pricing buyouts
- BUT same issue for patent infringement
41For comparative purposes
- The EPC exempts acts done privately and for
non-commercial purposes and acts done for
experimental purposes, Art. 31 (a), (b) - - interpreted to permit experiments to establish
the scope and application of a patented
invention, including experiments to discover an
improvement to it, but not experiments to prepare
to duplicate and sell what is already on the
market.
42Royal Society Report, Keeping Science Open (April
2003), 3.23
- Between these two extremes there is doubtful
ground, and prudent people avoid doubtful ground.
It would be conducive to the development of
science if the position of scientific work under
these exemptions was clearer.
43Compatibility with TRIPS Agreement
- Under art. 27 (nondiscrimination)
- is de facto discrimination actionable
- all sciences are not created alike
- Under art. 30 (permitted exceptions)
- is the immunity limited
- is exploitation of innovation market normal
- is it within the patentees legitimate interests
- what of the interests of third parties, such as
researchers and those who benefit from
spillovers?
44Compatibility with TRIPS Agreement (contd)
- Under the remedies provisions
- Art. 41(5) measures obligations by enforcement of
other laws, including limits on speculative
damages - Art. 45 measures royalty obligations by local
demand, capacity to pay, position on parallel
importation, and price controls - Art. 44 requires courts to be authorized to award
injunctions, but courts retain discretion of
equity - if nations can vary BENEFITS innovators can
extract, they must also be able to vary COSTS
innovators face
45Summary
- Organization and production of innovation
industries have changed - how should national law respond?
- are international agreements robust enough to
tolerate adjustment?