Interest Rate Futures: - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 152
About This Presentation
Title:

Interest Rate Futures:

Description:

... 1M loan for 180 days that it plans to finance by selling a 90-day CD now at the ... Bank sells $1M of CD now (June) at 8.258%. At the September ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:57
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 153
Provided by: hpcus503
Category:
Tags: cdnow | futures | interest | rate

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Interest Rate Futures:


1
Chapter 13
  • Interest Rate Futures
  • Applications and Pricing

2
Applications and Pricing
  • Hedging debt positions
  • Speculative positions
  • Managing asset and liability positions
  • Formation of synthetic fixed-rate and
    floating-rate debt and investment positions
  • Pricing of futures contracts using the
    carrying-cost model
  • Use of foreign currency futures contracts to
    hedge international investment and debt position
    against exchange-rate risk

3
Hedging
  • Naïve Hedge
  • Cross Hedge

4
Naïve Hedging Model
  • The simplest model to hedge a debt position is to
    use a naive hedging model.
  • For debt positions, a naive hedge can be formed
    by hedging each dollar of the face value of the
    spot position with one market-value dollar in the
    futures contract.
  • A naive hedge also can be formed by hedging each
    dollar of the market value of the spot position
    with one market-value dollar of the futures.

5
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Consider the case of a treasurer of a corporation
    who is expecting a 5 million cash inflow in June
    that she is planning to invest in T-bills for 91
    days.
  • If the treasurer wants to lock in the yield on
    the T-bill investment, she could do so by going
    long in June T-bill futures contracts.

6
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Example If the June T-bill contract were trading
    at the index price of 95, the treasurer could
    lock in a yield (YTMf) of 5.1748 on a 91-day
    investment made at the futures' expiration date
    in June

7
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • To obtain the 5.1748 yield, the treasurer would
    need to form a hedge in which she bought nf
    5.063291 June T-bill futures contracts (assume
    perfect divisibility)

nf Investment in June 5,000,000 5.063291
Long Contracts f0
987,500
8
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • At the June expiration date, the treasurer would
    close the futures position at the price on the
    spot 91-day T-bills.
  • If the cash flow, CF, from closing is positive,
    the treasurer would invest the excess cash in
    T-bills.
  • If it is negative, the treasurer would cover the
    shortfall with some of the anticipated cash
    inflow earmarked for purchasing T-bills.

9
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Hedge Relation

10
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Suppose at the June expiration, the spot 91-day
    T-bill rate is at 4.5.
  • The manager would find T-bill prices higher at
    989,086 but would realize a profit of 8,030.38
    from closing the futures position.
  • Combining the profit with the 5M CF, the
    manager would be able to buy 5.063291 T-bills and
    earn a rate off the 5M investment of 5.1748.

11
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
12
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Suppose at the June expiration, the spot 91-day
    T-bill rate is at 5.5.
  • The manager would find T-bill prices lower at
    986,740 but would realize a loss of 3,848 from
    closing the futures position.
  • With the inflow of 5 million, the treasurer
    would need to use 3,848 to settle the futures
    position, leaving her only 4,996,152 to invest
    in T-bills.
  • However, with the price of the T-bill lower in
    this case, the treasurer would again be able to
    buy 5.063291 T-bills, and therefore realize a
    5.1748 rate of return from the 5 million
    investment.

13
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
14
Long Hedge - Future 91-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Note, the hedge rate of 5.1748 occurs for any
    rate scenario.

15
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Case
  • Money market manager is expecting a 5M CF in
    June that she plans to invest in a 182-day
    T-bill.
  • Since the T-bill underlying a futures contract
    has a maturity of 91 days, the manager would need
    to go long in both a June T-bill futures and a
    September T-bill futures (note there is
    approximately 91 days between the contract) in
    order to lock in a return on a 182-day T-bill
    investment.

16
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
  • If June T-bill futures were trading at IMM of 91
    and September futures were trading at IMM of
    91.4, then the manager could lock in a 9.3 rate
    on an investment in 182-day T-bills by going
    long in 5.115 June T-bill futures and 5.11
    September contracts.

17
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
18
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Suppose in June, the spot 91-day T-bill rate is
    at 8 and the spot 182-day T-bill rate is at
    8.25.
  • At these rates, the price on the 91-day spot
    T-bill would be 980,995, the price on the
    182-day spot would be 961,245, and if the
    carrying-cost model holds, the price on the
    September futures would be 979,865.
  • At these prices, the manager would be able to
    earn a profit of 24,852 from closing both
    futures contract (which offsets the higher T-bill
    futures prices) and would be able to buy 5.227
    182-day T-bills, yielding a rate of 9.3 from a
    5M investment.

19
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
20
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
  • Suppose in June, the spot 91-day T-bill rate is
    at 10 and the spot 182- day T-bill rate is at
    10.25.
  • At these rates, the price on the 91-day spot
    T-bill would be 976,518, the price on the
    182-day spot would be 952,508, and if the
    carrying-cost model holds, the price on the
    September futures would be 975,413.
  • At these prices, the manager would incur a loss
    of 20,798 from closing both futures contracts.
    However, with lower T-bill futures prices, the
    manager would still be able to buy 5.227 182-day
    T-bills, yielding a rate of 9.3 from a 5M
    investment.

21
Long Hedge - Future 182-Day T-Bill Investment
22
Short Hedge Managing the Maturity Gap
  • In June, a bank makes a 1M loan for 180 days
    that it plans to finance by selling a 90-day CD
    now at the LIBOR of 8.258 and a 90-day CD
    ninety days later (in September) at the LIBOR
    prevailing at that time.
  • To minimize its exposure to market risk, the bank
    goes short in 1.03951 September Eurodollar
    futures at 92.4 (IMM).
  • By doing this, the bank is able to lock in a rate
    on its CD financing for 180 days of 8.17.

23
Managing the Maturity Gap
  • Bank sells 1M of CD now (June) at 8.258. At
    the September
  • maturity, the bank would owe 1,019,758.
  • To hedge this liability, the bank would go short
    in 1.03951 Eurodollar
  • futures at 981,000.

24
Managing the Maturity Gap
  • In September, the bank will sell a new 90-day CD
    at the prevailing LIBOR to finance its
    1.019758M debt on the maturing CD plus (minus)
    any debt (profit) from closing its short
    September Eurodollar futures position.
  • If the LIBOR rate is higher, the bank will have
    to pay greater interest on the new CD, but it
    will realize a profit on its futures that, in
    turn, will lower the amount of funds it needs to
    finance.
  • On the other hand, if the LIBOR is lower, then
    the bank will have lower interest payment on its
    new CD, but it will also incur a loss on its
    futures position and therefore have more funds
    that need to be financed.

25
Managing the Maturity Gap
  • As shown in the exhibit on the next slide, at a
    September LIBORs of 7.5 or 8.7, the banks
    total debt at the end of the 180-day period will
    be 1,039,509, which equates to a rate of 8.17.
  • Note This is true for any rate.

26
Managing the Maturity Gap
27
Cross Hedge Price-Sensitivity Model
  • Cross Hedging is hedging a position with a
    futures contract in which the asset underlying
    the futures is different than the asset to be
    hedged.
  • Example
  • Future CP sale hedged with T-bill futures
  • AA Bond portfolio hedged with T-bond futures

28
Cross Hedge Price-Sensitivity Model
  • One model used for cross hedging is the
    price-sensitivity model developed by Kolb and
    Chiang (1981) and Toers and Jacobs (1986)).
  • This model has been shown to be relatively
    effective in reducing the variability of debt
    positions.
  • The model determines the number of futures
    contracts that will make the value of a portfolio
    consisting of a fixed-income security and an
    interest rate futures contract invariant to small
    changes in interest rates.

29
Cross Hedge Price-Sensitivity Model
30
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future CP Issue
with T-bill Futures
  • A company plans to sell a 182-day CP issue with a
    10M principal in June to finance its anticipated
    accounts receivable.
  • The company would like to lock in the current CP
    rate of 6, ensuring it of funds from the CP sale
    of 9.713635M.
  • Using the price-sensitivity model, the company
    locks in a rate by going short in 20 June T-bill
    futures contracts at IMM index 95.

31
Cross-Hedging Example Hedging a Future CP Issue
with T-Bill Futures
32
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future CP Issue
with T-bill Futures
  • If CP sold at a discount yield that was 25 BP
    greater than the discount yield on T-bills, then
    the company would be able to lock in a rate on
    its CP of 5.48 when it sold its CP and closed
    its futures position (assuming the time of the CP
    sale and T-bill futures expiration are the same).

33
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future CP Issue
with T-bill Futures
34
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future AAA Bond
Sale Issue with T-bill Futures
  • Bond portfolio manager plans to sell AA bond
    portfolio in June. Currently, the fund has the
    following features
  • Current Value 1.02M,
  • YTM 11.75
  • Duration 7.66 years
  • Weighted Average Maturity 15 years.

35
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future AAA Bond
Sale Issue with T-bill Futures
  • Suppose the manager is considering hedging the
    portfolio against interest rate changes by going
    short in June T-bond futures contracts currently
    trading at f0 72 16/32 with the T-bond most
    likely to be delivered on the contract having the
    following features
  • YTM 9,
  • Maturity 18 years
  • Duration of 7 years
  • Using the Price-Sensitivity Model, the portfolio
    manager could hedge the bond portfolio by selling
    14 futures contracts.

36
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future AAA Bond
Sale Issue with T-Bond Futures
37
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future AAA Bond
Sale Issue with T-bill Futures
  • If the manager hedges the bond portfolio with 14
    June T-bond short contracts, she will be able to
    offset changes in the bond portfolio's value
    resulting from interest rate changes.

38
Cross Hedging Example Hedging a Future AAA Bond
Sale Issue with T-bill Futures
  • Example, suppose interest rates increased from
    January to mid-May causing the price of the bond
    portfolio to decrease from 102 to 95 and the
    futures price on the June T-bond contract to
    decrease from 72 16/32 to 68 22/32.
  • In this case, the fixed-income portfolio would
    lose 70,000 in value (decrease in value from
    1,020,000 to 950,000).
  • This loss, though, would be partially offset by a
    profit of 53,375 on the T-bond futures position
    Futures Profit 1472,500 - 68,687.50
    53,375.
  • Thus, by using T-bond futures the manager is able
    to reduce some of the potential losses in her
    portfolio value that would result if interest
    rates increase.

39
Speculating with Interest Rate Futures
  • While interest rate futures are extensively used
    for hedging, they are also frequently used to
    speculate on expected interest rate changes.
  • A long futures position is taken when interest
    rates are expected to fall.
  • A short position is taken when rates are expected
    to rise.

40
Speculating with Interest Rate Futures
  • Speculating on interest rate changes by taking
    such outright or naked futures positions
    represents an alternative to buying or short
    selling a bond on the spot market.
  • Because of the risk inherent in such outright
    futures positions, though, some speculators form
    spreads instead of taking a naked position.
  • A futures spread is formed by taking long and
    short positions on different futures contracts
    simultaneously.

41
Speculating with Interest Rate Futures
  • Outright Positions
  • Long Expect rates to decrease
  • ST Rates use T-bills or Eurodollar futures
  • LT Rates use T-bonds or T-note futures
  • Short Expect rates to increase
  • ST Rates use T-bills or Eurodollars futures
  • LT Rates use T-bonds or T-note futures

42
Speculating with Interest Rate Futures
  • Spread
  • Intracommodity Spread long and short in futures
    on the same underlying asset but with different
    expirations.
  • Intercommodity Spread Long and short in futures
    with different underlying assets but the same
    expiration.

43
Intracommodity Spread
  • More distant futures contracts (T2) are more
    price-sensitive to changes in the spot price than
    near-term futures contracts (T1)

44
Intracommodity Spread
  • A speculator who expected the interest rate on
    long-term bonds to decrease in the future could
    form an intracommodity spread by going
  • long in a longer-term T-bond futures contract and
  • short in a shorter-term one.
  • This type of spread will be profitable if the
    expectation of long-term rates decreasing occurs.

45
Intracommodity Spread
  • That is, the increase in the T-bond price
    resulting from a decrease in long-term rates,
    will cause the price on the longer-term T-bond
    futures to increase more than the shorter-term
    one. As a result, a speculators gains from his
    long position in the longer-term futures will
    exceed his losses from his short position.
  • If rates rise, though, losses will occur on the
    long position these losses will be offset
    partially by profits realized from the short
    position on the longer-term contract

46
Intracommodity Spread
  • If a bond speculator believed rates would
    increase but did not want to assume the risk
    inherent in an outright short position, he could
    form a spread with
  • a short position in a longer term contract and
  • a long position in the shorter term one.

47
Intracommodity Spread
  • Note that in forming a spread, the speculator
    does not have to keep the ratio of long- to-short
    positions one-to-one, but instead could use any
    ratio (2-to-1, 3-to-2, etc.) to give him his
    desired return-risk combination.

48
Intercommodity SpreadRate-Anticipation Swap
  • Consider the case of a spreader who is
    forecasting a general decline in interest rates
    across all maturities (i.e., a downward parallel
    shift in the yield curve).
  • Since bonds with greater maturities are more
    price sensitive to interest rate changes than
    those with shorter maturities, a speculator could
    set up a rate-anticipation swap by going long in
    the longer-term bond with the position partially
    hedged by going short in the shorter-term one.

49
Intercommodity SpreadRate-Anticipation Swap
  • Instead of using spot securities, the specualtor
    alternatively could form an intercommodity spread
    by going long in a T-bond futures contract that
    is partially hedge by a short position in a
    T-note (or T-bill) futures contract.
  • On the other hand, if an investor were
    forecasting an increase in rates across all
    maturities, instead of forming a
    rate-anticipation swap with spot positions, she
    could go short in the T-bond futures contract and
    long in the T-note.
  • Forming spreads with T-note and T-bond futures is
    one of the more popular intercommodity spread
    strategies it is referred to as the NOB strategy
    (Notes over Bonds).

50
Intercommodity SpreadQuality Swap
  • Another type of intercommodity spreads involves
    contracts on bonds with different default risk
    characteristics it is an alternative to a
    quality swap.
  • For example, a spread formed with futures
    contracts on a T-bond and a Municipal Bond Index
    (MBI) or contracts on T-bills and Eurodollar
    deposits.
  • Like quality swaps, profits from these spreads
    are based on the ability to forecast a narrowing
    or a widening of the spread between the yields on
    the underlying bonds.

51
Intercommodity SpreadQuality Swap
  • For example, in an economic recession the demand
    for lower default-risk bonds often increases
    relative to the demand for higher default-risk
    bonds.
  • If this occurs, then the spot yield spread for
    lower grade bonds over higher grade would tend to
    widen.
  • A speculator forecasting an economic recession
    could, in turn, profit from an anticipated
    widening in the risk premium by forming an
    intercommodity spread consisting of a long
    position in a T-bond futures contract (no default
    risk) and short position in a MBI contract (some
    degree of default risk).

52
Intercommodity SpreadQuality Swap
  • Similarly, since Eurodollar deposits are not
    completely riskless, while T-bills are, a
    spreader forecasting riskier times (and the
    resulting widening of the spread between
    Eurodollar rates and T-bill rates) could go long
    in the T-bill contract and short in the
    Eurodollar contract.
  • A spread with T-bills and Eurodollars contracts
    is known as a TED spread.

53
Managing Asset and Liability Positions
  • Interest rate futures can also be used by
    financial and non-financial corporations to alter
    the exposure of their balance sheets to interest
    rate changes. The change can be done for
  • Speculative purposes increasing the firms
    exposure to interest rate changes
  • Hedging purposes reducing the firms exposure to
    interest rate changes.

54
Managing Asset and Liability Positions
  • Example
  • Consider an insurance company that as a matter of
    policy maintains an immunized position in which
    the duration of its bond portfolio is equal to
    the duration of its liabilities DA DL.
  • With a duration gap of zero, DA - DL 0, the
    companys economic surplus is invariant to
    interest rate changes.
  • Suppose, though, that the managers expect rates
    will fall across all maturities in the future and
    would like to change the insurance companys
    interest rate exposure to a moderately
    speculative one in which the company has a
    positive duration gap DA - DL gt 0.
  • As noted in Chapter 8, one way for the company to
    do this would be to increase the duration of its
    bond portfolio by changing the allocation sell
    short-term bonds and buy long-term ones.

55
Managing Asset and Liability Positions
  • An alternative to this expensive strategy would
    be to take a long position in T-bond futures.
  • If rates decrease as expected, then the value of
    the companys bond portfolio would increase and
    it would also profit from its long futures
    position.
  • If rates were to increase, then the company would
    see not only a decline in the value of its bond
    portfolio but also losses on it futures position.
  • Thus, by adding futures the company has
    effectively increased its balance sheets
    interest rate exposure by creating a positive
    duration gap.

56
Managing Asset and Liability Positions
  • Instead of increasing its balance sheets
    exposure to interest rate changes, a company may
    choose to reduce it.
  • For example, a company with a positive duration
    gap and a concern over futures interest rate
    increases could reduce the gap by taking a short
    position in an interest rate futures contract.

57
Managing Asset and Liability Positions
  • This method of hedging or speculating in which
    the original composition of assets and
    liabilities is not changed is referred to as
    off-balance sheet restructuring.

58
Synthetic Debt and Investment Positions
  • There are some cases in which the rate on debt
    and investment positions can be improved by
    creating synthetic positions with futures and
    other derivative securities such as swaps.
  • These cases involve
  • Creating a synthetic fixed-rate loan by combining
    a floating-rate loan with short positions in a
    series of Eurodollar futures contracts
  • Creating a synthetic floating-rate loan by
    combining a fixed-rate loan with long positions
    in a series of Eurodollar futures contracts
  • Creating synthetic fixed-rate investment by
    combining an investment in a floating-rate note
    with a long position in a series of Eurodollar
    futures
  • Creating floating-rate investment by combining an
    investment in a fixed-rate note with a short
    position in a series of Eurodollar futures.

59
Synthetic Debt and Investment Positions
  • Note
  • In practice, exchange-traded interest rate
    futures contracts are usually priced so that such
    opportunities dont exist.
  • That is, if the equilibrium carrying-cost model
    governing interest rate futures prices holds,
    then the rate on synthetic positions will be
    equal to the rate on the spot.

60
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • A corporation wanting to finance its operations
    or capital expenditures with fixed-rate debt has
    a choice of either a direct fixed-rate loan or a
    synthetic fixed-rate loan formed with a
    floating-rate loan and short positions in
    Eurodollar futures contracts, whichever is
    cheaper.
  • Consider the case of a corporation that can
    obtain a one-year, 1M fixed-rate loan from a
    bank at 11 or alternatively can obtain a
    one-year, floating-rate loan from a bank.

61
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • In the floating-rate loan, suppose the loan
    starts on 9/20 with the rate at 11.25 and is
    then reset on 12/20, 3/20, and 6/20 at the
    prevailing LIBOR plus 150 BP.
  • The company fixes the floating rate by going
    short in a series of Eurodollar futures
    (Eurodollar strip).

62
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • Suppose the company goes short in Eurodollar
    contracts with expirations of 12/20, 3/20, and
    6/20 and the following prices

63
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • By doing this, the company is able to lock in a
    fixed rate of 10.12

64
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • For example, if the LIBOR is at 9 on date 12/20,
    the company will have to pay 26,250 on its loan
    the next quarter but it will also have a profit
    on its 12/20 Eurodollar futures of 1,250 that it
    can use to defray part of the interest expenses,
    yielding an effective hedged rate of 10.

65
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
66
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
  • If the LIBOR is at 6 on date 12/20, the company
    will have to pay only 18,750 on its loan the
    next quarter but it will also have to cover a
    loss on its 12/20 Eurodollar futures of 6,250.
    The payment of interest and the loss on the
    futures yields an effective hedged rate of 10.

67
Synthetic Fixed-Rate Loan
68
Synthetic Floating-Rate Loan
  • A synthetic floating-rate loan is formed by
    borrowing at a fixed rate and taking a long
    position in a Eurodollar or T-bill futures
    contract.

69
Synthetic Floating-Rate Loan
  • For example, suppose the corporation in the
    preceding example had a floating-rate asset and
    wanted a floating-rate loan instead of a fixed
    one.
  • Suppose the corporation could take a
    floating-rate loan at LIBOR plus 200 BP or it
    could form a synthetic floating-rate loan by
    borrowing at a fixed rate for one year and going
    long in a series of Eurodollar futures expiring
    at 12/20, 3/20, and 6/20

70
Synthetic Floating-Rate Loan
  • The synthetic loan will provide a lower rate than
    the direct floating-rate loan if the fixed rate
    is less than 10.5.
  • For example, suppose the corporation borrows at a
    fixed rate of 10 for one year with interest
    payments made quarterly at dates 12/20, 3/20, and
    6/20 and then goes long in the series of
    Eurodollar futures to form a synthetic
    floating-rate loan.

71
Synthetic Floating-Rate Loan
  • On date 12/20, if the settlement LIBOR were 9
    (settlement index price of 97.75 and a closing
    futures price of 977,500), the corporation would
    lose 1,250 ( (977,500 - 978,750)) from its
    long position on the 12/20 futures contracts and
    would pay 25,000 on its fixed-rate loan
    ((.10/4)(1M) 25,000).
  • The companys hedged annualize rate would be
    10.5 (4(25,000 1,250)/1,000,000 .105),
    which is .5 less than the rate paid on the
    floating-rate loan (LIBOR 200BP 9 2.0
    11).

72
Synthetic Floating-Rate Loan
  • If the settlement LIBOR were 6 (settlement
    index price of 94 and a closing futures price of
    985,000), the corporation would realize a profit
    of 6,250 ( (985,000 - 978,750) from the long
    position on the 12/20 futures contracts and would
    pay 25,000 on its fixed-rate loan.
  • Its hedged annualize rate would be 7.5
    ((4)(25,000 - 6,250))/1,000,000 .075), which
    again is .5 less than the rate on the floating-
    rate loan (LIBOR 200BP 6 2.0 8.0).

73
Synthetic Investment
  • Futures can also be used on the asset side to
    create synthetic fixed and floating rate
    investments.
  • An investment company setting up a three-year
    unit investment trust offering a fixed rate could
    invest funds either in three-year fixed-rate
    securities or a synthetic one formed with a
    three-year floating-rate note tied to the LIBOR
    and long positions in a series of Eurodollar
    futures, which ever yields the higher rate.

74
Synthetic Investment
  • An investor looking for a floating-rate security
    could alternatively consider a synthetic
    floating-rate investment consisting of fixed-rate
    security and a short Eurodollar strip.

75
Futures Pricing
  • The underlying asset price on a futures contract
    primarily depends on the spot price of the
    underlying asset.
  • The difference between the futures (or forward
    price) and the spot price is called the basis
    (Bt)

76
Futures Pricing
  • Note By definition a normal futures market is
    defined as one with a positive basis, while an
    inverted futures market is defined as one with a
    negative basis

77
Futures Pricing
  • For most futures (and forward) contracts, the
    futures price exceeds the spot price before
    expiration and approaches the spot price as
    expiration nears.
  • Thus, the basis usually is positive and
    decreasing over time, equaling or nearing zero at
    expiration (BT 0).
  • Futures and spot prices also tend to be highly
    correlated with each other, increasing and
    decreasing together their correlation, though,
    is not perfect.
  • As a result, the basis tends to be relatively
    stable along its declining trend, even when
    futures and spot prices vacillate.

78
Carrying-Cost Model
  • The relationship between the spot price and the
    futures or forward price can be explained by the
    carrying-cost model (or cost of carry model).
  • In this model, arbitrageurs ensure that the
    equilibrium forward price is equal to the net
    costs of carrying the underlying asset to
    expiration.
  • The model is used to explain what determines the
    equilibrium price on a forward contract. However,
    if short-term interest rates are constant, the
    carrying-cost model can be extended to pricing
    futures contracts.

79
Carrying-Cost Model
  • In terms of the carrying-cost model, the price
    difference between futures and spot prices can be
    explained by the costs and benefits of carrying
    the underlying asset to expiration.
  • For futures on debt securities
  • The carrying costs include the financing costs of
    holding the underlying asset to expiration.
  • The benefits include the coupon interest earned
    from holding the security.

80
Carrying-Cost Model
  • To illustrate the carrying-cost model consider
    the pricing of a T-bill futures contract.
  • With no coupon interest, the underlying T-bill
    does not generate any benefits during the holding
    period and the financing costs are the only
    carrying costs.

81
Pricing T-Bill FuturesCarrying Cost Model
82
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • Example
  • If the rate on a 161-day spot T-bill is 5.7 and
    the repo rate (or RF rate ) for 70 days is 6.38,
    then the price on a T-bill futures contract with
    an expiration of 70 days would be 98.74875

83
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • The futures price is governed by arbitrage. If
    the market price does not equal f, then
    arbitrageurs would take a position in the futures
    and an opposite position in the spot.
  • This arbitrage strategy is referred to as a cash
    and carry arbitrage.

84
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • Example Suppose f M 99
  • An arbitrageur would go short in the futures,
    agreeing to sell a 91-day T-bill for 99 seventy
    days later and would go long in the spot,
    borrowing 97.5844 at 6.38 for 70 days to finance
    the purchase of the 161-day T-bill that is
    trading at 97.5844.
  • Seventy days later (expiration), the arbitrageur
    would sell the bill (which now would have a
    maturity of 91 days) on the futures for 99 (fM)
    and pay off his financing debt of 98.74875 (f),
    realizing a cash flow of 2,512.50.

85
Pricing T-Bill Futures
86
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • Note at f M 99, a money market manager planning
    to invest for 70 days in a T-bill at 6.38 could
    earn a greater return by buying a 161-day bill
    and going short in the 70-day T-bill futures to
    lock in the selling price.

87
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • For example, using the above numbers, if a money
    market manager were planning to invest 97.5844
    for 70 days, she could buy a 161-day bill for
    that amount and go short in the futures at 99.
  • Her return would be 7.8, compared to only 6.38
    from the 70-day T-bill

88
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • Example Suppose f M 98
  • An arbitrageur would go long in the futures,
    agreeing to buy a 91-day T-bill for 98 seventy
    days later and would go short in the spot,
    borrowing the 161-day T-bill, selling it for
    97.5844 and investing the proceeds at 6.38 for
    70 days.
  • Seventy days later (expiration), the arbitrageur
    would buy the bill (which now would have a
    maturity of 91 days) on the futures for 98 (fM),
    use the bill to close his short position, and
    collect 98.74875 (f) from his investment,
    realizing a cash flow of 7,487.50

89
Pricing T-Bill Futures
90
Pricing T-Bill Futures
  • Note at f M 98, a money market manager with a
    161-day T-bill could earn an arbitrage by selling
    the bill for 97.5844 and investing the proceed at
    6.38 for 70 days, then going long in the 70-day
    T-bill futures.
  • Seventy days later, the money market manager
    would receive 98.74875 from the investment and
    would pay 98 on the futures to reacquire the bill
    for a CF of .74875 (per 100 face value).

91
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • Implication 1
  • If the carrying-cost model holds, then the spot
    rate on a 70-day bill (repo rate) will be equal
    to the synthetic rate (implied repo rate) formed
    by buying the 161-day bill and going short in the
    70-day futures.

92
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
93
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • Formally, the implied repo rate is defined as the
    rate in which the arbitrage profit from
    implementing the cash and carry arbitrage
    strategy is zero

94
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • The actual repo rate is the one we use in solving
    for the equilibrium futures price in the
    carrying-cost model in our example, this was the
    rate on the 70-day T-bill (6.38).
  • Thus, the equilibrium condition that the
    synthetic and spot T-bill be equal can be stated
    equivalently as an equality between the actual
    and the implied repo rates.

95
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • Implication 2
  • If the carrying-cost model holds, then the YTM of
    the futures will be equal to the implied forward
    rate (RI)

96
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • In terms of our example, if f0M f0 98.74875,
    then the implied futures rate will be 5.18

97
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • The implied forward rate on a 91-day T-bill
    investment to be made 70 days from the present,
    RI(91,70), is obtained by
  • Selling short the 70-day T-bill at 98.821
    (100/(1.0638)70/365 (or equivalently borrowing
    98.821 at 6.38)
  • Buying S0(T)/S0(T91) S0(70)/S0(161)
    98.821/97.5844 1.01267 issues of the 161-day
    T-bill
  • Paying 100 at the end of 70 days to cover the
    short position on the maturing bond (or the loan)
  • Collecting 1.01267(100) at the end of 161 days
    from the long position.

98
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • This locking-in strategy would earn an investor a
    return of 101.267, 91 days after the investor
    expends 100 to cover the short sale thus, the
    implied forward rate on a 91-day investment made
    70 days from the present is 1.267, or
    annualized, 5.18

99
Pricing T-Bill Futures Implications
  • Thus, if the carrying-cost model holds, then the
    implied yield on the futures is equal to the
    implied forward rate.

100
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • The T-bond futures contract gives the party with
    the short position the right to deliver, at any
    time during the delivery month, any bond with a
    maturity of at least 15 years.

101
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • When a particular bond is delivered, the price
    received by the seller is equal to the quoted
    futures price on the futures contract times a
    conversion factor, CFA, applicable to the
    delivered bond.
  • The invoice price, in turn, is equal to that
    price plus any accrued interest on the delivered
    bond.

Invoice Price (f0) (CFA) Accrued Interest
102
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • The CBOT uses a conversion factor based on
    discounting the deliverable bond by a 6 YTM. The
    CBOTs rules for calculating the CFA on the
    deliverable bond are as follows
  • The bonds maturity and time to the next coupon
    date are rounded down to the closest three
    months.
  • After rounding, if the bond has an exact number
    of six-month periods, then the first coupon is
    assumed to be paid in six months.
  • After rounding, if the bond does not have an
    exact number of six-month periods, then the first
    coupon is assumed to be paid in three months and
    the accrued interest is subtracted.

103
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • Example A 5.5 T-bond maturing in 18 years and 1
    month would be
  • Rounded down to 18 years
  • The first coupon would be assumed to be paid in
    six months
  • The CFA would be determined using a discount rate
    of 6 and face value of 100

104
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • The CFA for the bond would be .945419

105
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • If the bond matured in 18 years and four months,
    the bond would be assume to have a maturity of 18
    years and three months.
  • Its CFA would be found by determining the value
    of the bond three months from the present,
    discounting that value to the current period, and
    subtracting the accrued interest ((3/6)(2.75)
    1.375).

106
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • During the delivery month, there are a number of
    possible bonds that can be delivered.
  • The party with the short position will select
    that bond that is cheapest to deliver.
  • The CBOT maintains tables with possible
    deliverable bonds.

107
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • The tables show the bonds current quoted price
    and its CFA.
  • For example, suppose three possible bonds are

108
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • If the current quoted futures price were 90 16
    (90.5), the costs of buying and delivering each
    bond would be

Thus, the cheapest bond to deliver would be
number 2.
109
Pricing T-Bond Futures Cheapest-to-Deliver Bond
  • Over time and as rates change, the
    cheapest-to-deliver bond can change.
  • In general
  • If rates exceed 6, the CBOTs conversion system
    favors bonds with higher maturities and lower
    coupons.
  • If rates are less than 6, the system tends to
    favor higher coupon bonds with shorter maturities.

110
Pricing T-Bond Futures Wild-Card Play
  • Under the CBOT's procedures, a T-bond futures
    trader with a short position who wants to deliver
    on the contract has the right to determine during
    the expiration month not only the eligible bond
    to deliver, but also the day of the delivery.

111
Pricing T-Bond Futures Wild-Card Play
  • The delivery process encompasses the following
    three business days
  • Business Day 1, Position Day The short position
    holder notifies the clearinghouse that she will
    deliver.
  • Business Day 2, Notice of Intention Day The
    clearinghouse assigns a long position holder the
    contract (typically the holder with the longest
    outstanding contract).
  • Business Day 3, Delivery Day The short holder
    delivers an eligible T-bond to the assigned long
    position holder who pays the short holder an
    invoice price determined by the futures price and
    a conversion factor.

112
Pricing T-Bond Futures Wild-Card Play
  • Since a short holder can notify the
    clearinghouse of her intention to deliver a bond
    by 8 p.m. (Chicago time) at the end of the
    position day (not necessarily at the end of the
    futures' trading day), an arbitrage opportunity
    has arisen because of the futures exchange's
    closing time being 200 (Chicago time) and the
    closing time on spot T-bond trading being 400.

113
Pricing T-Bond Futures Wild-Card Play
  • Thus, a short holder knowing the settlement price
    at 200 p.m., could find the price of an eligible
    T-bond decreasing in the next two hours on the
    spot market.
  • If this occurred, she could buy the bond at the
    end of the day at the lower price, then notify
    the clearinghouse of her intention to deliver
    that bond on the futures contract.
  • If the bond price does not decline, the short
    holder can keep her position and wait another
    day.
  • This feature of the T-bond futures contract is
    known as the wild-card option. This option tends
    to lower the futures price.

114
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • Like T-bill futures, the price on a T-bond
    futures contract depends on the spot price on the
    underlying T-bond (S0) and the risk-free rate.
  • Note The pricing of a T-bond futures contract is
    more complex than the pricing of T-bill or
    Eurodollar futures because of the uncertainty
    over the bond to be delivered and the time of the
    delivery.

115
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • If we assume that we know the cheapest-to-deliver
    bond and the time of delivery, the equilibrium
    futures price is
  • where
  • S0 current spot price of the cheapest-to-deliver
    T-bond (clean price plus accrued interest)
  • PV(C) present value of coupons paid on the bond
    during the life of the futures contract

116
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • Example, suppose the following
  • The cheapest-to-deliver T-bond underlying a
    futures contract has the following features
  • Coupon 10
  • CFA 1.2
  • Currently Price 110 (clean price)
  • The cheapest-to-deliver T-bonds last coupon date
    was 50 days ago, its next coupon is 132 days from
    now, and the coupon after that comes 182 day
    later.
  • The yield curve is flat at 6.
  • The T-bond futures estimated expiration is T
    270 days.

117
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • The current T-bond spot price is 111.37 and the
    present value of the 5 coupon received in 132
    days is 4.8957

118
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • The equilibrium futures price based on a 10
    deliverable bond is therefore 111.16 per 100
    face value

119
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • The quoted price on a futures contract written on
    the 10 delivered bond would be stated net of
    accrued interest at the delivery date.
  • The delivery date occurs 138 days after the last
    coupon payment (270-132).
  • Thus, at delivery, there would be 138 days of
    accrued interest. Given the 182-day period
    between coupon payments, accrued interest would
    therefore be 3.791

Accrued Interest (138/182)(5) 3.791
120
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • The quoted futures price on the delivered bond
    would be 107.369
  • With a CFA of 1.2, the equilibrium quoted futures
    price would be 89.47

Quoted Futures Price 111.16 3.791 107.369
Quoted Futures Price on Bond 111.16 -
(138/182)5 107.369 Quoted Futures Price
107.369/1.2 89.47
121
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • Like T-bill futures, cash-and-carry arbitrage
    opportunities will exist if the T-bond futures
    were not equal to 111.16 (or its quoted price of
    89.47).

122
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • Example, if futures were priced at f M 113, an
    arbitrageur could
  • Go short in the futures at 113
  • Buy the underlying cheapest-to-deliver bond for
    111.37
  • Finance the bond purchase by
  • Borrowing 106.4743 ( S0 PV(C) 111.37
    4.8957) at 6 for 270 days
  • Borrowing 4.8957 at 6 for 132 days

123
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • 132 days later, the arbitrageur would receive a
    5 coupon that he would use to pay off the
    132-day loan of 5 ( 4.8957(1.06)132/365).
  • At expiration, the arbitrageur would
  • Sell the bond on the futures contract at 113
  • Pay off his financing cost on the 270-day loan of
    111.16 ( 106.4743(1.06)270/365).

124
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • At expiration, the arbitrageur realized a profit
    of 1.84 per 100 face value

fM f0 113 111.16 1.84 per 100 face
value
125
Pricing T-Bond Futures Equilibrium Price
  • This risk-free return would result in
    arbitrageurs pursuing this strategy of going
    short in the futures and long in the T-bond,
    causing the futures price to decrease to 111.16
    where the arbitrage disappears.
  • If the futures price were below 111.16,
    arbitrageurs would reverse the strategy, shorting
    the bond, investing the proceeds, and going long
    in the T-bond futures contract.

126
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • Note
  • For many assets the costs of carrying the asset
    for a period of time exceeds the benefits.
  • As a result, the futures price on such assets
    exceeds the spot price prior to expiration and
    the basis (ft-St) on such assets is positive.

127
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • A market in which the futures price exceeds the
    spot price is referred to as a contango or normal
    market.
  • If the futures price is less then the spot price
    (a negative basis), the costs of carrying the
    asset is said to have a convenience yield in
    which the benefits from holding the asset exceed
    the costs.
  • A market in which the basis is negative is
    referred to as backwardation or an inverted
    market.
  • For futures on debt securities, an inverted
    market could occur if large coupon payments are
    to be paid during the period.

128
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • Note
  • The same arbitrage arguments governing the
    futures and spot price relation also can be
    extended to establish the equilibrium
    relationship between futures prices with
    different expirations.

129
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • Note
  • The futures price is related to an unknown
    expected spot price.
  • Several expectation theories have been advanced
    to explain the relationship between the futures
    and expected spot prices.

130
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • One of the first theories was broached by the
    famous British economists John Maynard Keynes and
    J.R. Hicks.
  • They argued that if a spot market were dominated
    by hedgers who, on balance, wanted a short
    forward position, then for the market to clear
    (supply to equal demand) the price of the futures
    contract would have to be less than the expected
    price on the spot commodity at expiration
    (E(ST)) f0 lt E(ST).
  • According to Keynes and Hicks, the difference
    between E(ST) and f0 represents a risk-premium
    that speculators in the market require in order
    to take a long futures position. Keynes and
    Hicks called this market situation normal
    backwardation.

131
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • C.O. Hardy argued for the case of f0 gt E(ST),
    even in a market of short hedgers.
  • His argument, though, is based on investor's risk
    behavior.
  • He maintained that since speculators were akin to
    gamblers, they were willing to pay for the
    opportunity to gamble (risk-loving behavior).
  • Thus, a gambler's fee, referred to as a contango
    or forwardation, would result in a negative risk
    premium.

132
Notes on Futures Pricing
  • Finally, there is a risk-neutral pricing
    argument.
  • In this argument, the futures price represents an
    unbiased estimator of the expected spot price (f0
    E(ST)) and, with risk-neutral pricing,
    investors purchasing an asset (bond) for S0 and
    expecting an asset value at T of E(ST) f0
    require an expected rate of return equal to the
    risk-free rate.
  • As a result, in a risk-neutral market, the
    futures price is equal to the expected spot
    price

133
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • When investors purchase and hold foreign
    securities or when corporations and governments
    sell debt securities in external markets or incur
    foreign debt positions, they are subject to
    exchange-rate risk.
  • As noted in Chapter 7, major banks provide
    exchange-rate protection by offering forward
    contracts to financial and non-financial
    corporations to hedge their international
    positions.
  • In addition to contracts offered in this
    interbank forward market, hedging exchange rate
    risk can also be done using foreign currency
    futures contracts listed on the Chicago
    Mercantile Exchange (CME), as well as a number of
    exchanges outside the U.S.

134
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • Short Hedging Case
  • Consider a U.S. fund that has a sizable
    investment in Eurobonds that will pay a principal
    in British pounds of 10M next September.
  • Suppose the current spot exchange rate is
    1.425/, making the dollar value of the
    principal worth 14.25M.
  • Suppose the fund is concerned that the /
    exchange rate could decrease by September,
    reducing the amount of dollars they would receive
    when they convert 10M.

135
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • To minimize its exchange-rate exposure, the fund
    could go short in an interbank forward contract
    in which it agrees to sell 10M at the September
    principal payment date at a specified forward
    exchange rate.
  • Alternatively, the fund could take a short
    position in a CME September futures contract.
  • Given the contract size on CMEs British pound
    contract of 62,500, the fund would need go short
    in 160 CME British pound contracts in order to
    hedge its 10M September receipt

nf 10,000,000/62,500 160
136
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • If the futures price on the September contract
    were equal to f0 1.425/, and the September
    principal payment occurred at the same time as
    the futures expiration, then the fund would be
    able realize a 14.25M cash inflow when it
    converted its 10M principal to dollars at the
    spot / exchange rate at the September principal
    payment date and closed its 160 British pound
    futures contracts at an expiring futures price
    equal to the spot exchange rate.

137
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • The hedge is illustrated in the exhibit on the
    next slide.
  • The exhibit shows the funds hedged revenue of
    14.25M at expiration from converting the 10M at
    spot exchange rates of 1.47/ and 1.39/ and
    from closing its 160 short futures contracts by
    going long at expiring futures prices equal to
    the different spot exchange rates.

138
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
139
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • Long Hedging Case
  • Consider the case of a U.S. corporation that has
    issued a Eurobond denominated in British pounds.
  • Suppose the company has to make a September
    principal payment in pounds of 5M and that the
    September CME British pound futures is trading at
    f0 1.425/ and expires at the same time the
    principal payment is due.

140
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
  • In this case, the U.S. company could hedge the
    dollar cost on its principal payment against
    exchange-rate changes by going long in 80
    September futures contracts
  • At expiration, the company would realize a hedged
    dollar cost of 7.125M when it purchased 5M at
    the spot exchange rate and closed its 80 long
    futures contracts at expiring futures prices
    equal to the spot exchange. This hedge is
    illustrated in the exhibit on the next slide.

nf 5,000,000/62,500 80
141
Hedging International Positions with Currency
Futures
142
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • The carrying cost model can be used to determine
    the equilibrium price of a currency forward or
    futures exchange rate.
  • In international finance, the carrying cost model
    governing the relationship between spot and
    forward exchange rates is referred to as the
    interest rate parity theorem (IRPT).
  • In terms of IRPT, the forward price of a currency
    or forward exchange rate (f0) is equal to the
    cost of carrying the spot currency (priced at the
    spot exchange rate of E0) for the contracts
    expiration period.

143
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • In terms of IRPT, the equilibrium forward price
    or exchange rate is
  • where
  • RUS U.S. risk-free rate
  • RF foreign risk-free rate

144
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • If the interest rate parity condition does not
    hold, an arbitrage opportunity will exist.
  • The arbitrage strategy to apply in such
    situations is known as covered interest arbitrage
    (CIA).

145
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • To illustrate, suppose the annualized U.S. and
    foreign interest rates are RUS 4 and RF 6,
    respectively, and the spot exchange rate is E0
    0.40/FC.
  • By IRPT, a one-year forward contract would be
    equal to 0.39245283/FC

146
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • If the actual forward rate, f0M, exceeds
    0.39245283/FC, an arbitrage profit would exist
    by
  • Borrowing dollars at RUS
  • Converting the dollar to FC at E0
  • Investing the fund in a foreign risk-free rate of
    RF
  • Entering a short forward contract to sell the FC
    at the end of the period at f0M

147
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • Example If f0M 0.40/FC, an arbitrageur could
  • Borrow 40,000 at RUS 4 creating a loan
    obligation at the end of the period of 41,600
    (40,000)(1.04).
  • Convert the dollars at the spot exchange rate of
    E0 0.40/FC to 100,000 FC (
    (2.5FC/)(40,000)).
  • Invest the 100,000 FC in the foreign risk-free
    security at RF 6 creating a return of
    principal and interest of 106,000 FC one year
    later.
  • Enter a forward contract to sell 106,000 FC at
    the end of the year at f0M 0.40/FC.

148
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • One year later, the arbitrageur would
  • receive 42,400 when she sells the 106,000 FC on
    the forward contract and
  • owe 41,600 on her debt obligation,
  • for an arbitrage return of 800.

149
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • Such risk-free profit opportunities, in turn,
    would lead arbitrageurs to try to implement the
    CIA strategy.
  • This would cause the price on the forward
    contract to fall until the riskless opportunity
    disappears. The zero arbitrage profit would
    occur when the interest rate parity condition is
    satisfied.

150
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • If the forward rate is below the equilibrium
    value, then the CIA is reversed. In the example,
    if f0M 0.38/FC, an arbitrageur could
  • Borrow 100,000 FC at RF 6 creating a 106,000
    FC debt.
  • Convert the 100,000FC at the spot exchange rate
    to 40,000.
  • Invest the 40,000 in the U.S. risk-free security
    at RUS 4.
  • Enter a forward contract to buy 106,000 FC at the
    end of the year at f0M 0.38/FC.

151
Pricing Currency Futures and Forward Exchange
Rates
  • At the end of the period, the arbitrageurs
    profit would be 1,320
  • As arbitrageurs attempt to implement this
    strategy, they will push up the price on the
    forward contract until the arbitrage profit is
    zero this occurs when the interest rate parity
    condition is satisfied.

40,000(1.04) (0.38/FC)(106,000) 1,320
152
Websites
  • For information on forward exchange rates go to
    www.fxstreet.com
  • For information on CME currency futures contracts
    go to www.cme.com and click on Delayed Quotes
    in Market Data, and then Currency Products.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com