Title: Game Theoretic Analysis in Supply Chains
1Game Theoretic Analysis in Supply Chains
- Yang Sun
- Dept. of Industrial Engineering
- Arizona State University
2Agenda
- Basic introduction to game theory
- Basic economic models (market games)
- Supply chain model Competitive newsvendors
- Capacity allocation game with non-competitive
buyers - Capacity allocation game with competitive buyers
3Game Theory
- Definition Game theory is a branch of applied
mathematics that studies interaction among a
group of rational agents who behave
strategically. - Key Concepts
- Group
- Interaction
- Strategic
- Rational
4A Brief Game Theory History
- Early works James Waldegraves, Antoine Augustin
Cournot, Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Emile Borel in
1700s and 1800s - 1928-1944 John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern
published a series of papers and was credited as
the fathers of modern game theory. Their work is
culminated in the 1944 book The Theory of Games
and Economic Behavior. - 1950 Discussion and experimentation on the
Prisoners dilemma at the RAND Corp. - 1950 John Nashs dissertation on non-cooperative
games - Advisor Albert W. Tucker
- Contained the definition and properties of an
optimum strategy that would later be called the
Nash Equilibrium. - Led to three important journal articles.
- 1950s Games of imperfect information (Kuhn
1953) cooperative games (Aumann 1959) game
theory experienced a flurry of activity including
its first applications in philosophy and
political science. - 1960s Reinhard Seltens work on subgame perfect
equilibria and John Harsanyis work on compete
information and Bayesian games. - 1970s and 1980s Works on evolutionary strategy
and its applications in biology correlated
equilibrium trembling hand equilibrium common
knowledge sequential equilibrium extensive
games repeated games extensive Bayesian games
a lot of applications. - 1994 Nash, Selten, and Harsanyi won the Nobel
prize in Economics. - 2005 Thomas Schelling (works on evolutionary
game theory) and Robert Aumann (works on common
knowledge) won the Nobel prize.
5Games and Strategies
- Static Game
- Dynamic Game
- Non-cooperative game
- Cooperative game
- Pure Strategies
- Mixed Strategies
- Two ways of formalizing a game
- The extensive form
- The normal form
- Players
- Strategies
- Payoffs
- (See examples)
6Examples
1
R
L
2
l
l
r
r
3 1
1 0
2 -1
2 0
Source Tirole, Jean, 1988, The Theory of
Industrial Organization, MIT Press
7Examples (contd)
P2
P1
P2
P1
Source Tirole, Jean, 1988, The Theory of
Industrial Organization, MIT Press
8The Prisoners Dilemma
- (D, D) is the dominant strategy equilibrium.
- Si is a dominant strategy if Ui(Si, S-i)
gtUi(Si, S-i) for all Si, S-i - i.e., the dominant strategy is independent of
others strategies. - A dominant equilibrium is a Nash equilibrium.
9Nash Equilibrium
- A strategy vector S(S1, S2,, Sn) is a Nash
Equilibrium if for all i, - Ui(Si, S-i) gtUi(Si, S-i) for all Si
- The concept was originally shown in the Cournot
duopoly game (we will talk about this later). - Nash showed for the first time in his
dissertation, Non-cooperative games (1950), that
Nash equilibria exist for finite games with any
number of players. Until Nash, this had only been
proved for 2-player zero-sum games by von Neumann
and Morgenstern (1944)
10Other Important Concepts
- Sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium
- Complete Information and Common Knowledge
- Mixed Strategy equilibrium
- Bayesian equilibrium
- Note that not all games have an equilibrium.
- Many games have multiple equilibria.
- Some games have equilibria that are not good.
11An Economic Example
- Consider a monopoly who is the only one in the
market that sells a particular product and there
is no viable substitute goods. - The price is set by market and is a function of
the total sales quantity - e.g. p D q, where D is a constant.
- The production cost is also a function of the
quantity. - e.g. C(q) cq, where c is a constant.
- The monopoly solves the following optimization
problem to determine the optimal sales quantity
that maximize his profit. - The first-order condition yields
12The Market Game
- Assume two firms selling the same product. There
are barriers to enter the market, so the two
firms form a duopoly (oligopoly). - The market price is a function of the total sales
quantity. - Payoffs (profits) to the two players are then
13Nash Equilibrium
- Nash Equilibrium is characterized by solving a
system of best responses that translates into the
system of first-order conditions - This is the classic Cournot duopoly model.
- Are the firms more profitable?
14Oligopoly Models
- Collusion Model
- Stackelberg Model
- Cournot Model
- N-Firm Nash Cournot
- N? 8 Perfect Competition
- Recommended Readings
- Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green, 2000,
Microeconomic Theory - Varian, 1992, Microeconomic Analysis
- Tirole, 1988, The Theory of Industrial
Organization - Osborne and Rubinstein, A Course in Game Theory
15A Supply Chain Example
- Consider the classic newsvendor model
- Each newsvendor buys Q units of a single product
at the beginning of a single selling season. - Demand during the season is a random variable D
with distribution function FD and density
function fD. - Each unit is purchased for c and sold on the
market for r gt c - In the absence of competition, each newsvendor
solves the following optimization problem - with the unique solution
16Competitive Newsvendors
- Assume two newsvendors selling the same product.
If retailer i is out of stock, all unsatisfied
customers will try to buy at retailer j instead
(competing on product availability). - Retailer is total demand is Di (Dj Qj).
Payoffs to the two players are then - First-order conditions are
- See Cachon and Netessine (2004) and Lippman and
McCardle (1997) for competitive newsvendors. - Cachon, G. and S. Netessine. 2004. Game theory in
Supply Chain Analysis. in Handbook of
Quantitative Supply Chain Analysis Modeling in
the eBusiness Era. edited by David Simchi-Levi,
S. David Wu and Zuo-Jun (Max) Shen. Kluwer. - Lippman, S. and K. McCardle. 1997. The
competitive newsboy. Operations Research. 45(1)
54-65
17Nash Equilibrium
- Nash Equilibrium is characterized by solving a
system of best responses that translates into the
system of first-order conditions - The slope of the best response functions are
negative, i.e., each players best response is
monotonically decreasing in the other players
strategy. (This makes intuitive sense)
18Nash Equilibrium (contd)
- The two best response functions form a best
response mapping R2?R2 (or in the more general
case Rn?Rn). One way to think about a Nash
Equilibrium is a fixed point on the best response
mapping R2?R2.
19Nash Equilibrium (contd)
- There exists at least one pure strategy Nash
Equilibrium under the following conditions - For each player the strategy space is compact and
convex and the payoff function is continuous and
quasi-concave with respect to each players own
strategy. - However, demonstrating uniqueness is generally
much harder than demonstrating existence of
equilibrium.
20The Allocation Game
- Consider a simple supply chain in which a single
supplier sells to several downstream buyers. - The buyers are local monopolies (e.g., retailers,
auto dealers of the same brand) that do not
compete with each other for customers. - The supplier has limited (and fixed) capacity and
sells the product at a fixed wholesale price. - If buyer orders exceed available capacity (demand
is high), the supplier needs to allocate his
restrictive capacity among buyers. - The allocation policy is publicly known
(announced). - How will the choice of allocation policy impact
buyer behavior and supply chain performance?
21Recommended readings
- Lee, H.L., V. Padmanabhan and S. Whang. 1997.
Information distortion in a supply chain the
Bullwhip effect. Management Science. 43(4)
546-558 - The allocation game is a major cause of the
Bullwhip Effect. - Cachon, G. and M. Lariviere. 1999a. Capacity
choice and allocation strategic behavior and
supply chain performance. Management Science.
45(8) 1091-1108 - Cachon, G. and M. Lariviere. 1999b. Capacity
allocation using past sales when to
turn-and-earn. Management Science, 45(5)
685-703. - Cachon, G. and M. Lariviere. 1999c. An
equilibrium analysis of linear and proportional
allocation of scarce capacity. IIE Transactions.
31(9) 835-850 - Semiconductor Manufacturing Case
- Mallik, S. and P.T. Harker. 2004. Coordinating
supply chains with competition capacity
allocation in semiconductor manufacturing.
European Journal of Operational Research. 159(2)
330-347 - Karabuk, S. and S. D. Wu. 2005. Incentive schemes
for semiconductor capacity allocation a game
theoretic analysis. Production and Operations
Management. 14(2) 175188.
22Uniform (fixed) allocation policy
- Under uniform (fixed) allocation, buyer i is
allocated - where K is the fixed capacity xi retailer is
order quantity. - Assume market price p D q (downward sloping
linear demand) - Independent of K, each buyer orders the local
monopoly quantity - It is straightforward to show that, under fixed
allocation, the unique Nash equilibrium has each
buyer selling minqi, K/2.
23Linear allocation
Further, assume that buyer i orders xil if he
faces low demand situation and xih if he faces
high demand situation. There are some cases in
which identifying pure strategy Nash equilibria
is simple. For example, if Kgt2xih, each buyer
could order xi and be assured of receiving xi. A
buyer could never do better, so this is a unique
Nash Equilibrium. If Kltxih, neither buyer facing
high demand is ever satisfied. To secured the
full capacity, each buyer will try to order K
more that the other buyer. Hence the game reduces
to who can name the largest number and
naturally there is no Nash equilibrium. If
Kltxil, the buyer facing low demand with the
smaller order always receives less than his order
quantity so always has an incentive to raise his
order, thereby destroying any possible
equilibrium. See Cachon and Lariviere (1999c)
for other cases.
24Proportional allocation
- ai(xi,xj) minxi, xi/(xixj)K
- As with linear allocation, there are some cases
that no equilibrium exists. Symmetric equilibria
are possible for some cases. See Cachon and
Lariviere (1999c) for details. - With any equilibrium under linear or proportional
allocation, the suppliers expected sales are
declining in her capacity. - The supply chain must balance two objectives (1)
increase the suppliers profit by increasing the
capacity utilization and (2) increase the
buyers profit by ensuring that the allotment
closely matches the buyers true needs. Uniform
allocation suppresses order inflation, so it
performs well for the 2nd goal, but may perform
poorly for the 1st goal. Inflation-inducting
allocation policies (linear or proportional)
perform the 1st goal well, and also the 2nd goal
reasonably well when the order inflation is
moderate and orderly, i.e., when there exists an
equilibrium.
25Prioritized allocation
- The Suppliers Decision
- Assume , it is straightforward to show
that
26Now assume that the buyers do compete for
customers (Cournot competition)
- Assume downward sloping linear demand
- The buyers decisions
- Nash Equilibrium
- The Nash equilibrium has buyer i selling
- and buyer j selling
- (Case 0)
27What if the suppliers capacity K is explicit
knowledge?
- Case 1 (loose supply)
- According to the previous slide, the NE has both
buyers selling their Cournot quantities. - Case 2 (tight supply)
- The dominant equilibrium has buyer i selling
- minK , (Dhi-ci)/2 and buyer j selling 0
- under prioritized allocation. (still assume
)
28The supply chain can be more profitable when
keeping K inexplicit
- Assume
- it can be shown that the supplier is better off
in Case 0 than in Case 2 ( ) if
the supply is tight. - In addition, if implies ,
- it can be shown that the Case 0 overall profit
- is greater than the Case 2
- overall profit
- while
29Multi-period model
- Regular allocation mechanisms.
- Allocation using past sales
- The supplier reserves some capacity for the buyer
who was the sales leader in the previous period. - See Cachon and Lariviere (1999b) for details.
- Case A Period 1 Demand Low Period 2 Demand High
- Is it beneficial for the buyers to carry
inventory over the first period? - Case B Period 1 Demand Low Period 2 Demand Low
- Is it beneficial for the buyers to allow
backorders in the first period?
30Another ExampleTwo-Period Allocation, Case A
- Buyers second-period decisions are
Buyers optimal stock level are
given that the first-period allotment is
sufficient to cover s and her first-period sales
quantity.
Further, it can be shown that the marginal
increase in profit from increasing sales in the
second period is greater than the marginal cost
of holding inventory and buyer i would like to
stock a sufficient amount in the first period to
increase second-period sales under the following
condition
31If uniform allocation is used
- In period k, buyer i is allocated
- minxki , K/2(K/2 xkj)
- Suppose q1isi(K/2) gt K/2 (very tight supply),
- the supplier will sell K in each period, and
buyer i will sell min(2K-(D2-D1)hi)/4 ,K/2 in
the first period. Sales can be sacrificed in the
first period so that inventory can be carried
into the second period, in which the marginal
value of selling a unity is higher, since in the
second period neither buyer has an advantage of
receiving more that K/2 units under an uniform
allocation mechanism. - Suppose q2igtK/2gtq1isi(K/2), (moderately tight
supply) - buyer i will order q1isi(K/2) in the first
period and sell K/2si(K/2) in the second period.
Some of the suppliers capacity might be left
idle in the first period. The uniform allocation
may harm the suppliers profitability since it
will not induce over-ordering from the buyers.
32Conclusion
- Game theoretic models are descriptive models that
study strategic behaviors of players in a game
setting. - In the capacity allocation game, it is important
for the supplier to choose an appropriate
allocation mechanism/policy that increases not
only her capacity utilization but also the supply
chain profitability and to derive conditions
under which the policy performs well.