Title: GEOG 3404 Economic Geography
1GEOG 3404Economic Geography
LECTURE 2 Agriculture, Scarcity and Economic Rent
- Dr. Zachary Klaas
- Department of Geography and Environmental Studies
- Carleton University
2Land and natural resources
- A critical question in economic geography, which
must be understood before one even begins
Where do things of economic value come from? - All material or tangible items (that is, items
that are not ideas with no material form) come
from nature. - Natural resources are those elements which are
taken from or exist on the planet in their raw
form. - Synthetic products, if they are tangible, always
contain a mixture of elements taken in their raw
form from nature. - The capacity to make products, in short, depends
upon having some measure of control over natural
resources used to make them either direct
control or influence over those who have that
direct control.
3Conceptualising land
- Land can be the soil earth which has value as
the location where agricultural products are
grown. - Land can be ground earth which has value as the
location where buildings or constructions are
physically possible. - Land can be a site earth which has value as the
location for economic activities. - Land can be a milieu earth which has value
because of its impacts (environmental, social,
etc.) on other areas. - Land can be conceived of as the natural resources
themselves not just the earth but all products
which come in their raw form from nature. By
this last definition, land has value as the
substance from which, ultimately, all economic
products are made.
4Agriculture the primary sector of the economy
- The first stage of economic development is
undeniably the agriculturalisation of societies. - The Neolithic Revolution saw the rise of
subsistence agriculture, which allowed
settlements to be rooted in one location. After
agriculture became efficient enough to produce
more than mere subsistence, these settlements
became the geographic bases for urbanised
communties to serve as central agricultural
marketplaces. - Agricultural products would soon be supplemented
as the primary products of marketplaces by
manufactured goods (at first primitively
manufactured) and services (at first primitive
services), but agriculture importantly served as
the base upon which these other elements of the
economy depended.
5Land ownership as social power
- Given the historical importance of
agriculture/land/the natural resource base, we
have a lingering conception of economic power
being secured by land ownership. Phrases like
having a piece of the rock persist in the
language, denoting the assumptions of many in
past generation that direct ownership of land is
vital to ones economic health. (Think of the
grandfather in The Apprenticeship of Duddy
Kravitz by Mordecai Richler A man without land
is nothing, Duddy, remember that.) - Is this true today? Or has something supplanted
it in importance today? Now do we think of
capital ownership as more important? What about
home ownership? Do we think of that the way
people once thought about primarily about their
farms?
6Agricultural republicans
- In the 17th and 18th Centuries, a political
philosophy centred around the importance of free
access to land, called agricultural
republicanism grew in popularity. - The central contention of the agricultural
republicans is that elites held power over
so-called common people primarily because they
held control over land, understood in this
context as the natural resource base of the
planet. So long as this was the case, those
elites would be always able to dominate those
commoners, on the basis of the scarcity of any
other available natural resources. - Political philosophers such as James Harrington,
John Locke, Thomas Jefferson, Thomas Paine and
John Taylor of Caroline were prominent defenders
of this viewpoint. Political independence, in
large measure, was for these persons bound up in
the freedom to own land.
7Homesteading and the New World
- In the New World of the Americas of the 18th
and 19th Centuries, the availability of land
afforded an opportunity to distribute social
power more widely than it was in the Old World,
where control over land was held by the landed
gentry. (Think of the movie Far and Away,
where the main character leaves the service of an
Irish landlord, a member of the landed gentry,
for the opportunity to own land himself in
Oklahoma.) - Homesteading was the free distribution of plots
of land in the New World and a centrepiece of
the agricultural republican ethic of greater
distribution of political power by means of wider
distribution of land.
8Land office business in the New World
- In Canada, distribution of land was more
controlled. The initial idea of the imperial
government was to create a version of a landed
gentry in Canada, and those who controlled land
offices, the agencies responsible for the
distribution of plots of land, essentially saw
their role as the shaping of a Canadian nobility,
defined through land ownership. - Elite groups in Ontario (the family compact)
and Quebec (the Château clique) were defined in
large measure through their control of land
offices. - Interestingly, even today, a formal requirement
of membership in the Senate of Canada is the
formal ownership of land.
9Scarcity of natural resources as a theme in
political economy
- If we lived in a world of overflowing natural
resources, where every person could have
unlimited claims to natures bounty, then there
would be no such thing as scarcity. - If there were no such thing as scarcity, however,
there would probably also be no such thing as
money or even barter transactions, as people
would be able to take directly from nature
everything that they need, and would need no
monetary system to facilitate transactions they
dont need to undertake in the first place. - It is, in fact, the scarcity of natural
resources, to various degrees, in the world that
makes us need to have economic transactions in
the first place. Things become economically
valuable because they are not found in abundance.
10David Ricardos observations about land
- The 19th Century British political economist
David Ricardo noted that profit on land (if we
understand that term to refer to the natural
resources generally) can either be off the use of
the land or off its mere value in exchange. - A landowner could, for example, raise crops and
sell them, and thus profit off the sales. This
would be an example of the use value of the land,
and it would also be an example of putting the
land to productive use. - The landowner could also, however, keep his land
unproductive until such point as the land could
be sold to someone else. This is an example of
the exchange value of the land. Ricardo noted
that no one would buy land when land of equal
quality was available in nature for free, so the
landowner in this case is profiting not off
productive use of the land, but rather off of the
scarcity of available land of equal quality.
11Henry George and his single tax idea
- So scarcity in nature is, by this argument,
essentially what gives everything value in an
economy. Thus, it would seem to be an inherent
relationship that those who control scarce
natural resources would control the economy. - This is essentially the viewpoint of the 19th
Century political economist Henry George, who
wrote the book Progress and Poverty. - George was of the view that landowners, by virtue
of their control of land, were elite figures who
unjustly controlled the economy through control
of scarce resources. His solution to this
problem was to tax the value of land (understood
as the value of all natural resources) and fairly
redistribute this money to non-landowners. This
proposal was called the single tax.
12The unearned increment
- The idea behind Georges proposal was to tax that
which is unearned in the profit of those who
hold control over natural resources, the part of
that profit which he referred to as the unearned
increment. - George had no problem with land having use value,
and this part of lands value he was unwilling to
tax. He was content to allow labour to be
properly rewarded for working the land, as well
as capitalists to be rewarded for investing in
the lands productive capacity. But he opposed
rewarding landowners simply for holding the title
to the land, even if they did nothing to make it
productive and serve peoples economic needs. In
other words, he wanted to put his tax on the
exchange value of the land.
13The value of land use The von Thünen model
- Being the basis of the first stage in the
economic development of most societies, the
agricultural sector was the first sector to be
effectively studied by economic geographers. - The mathematical model of the German economic
geographyer Johann Heinrich von Thünen in the
early 19th Century was one of the first attempts
to rationally explain what gives particular
tracts of land economic value. - The von Thünen model is a deductive model, which
means it abstracts from the facts of the real
world to provide an idealised, logical and
theorised version of how things work. - It proceeds from knowledge of certain elements as
premises of reality, and assumptions that one
does not need to know additional elements, to
reason to a conclusion.
14Prediction of economic rent
- Economic rent is what von Thünen called the value
of land for a given land use purpose. Since he
was an agricultural economic geographer, he was
interested in predicting this value for land used
to grow particular agricultural crops. He wanted
to know which lands should be used for which
crops, and the purpose of his model is to
determine which crop, if grown on the land, would
generate the highest economic rent (value) for
that land. - To that end, von Thünen designed a predictive
equation. The equation calculated a value for
economic rent (R), which was derived in the
equation from a number of other variables, as
well as from the distance to the central
marketplace where the crops were to be sold (k).
15The von Thünen equation
- The equation itself R E ( p a ) Efk
- The elements of the equation
- R is the economic rent to be predictedE is
the output of the land (in units of output) - p is the market price of the units
- a is the production cost of the units
- f is the cost of freight for each unit and
over each - unit of distance and
- k is the distance from the central marketplace
in - units of distance.
16Assumptions of the model
- Since von Thünen was reasoning about the world
deductively, attempting to predict the world from
rational principles rather than constantly
observing the real world and experientially
arriving, inductively, at conclusions about it,
there are certain things he had to assume about
reality. - Assumptions are part of any deductive model of
reality these models only work under certain
constraints, and when those constraints are
violated, the results of the predictive model
will not hold. - In the case of the von Thünen model, the main
assumption one must make is that one is
predicting results for a surface uninterrupted by
complicating geographic obstacles. For example,
the value of the top of a mountain for farming
will probably be low. Yet nowhere in the von
Thünen model is elevation taken into account.
This is an element which is beyond the scope of
the model, and must be assumed away.
17The Isolated State
- For this reason, von Thünen had to imagine an
idealised isolated state to exist, in which
there were no complicated geographic obstacles
(e.g., rivers, mountain ranges) or uneven
conditions (some land far less suitable for
farming than others). - So important was this part of his reasoning, in
fact, that the book in which he presented his
model was in fact entitled Der isolierte Staat
(German for the isolated state). - Where conditions more clearly approach von
Thünens hypothetical isolated state, his
equation tends to predict very well. Where, by
contrast, the landscape is broken or interrupted
by geographic obstacles, the model tends to lose
its predictive power. - The model is highly regarded, however, because in
general, its assumptions are not often violated,
and where they are, additional compensating terms
could be introduced into the equation.