Title: SURVEY OF ECONOMIC THEORY
1SURVEY OF ECONOMIC THEORY
Microsoft
2SURVEY OF ECONOMIC ANALYSIS
VOLUNTARY EXCHANGE AT THE RUDIMENTARY LEVEL
Microsoft
3Quote from Adam Smith
4Basis of Free Exchange
- THIS division of labour, from which so many
advantages are derived, is not originally the
effect of any human wisdom, which foresees and
intends that general opulence to which it gives
occasion. It is the necessary, though very slow
and gradual consequence of a certain propensity
in human nature which has in view no such
extensive utility the propensity to truck,
barter, and exchange one thing for another.
5- Whether this propensity be one of those original
principles in human nature of which no further
account can be given or whether, as seems more
probable, it be the necessary consequence of the
faculties of reason and speech, it belongs not to
our present subject to inquire. - It is common to all people, and to be found in no
other race of animals, which seem to know neither
this nor any other species of contracts. - Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith
6GAIN FROM TRADE OR EXCHANGE
- TRULY VOLUNTARY TRADE OR EXCHANGE BENEFITS
EVERYONE INVOLVED. - IN THE EXCHANGE PROCESS , PEOPLE REVEAL THEIR
TRUE PREFERENCES BY WHAT THEY DO -- AN ACTION --
NOT BY WHAT THEY SAY. - Consumer Surplus difference between the price a
consumer is willing to pay for a good or service
and what she/he actually pays for it. - Supplier Surplus difference between what a
supplier (producer) would sell a good or service
for and what he/she actually sells it for.
7- Each person driven by incentives results in
benefits to all. - Organizing force of exchange process. The
exchange process is the organizing force. - Invisible hand operates through the exchange
process. - Results in the efficient use of resources
8(No Transcript)
9- Imagine that there are two goods in the world-
meat and potatoes. And that there are two people
in the world a cattle rancher and a farmer each
of whom would like to eat meat and potatoes. - The gains from trade are most obvious if the
rancher can produce only meat and the farmer can
produce only potatoes. - In one scenario, the rancher and the farmer could
choose to have nothing to do with each other in
which case the rancher would eat only meat and
the farmer would eat only potatoes.
10- Suppose more realistically that the potato farmer
is able to raise cattle and produce meat but that
he is not very good at it. Further suppose that
the rancher can produce potatoes but not very
productively. In this situation there is
obviously an incentive for exchange. - Exchange can take place even if one party is
better at producing both goods. - This is the basis of the law of comparative
advantage.
11Production Possibilities
12- Suppose that the farmer and the rancher each work
40 hours a week and can the devote this time to
growing potatoes, raising cattle, or a
combination of the two. - The amount of time each person requires to
produce one pound of each good is shown in the
table on the next slide.
13Production Possibilities
14Farmer has 40 hours
20 hours to produce 1 lb of meat
10 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
2 lbs of meat in 40 hours
4lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
15Farmer has 40 hours
20 hours to produce 1 lb of meat
10 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
2 lbs of meat in 40 hours
4lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
16Farmer has 40 hours
20 hours to produce 1 lb of meat
10 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
2 lbs of meat in 40 hours
4lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
Rancher has 40 hours
1 hour to produce 1 lb of meat
8 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
5lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
40 lbs of meat in 40 hours
17Farmer has 40 hours
20 hours to produce 1 lb of meat
10 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
2 lbs of meat in 40 hours
4lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
Rancher has 40 hours
1 hour to produce 1 lb of meat
8 hours to produce 1 lb of potatoes
5lbs of potatoes In 40 hours
40 lbs of meat in 40 hours
18Production Possibilities Functions of the Farmer
and the Rancher
19Farmers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
2
A
1
0
2
4
Potatoes lbs
20Farmers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
2
A
1
0
2
4
Potatoes lbs
21Ranchers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
40
B
20
0
2.5
5
Potatoes lbs
22Ranchers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
40
B
20
2.5
0
5
Potatoes lbs
23 In the first diagram if the farmer devotes all
40 hours of his time to producing potatoes then
he can produce 4 lbs. of potatoes and no meat. If
he devotes all his time to producing meat he
produces 2 lbs. of meat and no potatoes. If the
farmer divides his time equally between the two
activities, spending 20 hours on each, he
produces 2 lbs. of potatoes and 1 lb. and of
meat. In the second diagram if the rancher
devotes all 40 hours of her time to producing
potatoes she can produce 5 lbs. of potatoes and
no meat. If she devotes all of her time to meat,
she can produce 40 lbs. of meat and no potatoes.
If the rancher divides her time equally, spending
20 hours on each activity, she produces 2.5 lbs.
of potatoes and 20 lbs. of meat. If the farmer
and the rancher chose to be self-sufficient,
rather than trade with each other, then each
consumes exactly what he or she produces. In
this case, The production possibilities frontier
is also the consumption possibilities frontier.
24Specialization and Trade
- Consider this conversation between the farmer and
the rancher. - Rancher
25Specialization and Trade
- Consider this conversation between the farmer and
the rancher. - Rancher farmer my friend have I got a deal for
you. I know how to improve life for both of us. - I think you should stop producing meat
altogether and devote all your time to producing
potatoes.According to my calculations, if you
devote 40 hours a week growing potatoes you will
produce 4 lbs. potatoes.
26- If you give me 1 pounds of those 4 lbs., I will
give you 3 lbs. of meat in return. In the end,
you will get to eat 3 lbs. of potatoes and 3 lbs.
of meat every week, instead of the 2 lbs of
potatoes and 1 lb of meat you now get. If you go
along with my plan you will have more of both
foods. - Farmer
27- If you give me 1 pounds of those 4 lbs., I will
give you 3 lbs. of meat in return. In the end,
you will get to eat 3 lbs. of potatoes and 3 lbs.
of meat every week, instead of the 2 lbs of
potatoes and 1 lb of meat you now get. If you go
along with my plan you will have more of both
foods. - Farmer That seems like a good deal to me. But I
dont understand why youre offering it. If the
deal is so good for me, it cant be good for you
too. Can it?
28 29- Rancher If I spend 24 hours a week raising
cattle and 16 hours growing potatoes, I will
produce 24 lbs. of meat and 2 lbs of potatoes.
After I give you 3 lbs. of meat in exchange for 1
lb of potatoes, I will have 21 lbs of meat and 3
lbs. of potatoes. In the end, I will also get
more of both foods than I have now. - Farmer
30- Rancher If I spend 24 hours a week raising
cattle and 16 hours growing potatoes, I will
produce 24 lbs. of meat and 2 lbs of potatoes.
After I give you 3 lbs. of meat in exchange for 1
lb of potatoes, I will have 21 lbs of meat and 3
lbs. of potatoes. In the end, I will also get
more of both foods than I have now. - Farmer I dont know. This sounds too good to
be true. - The following diagrams illustrate the production
possibilities and consumption possibilities.
31Farmers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
Farmers consumption with trade A point on the
consumption possibilities curve
A
3
2
Farmers consumption without trade
A
1
3
2
4
Potatoes lbs
32Ranchers Production Possibilities Frontier
Meat lbs
40
Ranchers consumption with trade A point on the
consumption possibilities curve
B
21
20
B
Ranchers consumption without trade
2.5
5
3
Potatoes lbs
33Absolute Advantage
- Economist use the term absolute advantage when
comparing the productivity one person, firm, or
nation to that of another. The producer that
requires a smaller quantity of inputs to produce
a good is said to have an absolute managing
producing that good.
34Absolute Advantage
Meat lbs
40
Rancher
2
Farmer
4
5
Potatoes lbs
35Opportunity Cost and Comparative Advantage
- Economist use the term comparative advantage when
describing the opportunity costs of two
producers. - The producer who has the smaller opportunity cost
of producing a good is said to have a comparative
advantage in producing that good. -
36- In our example, the farmer has a lower
opportunity cost of producing potatoes than the
rancher ( 0.5 lbs. versus 8 lbs. of meat). The
rancher has a lower opportunity cost of producing
meat than the farmer ( 1/8 lbs. versus 2 lbs. of
potatoes). Thus the farmer has a comparative
advantage in growing potatoes, and the rancher
has a comparative advantage in producing meat. - The table in the next slide illustrates the
opportunity cost.
37Opportunity Cost
38Opportunity Cost
Potatoes are Relatively Cheap
Meat is Relatively Cheap
39- "What is prudence in the conduct of every
private family, can scarce be folly in that of a
great kingdom. If a foreign country can supply
us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can
make it, better buy it of them with some part of
the produce of our own industry, employed in a
way in which we have some advantage. The general
industry of the country, being always in
proportion to the capital which employs it, will
not therby be diminished... but only left to find
out the way in which it can be employed with the
greatest advantage. - (Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, Book IV2,
Modern Library edition)
40LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
- Individuals and countries tend to specialize in
producing those goods in which they are
relatively, not absolutely, more efficient. - Trade can benefit everyone in society because it
allows people to specialize in activities in
which they have a comparative.
41Advantages and Disadvantages of Specialization
42Adam Smiths Pin Factory
- To take an example, therefore, from a very
trifling manufacture but one in which the
division of labour has been very often taken
notice of, the trade of the pin-maker a person
not educated to this business (which the division
of labour has rendered a distinct trade), nor
acquainted with the use of the machinery employed
in it (to the invention of which the same
division of labour has probably given occasion),
could scarce, perhaps, with his utmost industry,
make one pin in a day, and certainly could not
make twenty. But in the way in which this
business is now carried on, not only the whole
work is a peculiar trade, but it is divided into
a number of branches, of which the greater part
are likewise peculiar trades. One person draws
out the wire, another straights it, a third cuts
it, a fourth points it, a fifth grinds it at the
top for receiving, the head to make the head
requires two or three distinct operations to put
it on is a peculiar business, to whiten the pins
is another it is even a trade by itself to put
them into the paper and the important business
of making a pin is, in this manner, divided into
about
43- eighteen distinct operations, which, in some
manufactories, are all performed by distinct
hands, though in others the same person will
sometimes perform two or three of them. I have
seen a small manufactory of this kind where ten
people only were employed, and where some of them
consequently performed two or three distinct
operations. But though they were very poor, and
therefore but indifferently accommodated with the
necessary machinery, they could, when they
exerted themselves, make among them about twelve
pounds of pins in a day. There are in a pound
upwards of four thousand pins of a middling size.
Those ten persons, therefore, could make among
them upwards of forty-eight thousand pins in a
day. Each person, therefore, making a tenth part
of forty-eight thousand pins, might be considered
as making four thousand eight hundred pins in a
day. But if they had all wrought separately and
independently, and without any of them having
been educated to this peculiar business, they
certainly could not each of them have made
twenty, perhaps not one pin in a day that is,
certainly, not the two hundred and fortieth,
perhaps not the four thousand eight hundredth
part of what they are at present capable of
performing, in consequence of a proper division
and combination of their different operations.
44WHY SPECIALIZATION INCREASES PRODUCTIVITY
- Avoids time wasted in switching between tasks in
the production process. - Repetition improves worker skills --worker
productivity. - Creates a fertile environment for inventions.
45LIMITS OF SPECIALIZATION
- Specialization is limited by the extent of the
market. - Repetition may lead to bored/unproductive workers
- Cross-fertilization between different jobs may
result in new ideas and innovations. - Specialization in a high-technology society can
be risky for individual workers Life-long
learning concept.
46Issues About Efficiency and Equity of the
Exchange Process
- Asymmetrical information
- Distribution of gains from an exchange
- Interference with the exchange process and gain
from trade
47COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE ANOTHER EXAMPLE
48COMPARATIVE COST OF PRODUCING COMPUTERS AND WHEAT
- U.S.
JAPAN - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR 1 COMPUTERS 100
120 - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR 1 UNIT WHEAT 5
8 - RELATIVE TIME TO
- PRODUCE A COMPUTER (100/5) 20x
(120/8) 15x
49COMPARATIVE COST OF PRODUCING COMPUTERS AND WHEAT
- U.S.
JAPAN - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR COMPUTERS 100
120 - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR WHEAT
5 8 - RELATIVE TIME TO
- PRODUCE A COMPUTER (100/5) 20x
(120/8) 15x
WHEAT PRICE OF A COMPUTER IN U.S.
50COMPARATIVE COST OF PRODUCING COMPUTERS AND WHEAT
- U.S.
JAPAN - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR COMPUTERS 100
120 - LABOR REQUIRED
- FOR WHEAT
5 8 - RELATIVE TIME TO
- PRODUCE A COMPUTER (100/5) 20x
(120/8) 15x
WHEAT PRICE OF A COMPUTER IN U.S.
WHEAT PRICE OF A COMPUTER IN JAPAN
51EXAMPLE ASSUME A TOTAL OF 240,000 HOURS TO
PRODUCE COMPUTERS AND WHEAT FOR BOTH COUNTRIES
- U.S.
JAPAN - LABOR TO LABOR TO LABOR TO
LABOR TO - WHEAT COMPUTERS WHEAT
COMPUTERS - 120,000 120,000
120,000 120,000 - (24,000) (1200)
(15,000) (1000)
COMBINED OUTPUT WHEAT
39,000 COMPUTERS 2,200
52EXAMPLE ASSUME A TOTAL OF 240,000 HOURS TO
PRODUCE COMPUTERS AND WHEAT FOR BOTH COUNTRIES
- U.S.
JAPAN - LABOR TO LABOR TO LABOR TO
LABOR TO - WHEAT COMPUTERS WHEAT
COMPUTERS - 200,000 40,000
20,000 220,000 - (40,000) (400)
(2500) (1833)
COMBINED OUTPUT WHEAT
42,500 COMPUTERS 2233
53DIAGRAMMATIC PRESENTATION
United States
Japan
WHEAT
WHEAT
48
30
15
40
2.5
24
1200
1833
400
2400
2000
1000
COMPUTERS
COMPUTERS
54DIAGRAMMATIC PRESENTATION
SLOPE ??WHEAT /?? COMPUTER
-16,000 / 800 -20x
80,000 LABOR HOURS
WHEAT
WHEAT
48
30
15
40
2.5
24
1200
1833
400
2400
2000
1000
COMPUTERS
COMPUTERS
55DIAGRAMMATIC PRESENTATION
SLOPE ??WHEAT /?? COMPUTER
-12,500 / 833 -15x
WHEAT
WHEAT
48
30
15
40
2.5
24
1200
1833
400
2400
2000
1000
COMPUTERS
COMPUTERS
56WHAT DETERMINES COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
- Natural endowments --geographical determination
- Acquired endowments
- Higher savings rates
- Devoting resources to
- Education
- Capital accumulation
- Superior knowledge
- Specialization
57PERCEIVED COSTS OF INTERNATIONAL INTERDEPENDENCES
- Loss of domestic jobs
- Vulnerability
- Unfair trade -- dumping / monopoly
- Indebtness -- interest burden
- Weak countries hurt trade
58Example from the History of Economic Thought
59David Ricardo on Comparative Advantage
60- David Ricardo, working in the early part of the
19th century, realized that absolute advantage
was a limited case of a more general theory. He
considered the following example. It can be seen
that Portugal can produce both wheat and wine
more cheaply than England (i.e., it has an
absolute advantage in both commodities). What
David Ricardo saw was that it could still be
mutually beneficial for both countries to
specialize and trade.