Title: Netspar basic sheets
1Saving and investing over the life cycle and the
role of collective pension funds
Lans Bovenberg, Ralph Koijen, Theo Nijman and
Coen Teulings June 2007
2Trend to individual arrangements
- Trend in many countries towards individual
pension products rather than collective
arrangements - Main drivers
- Transparency (costs, risks, property rights)
- Underfunding of collective schemes
- Tailor-made pension solutions
- International Accounting Standards firm no
longer residual risk taker - Desire to take savings and investment decisions
(?)
3Traditional collective DB
- The distinction between individual and collective
is often seen as a synonym for DC versus DB and
the choice between them often seems also 0/1. - Traditional collective DB
- No risk taking by individual
- Pension contributions uniform and imposed
collectively - Asset allocation uniform and imposed collectively
- Forced participation in sector / firm specific
fund - Purchasing power guarantee on pension
entitlements (deferred real annuities imposed) - Crucial role trustees in governance
4Traditional individual DC
- Traditional individual DC usually
- Risk taking by individual
- No risk taking by sponsor
- Savings decisions taken by individual
- Investment decision taken by individual
- Freedom to choose pension provider
- No forced (deferred) annuities
- No pre-set defaults, automatic enrollment etc.
5The Dutch hybrid model
- In the Netherlands hybrid collective schemes have
developed which contain elements of the
traditional DB and DC setting - No (or less) risk taking by sponsor
- Risk taking by individual
- Nominal guarantee on entitlement
- Indexation of nominal guarantee depends on
coverage ratio of the fund - Uniform savings decisions (pension contribution)
collectively imposed - Uniform investment decision collectively imposed
- Industry / firm specific pension funds
- Deferred annuities imposed
- Stringent supervision to combat underfunding
6Potential advantages hybrid collective model over
individual DC
- More cost efficient (30 bp)
- Avoids behavioral biases, professional decision
makers - Enables borrowing against human capital
- Completes markets (longevity risk and (wage)
inflation risk traded within fund) - Potential for risk sharing with non-overlapping
generations (intergenerational solidarity)
7Disadvantages hybrid collective model over
individual DC
- Asset allocation of financial capital independent
of age - Workhorse model suggests substantial risk taking
in financial capital for the young (target date
or life cycle funds) - No optimal consumption smoothing of shocks in
contribution levels - Uniform over individual characteristics
- Differences in life expectancy socioeconomic
groups - Differences in accumulated pension benefits
- Differences in risk aversion etc.
- Property rights and exposures often not well
defined or transparent
8Aim of this paper
- Panel / survey paper for Netspar participants and
researchers - Detailed analysis of saving and investing in the
work horse life cycle model (Merton, Bodie and
Samuelson) - Numerical results on welfare effects of
individual and collective schemes in this work
horse model - Survey of extensions of the basic model in the
recent literature
9Saving and investing over the life cycle in the
basic model
10Basic model
- Individuals work for T years and spend D-T years
in retirement - Constant exogenous riskless labor income
- Single risky investment opportunity the stock
market - Stock returns are i.i.d. normal
- No other financial assets than pension contract
- Smooth time separable CRRA utility with
exponential discounting - No bequest motive
11Benchmark parameters
- Rate of time preference 2
- Risk aversion 5
- Risk free rate 2
- Equity premium 4
- Volatility stock market 20
- Working life (T) 45 yrs
- Retirement (D-T) 15 yrs
-
12First best individual contract
- Contribution dependent on age and past returns
- Asset allocation of over-all wealth constant
- f expected excess return / (risk aversion
variance) - Asset allocation of financial wealth dependent on
age and past returns ft f (1 Ht / Ft) where
- Ht reflects human capital
- Ft reflects financial capital
- Expected asset allocation resembles investment in
life cycle fund
13Financial, human and total wealth without access
to stock market
14Expected asset allocation financial wealth
Expected share of financial wealth invested in
risky assets
15Asset allocation financial wealth
Expectation, 10 and 90 quantiles and two
simulated scenario paths of the share of
financial wealth invested in risky assets
16Optimal consumption path (contribution level)
Trajectories of the consumption paths of
individuals entering at respectively time t1 and
t 31. Shocks in the asset price are absent
except at time t20 and t40, when a negative
shock is imposed.
17Distribution of future consumption
Expectation, 10 and 90 quantiles and two
simulated scenario paths of the consumption path
over the life cycle
18Characteristics of first best contract without
intergenerational risk sharing
- Expected asset allocation resembles investment in
life cycle fund - Actual asset allocation initially quite volatile
- Initial pension contribution is low (7 versus
15 in case without risk taking) - Pension contribution quite volatile which reduces
the welfare gain
19Welfare loss of sub-optimal contracts
- Measure of welfare loss
- Annual change in consumption in reference
contract that generates same welfare level as
contract considered - Reference contract First best contract without
intergenerational solidarity - No use of equity exposure at all -8.5
- Risk aversion level of 3 imposed -5.0
- Implementation cost of 0.3 -1.2
- Implementation cost of 1.0 -4.0
- Fixed asset allocation -5.3
- Fixed contribution rate -6.6
20Welfare loss of sub-optimal contracts
- Specific strategies with constant savings rate
and asset allocation, relative to optimal
strategy with constant rates and exposure
- Optimal constant policy r.t. to first best
without intergenerational risk sharing -7.0
21Borrowing constraints
22Borrowing constraints
- The first best solution assumes that individual
can take unrestricted equity exposure - If returns get negative their human capital is to
be used as collateral for their debt. - Adverse selection and moral hazard make it hard
for financial institutions to ensure that loans
will be paid back Junior cannot borrow,
Constantinides et al (QJE, 2002) - The use of derivatives and / or mortgages can
mitigate the problem for the individual, but
requires very sophisticated strategies.
23Expected equity exposure optimal borrowing
constrained contract
Expected optimal equity share in financial wealth
over the life cycle in the presence of a
borrowing constraint
24Welfare analysis second best individual contract
- First best contract cannot be implemented by
individuals - No borrowing against future human capital
- Often no equity exposure joint with annuities
after retirement - Behavioral biases
- Welfare effects ignoring behavioral biases
- Joint effect is utility loss of 3.6 for
benchmark model. - With implementation costs of 0.3 (1.0) the
welfare loss increases to 4.6 (7.0)
25Risk sharing with non-overlapping generations
26Intergenerational solidarity
- Additional risk sharing is possible if trade is
possible with non-overlapping generations - This can not be contracted on financial markets
buffers (and deficits) of collective pension
schemes aim to achieve this - Welfare gain of 6.2 due to intergenerational
risk sharing in optimal (age dependent) contracts
if agent participates fully in investment risk 15
years before entry to labor market - The argument assumes that negative buffers will
not be avoided - Probability of negative buffer is 35
- Probability that buffer exceeds two working years
is 28.
27Intergenerational solidarity II
- Mandatory participation in sector or firm
specific pension funds is often put forward as an
instrument to make sure that collective pension
deficits can not be avoided - But
- Workers can leave firm / sector or reduce labor
supply - Firm / sector can default
- Derivative structures (not unlike solvency
requirements as in FTK and Solvency II) can be
imposed to reduce potential size of deficit and
retain some welfare gain of trade between
non-overlapping generations
28Welfare gains of intergenerational risk sharing
with capped deficits
- Strategies that benefit from intergenerational
risk sharing but reduce the probability of
substantial negative buffers on entry to the
labor market using (synthetic) put options
29Welfare analysis of stylized collective schemes
30Stylized collective schemes
- The collective schemes considered so far have age
and wealth dependent contribution rates and asset
allocations. - We now consider DC, DB and hybrid schemes that
impose uniform asset allocation and contribution
rates - The premium and benefit level consist of a base
level (?b and bb) as well as adjustment levels
towards recovery (?ta and bta) - ?t ?b ?ta bt bb bta
- ?ta ??1 (1 ft) ? bta ??1 (1 ft)
- The asset allocation is also dependent on the
coverage ratio ft of the fund xt ?0 ?1(1
ft)
31Stylized collective schemes
- Model
- ?t ?b ?ta bt bb bta
- ?ta ??1 (1 ft) ? bta ??1 (1 ft)
- xt ?0 ?1(1 ft)
- Note that ??1 gt 0 and ??1 lt 0.
- A (collective) DB scheme is obtained if ??1 0.
- Likewise a (collective) DC scheme is obtained if
??1 0. - A hybrid scheme is obtained if ?1 gt 0 and ??1 lt
0. - Hybrid schemes smooth shocks over active life and
retirement, and allow for intergenerational risk
sharing - Parameters are optimized subject to a constraint
on the half life of shocks in buffer
32Optimal parameters and welfare effects collective
schemes
Characteristics of collective schemes and welfare
gains relative to first best contract without
intergenerational risk sharing
33Findings on stylized collective schemes
- Optimal base premium and benefit same all cases
- More risk taking and risk sharing in hybrid
schemes, which are more attractive than pure DB /
DC - Uniform scheme that does not address age
differences but does exploit intergenerational
risk sharing can outperform the first best
contract without trade between non-overlapping
generations (and a fortiori outperforms the
second best individual contract) - Note that potential differences in individual
characteristics have been assumed away - Likewise continuity of the contract between
non-overlapping generations is assumed - A long recovery period is attractive if
continuity of the contract is assumed.
34Extensions of the basic model
- Final section provides literature reviews on
extensions of the basic model - /- indicates additional or less risk taking by
young - Labor markets and human capital
- Risky human capital (-)
- Endogenous labor supply ()
- Risk factors in financial markets
- Interest and inflation risk
- Mean reversion in equity returns ()
- Preferences
- Minimum consumption (-)
- Loss aversion ()
35Conclusions
- Risk taking adds substantial welfare
- Hybrid restricted collective contracts to be
preferred over pure collective DB or DC. - Collective contracts have potential to generate
welfare through cost reduction, intergenerational
solidarity and relaxation of borrowing
constraints. - Collective contracts can reduce behavioral biases
- Collective contracts often suffer from
in-transparency. - Tailor made contracts are valuable if implemented
adequately - The optimal pension contract might have elements
of both worlds collective as well as individual
(guided through adequate defaults)
36(No Transcript)