Title: Trading Costs and Intraday Patterns
1Trading Costs and Intraday Patterns
- Rotman Distinguished Lecture Series
- March 2008
- Ingrid M. Werner
- Martin and Andrew Murrer Professor of Finance
- Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State
University
2Empirical Predictions Trading Costs
- Measuring trading costs using only trades
- Measuring trading costs by referencing quotes
- Trading costs should be increasing in trade size
- Spreads reflect several components
- Order processing costs
- Inventory risk
- Adverse selection
3Roll (1984)Trade-Based Transactions Costs
- How should we measure transactions costs from
trade-by-trade data (no quotes)? - Roll (1984) came up with a clever technique that
uses the idea that trade-prices should have a
negative autocorrelation on average due to
bid-ask bounce. - In practice, the spread varies over the day and
there are lots of continuations - Tested in Harris (1990)
½
1
qt
-1
½
qt is independent of ut and iid
4Transactions Costs using Quotes
- It is not so obvious how we should measure
transactions costs! - Petersen Fialkowski (1994) emphasized the
difference between the quoted spread, effective
spread, and realized spread - Should we weigh measures?
- To determine whether a particular trade is a buy
or a sell, we need to use a trade-classification
rule. - Lee Ready (1991) proposed to use the following
simple rule - A trade above the mid-quote is a buy
- A trade below the mid-quote is a sell
- A trade at the mid-quote is classified based on a
tick-test (the direction of recent prices) - Trade are matched to quotes lagged 5 seconds
1
3
2
- Is a buy
- Is a sell
- Is a buy (uptick)
5Comparative Studies of Trading Costs
- For example, Huang and Stoll (1996) compare
trading costs for Nasdaq and NYSE firms in 1991
based on a matched sample - Matching is on SIC code, LT debt, closing price,
SHOUT, and BV equity - NYSE quoted and effective spread are lower than
Nasdaq quoted and effective spreads. - Price impact of trades are larger on NYSE than on
Nasdaq, so differences in adverse selection
cannot explain result - Rolls spread is also larger on Nasdaq than on
the NYSE - Cross-sectional regressions suggest that the
observed differences cannot be accounted for by
the matching techniqueNYSE trading costs are
lower than Nasdaq trading costs???
6Updated Trade Classification Algorithms
- More recently, several authors have proposed more
reliable ways of classifying trades as buyer and
seller initiated. - The LR (1991) algorithm does poorly for trades
that are within the spread, and for trades
outside of the spread. - Odders-White (2000) discusses the occurrence and
consequences of trade misclassification of NYSE
stocks. - Werner (2003) uses NYSE audit trail data to
analyze traing costs. - Actual effective spreads for liquidity-demanding
orders are about 50 less than those measured
using the LR (1991) algorithm. - Trade composition (SP, FB, MO, LO, etc) matters
for costs - Ellis, Michaely, and OHara (2001) propose an
alternative trade-classification method for
Nasdaq stocks. - Classify a trade at the ask as a buy and a trade
at the bid as a buy, and use a tick-test for all
other trades. - While the classification success is not
significantly larger, it turns out to have a very
large effect on measures of effective spreads. - Moreover, a zero second delay is now recommended.
7Comparative Studies of Trading Costs
- Bessembinder (JFM, 2003) uses 1998 data to show
that correcting for the misclassification
(relying on EMO (2001)) does not affect the
conclusion that Nasdaq has higher trading costs
than the NYSE.
Bessembinder (JFQA, 2003) Shows that spreads
and depth after decimalization in 2001 are lower
on both Nasdaq and the NYSE. The NYSE is still
cheaperthan Nasdaq
8Trading Costs and Trade Size
- Theoretical models (e.g., Easley OHara (1987))
suggest that large trades should pay a higher
transactions cost - Inventory
- Information
- Lots of empirical papers have verified that this
is the case based on NYSE data. - Reiss and Werner (1996) instead show that large
trades in London actually get significant price
improvement! - Bernhardt, Dvoracek, Hughson and Werner (2003)
show that London price improvements are based on
reputation/relationships (measured as trading
between the dealer and broker in the past).
9Trading Costs and Trade Size
10Transactions Costs References
- Bernhardt, D., E. Hughson, V. Dvoracek, and I.
Werner, 2003, Why do larger orders receive
discounts on the London Stock Exchange?, Review
of Financial Studies, . - Bessembinder, H., 2003, Issues in assessing trade
execution costs, Journal of Financial Markets 6,
. - Huang, R., and H. Stoll, 1996, Dealer versus
auction markets A paired comparison of execution
costs on Nasdaq and the NYSE, Journal of
Financial Economics 41, 313-357. - Reiss, P., and I. Werner, 1996, Transaction costs
in a dealer markets Evidence from the London
Stock Exchange, in A. Lo Ed. The Industrial
Organization and Regulation of the Securities
Industry, University of Chicago Press, 125-175. - Werner, I., 2003, NYSE Spreads, order flow, and
information, Journal of Financial Markets 6,
309-335.
11Glosten and Harris (1988)Decomposing Spreads
- What part of the spread is attributable to order
processing and asymmetric information
respectively? - Develop a model where both information shocks and
order flow affect the fundamental value, and
transactions costs are assumed to be increasing
in volume. - Use TS to estimate c0 and z1 for each stock.
- Study CS of c0 and z1 to figure out if z1 is a
significant proportion of the spread..
Z1adverse selection z1(c0/P (), insider conc.
(0), SHH (-))
c0order processing c0(1/Trd.Frq (), s ())
12Ho and Stoll (1997)Decomposing Spreads
- What part of the spread is attributable to order
processing, asymmetric information, and inventory
respectively? - Exclude continuations
- Cannot separate out asymmetric from inventory
costs ?(aß). - Rest is order processing (1-?)
- Results
- S0.1222
- ?11.4
- (1-?) 88.6
- Fixed costs are much more important than
information/inventories!
Adverse selection
Inventory
13Ho and Stoll (1997)Decomposing Spreads
- What part of the spread is attributable to order
processing, asymmetric information, and inventory
respectively? - Try to separate a from ß
- Model serial correlation in trade flows
- Results
- a -3 !!!!
- ß 19
- (1-?) 84
- Fixed costs are still much more important!
- Adverse selection costs are negative!
- Woops those results violate the model
- Perhaps the problem is that orders are broken up.
- Bunch trades at the same price
- Results
- a 9 !!!!
- ß 29
- (1-?) 62
- Cheating???
- Other researchers (e.g., Jones and Lipson (1995))
have tried to fix it, but they keep having
trouble getting the adverse selection component
to behave
14Spread Decomposition References
- Hasbrouck, J., 2007, Chapter 3.4 and Chapter 9.8.
- George, T., G. Kaul, and Nimalendran, 1991,
Estimation of the bid-ask spread and its
components A new approach, Review of Financial
Studies 4, 623-656. - Glosten, L., and L. Harris, 1988, Estimating the
components of the bid-ask spread, Journal of
Financial Economics 21, 123-142. - Huang, R., and H. Stoll, 1997, The components of
the bid-ask spread A General approach, Review of
Financial Studies 10, 995-1034. - Petersen, M., and D. Fialkowski, 1994, Posted
versus effective spreads, Journal of Financial
Economics 35, 269-292. - Roll, R., 1984, A simple implicit measure of the
effective bid-ask spead in an efficient market,
Journal of Finance 39, 1127-1139. - Stoll, H., 1989, Inferring the components of the
bid-ask spread theory and empirical tests,
Journal of Finance 44, 115-134.
15Intraday Patterns
- Several authors have examined the intraday
patterns of returns, volatility, volume, and
spreads. - NYSE-listed stocks
- Jain and Joh (1988) returns and volume
- Wood, McInish, and Ord (1984) volume and
volatility - Wood, McInish (1992) spreads
- Nasdaq-listed stocks
- Chan, Christie, and Schultz (1995) volume,
volatility, and spreads - London stock exchange
- Werner and Kleidon (1996) volume, volatility, and
spreads - Returns are declining
- Volatility is U-shaped over the day
- Volume is U-shaped over the day
- Spreads are U-shaped over the day
- Why?
16Werner and Kleidon (1996)London Intraday Patterns
17Intraday (Day-of-the Week) Patterns
- Theoretical models with asymmetric information
make predictions on how actions of strategic
traders translate into patterns in the data. - For example
- Kyle (1985) predicts that prices should be linear
in signed order flow and that informed traders
should smooth out their trades over time - Admati and Pfleiderer (1988) predicts that
trading will be clustered to periods with low
trading costs and high volatility - Foster and Viswanathan (1993)
- Estimate based on 60 NYSE firms, deciles 1, 5,
and 10 (20 each) - Day of the week effect as well as intraday
patterns - Interday pattern (decile 10)
- Mondays are characterized by low volume and high
adverse selection. - Tuesdays have low volatility and adverse
selection - Intraday pattern
- Volume volatility is U-shaped for all deciles
- Volume and adverse selection are weakly
positively correlated
18Foster and Viswanathan (JF, 1993)
Volume
Volatility
19Foster and Viswanathan (1993)
Spreads
C fixed component
Lambda adverse selection component
20Madhavan, Richardson, and Roomans (1997)Intraday
Patterns
- Theoretical structural Bayesian model of
specialist pricing that addresses both
decomposition of spread and intraday patterns. - Builds on Madhavan and Smidt (1991)
- Accounts for asymmetric information and inventory
risk. - Tested based on NYSE-listed stocks
- Results
- Asymmetric information declines over the day
- The inventory component of the spread increases
over the day - Price impact (trading costs) declines over the
day - The autocorrelation of order flow is U-shaped
over the day
21Madhavan, Richardson, and Roomans (1997)Intraday
Patterns
Asymmetric information
Transaction cost
22Intraday Pattern References
- Chan, K.C., W. Christie, and P. Schultz, 1995,
Market structure and the intraday patterns of
bid-ask spreads for Nasdaq securities, Journal of
Business 68, 35-60. - Foster, D., and S. Viswanathan, 1993, Variations
in trading volume, variance, and trading costs
Evidence on recent price formation models,
Journal of Finance 48, 187-211. - Jain, P. and G. Joh, 1988, The dependence between
hourly prices and trading volume, Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 23, 269-284. - Madhavan, A., Richardson, M., and M. Roomans,
1997, Why do security prices change? A
transaction-level analysis of NYSE-listed stocks,
Review of Financial Studies 6, 345-374. - Madhavan, A., and S. Smidt, 1991, A bayesian
model of intraday specialist pricing, Journal of
Financial Economics 31, 99-134. - McInish, T., and R. Wood, 1992, An analysis of
intraday patterns in bid/ask spreads for NYSE
stocks, Journal of Finance 47, 753-764. - Werner, I., and A. Kleidon, 1996, UK and US
trading of British cross-listed stocks An
intraday analysis of market integration, Review
of Financial Studies 9, 619-664.
23Price Process
- The structural models that we have discussed so
far have only limited dynamics. - One way to accommodate richer dynamics is to cast
the price and order flow problem in a Vector Auto
Regression (VAR) framework. - The easiest example is to consider the Roll model
as a two-equation system - where A, B, and C are 2x2 matrices
- Well known techniques exist for specifying and
estimating VARS. - Dynamics are studied by impulse response
functions - Study how a shock to an exogenous variable, i.e.,
ut or vt, affects current and future price
changes and order flow
24Hasbrouck (1991)Price Process
- Hasbrouck has pioneered modeling the joint
dynamics of trades and quotes as a VAR. - Idea (from Hasbrouck (1988)) is to separate the
effect of inventory (temporary) from information
(permanent) on price changes - Key is that only unanticipated changes in order
flow should have permanent price impact - Hasbrouck (JF, 1991) measures the information
effects as the permanent price impact of a trade
(impulse response). - Inventory, order processing, and other frictions
should have transient impact on prices - Price impact takes time
- Price impact is a positive and concave function
of trade size - Large trades cause a widening of the spread
- When spreads are wide, the price impact is larger
- There are more information asymmetries for small
firms
25Hasbrouck (1991)Price Process
26Hasbrouck (1991)Price Process
27Hasbrouck (1991)Price Process
- Hasbrouck (RFS, 1991) proposes a method to
decompose the variance of changes in the
efficient price to those that are trade related
(information based), and those that are unrelated
to trades. - Finds that trades (information) account for about
34 of total variation - The fraction of variances attributable to
information is higher for less liquid stocks than
for more liquid stocks. - Finds support for Foster and Viswanathan (1993),
and contradicts Admati Pfleiderer (1988) when it
comes to intraday patterns - Price impact is largest at the open
28Hasbrouck (1993)Measure of Market Quality
- Hasbrouck (1993) identifies a new measure of
market quality - The standard deviation of the difference between
the transaction price and the implicit
unobservable efficient price - The efficient price is assumed to follow a random
walk component - Problem is that the efficient price is
unobservable!!! - The stationary component is labeled pricing
errors - Propose a clever VAR is used to estimate the
variance of the efficient price - Pricing error standard deviation is about 0.33
of stock price, corresponding to a cost of 0.26
of stock price. - Dispersion of pricing errors are elevated around
the open and the close
29Hasbrouck (1995)Off-Exchange Competition
- Hasbrouck (1995) studies what part of the
information comes from the NYSE versus the
Regional exchanges - A VAR is used for cross-market analysis of quotes
for Dow 30 stocks - Idea is that the efficient price is a common
process across markets trading the same stock - What fraction does the NYSE versus the regionals
contribute to changes in the efficient price? - NYSE is the main source of price discovery (92.7
information share) - Regional exchanges are cream-skimming
30Hasbrouck (1995)Off-Exchange Competition
31Hasbrouck (1995)Off-Exchange Competition
32Engle and Russell (2003)The ACD Model
- Engle and co-authors have developed a time-series
model called the ARCH model (AutoRegressive
Conditional Heteroscedasticity) to model the
variance of returns. - Most market microstructure work samples trades,
regardless of how close together or far apart
those trades occur in time. - The Autoregressive Conditional Duration model
addresses the fact that data is often irregularly
spaced. - Technically, the time between trades is modeled
as a point process with dependent arrival rates. - The ACD model is essentially a ARCH model for the
time between trade arrivals. - Additional papers by Engle and co-authors extend
these ideas to analyze the joint dynamics of
quotes and trades.
33Price Process References
- Hasbrouck, J., 2007, Chapter 9
- Chakravarty, S., 2001, Stealth trading Which
traders trades move prices? Journal of Financial
Economics 61, 289307. - Engle, R., and J. Russell, 2003, Autoregressive
conditional duration A new model for irregularly
spaced data, Econometrica 66, 1127-1162. - Hasbrouck, J., 1991a, Measuring the information
content of stock trades, Journal of Finance 46,
179-207. - Hasbrouck, J., 1991b, The summary informativeness
of stock trades An econometric analysis, Review
of Financial Studies 4, 571-595. - Hasbrouck, J., 1993, Assessing the quality of a
security market A new approach to
transaction-cost measurement, Review of Financial
Studies 6, 191-212.