Title: Surplus Production models
1Surplus Production models
- Surplus production vs Dynamic pool vs Cohort
models - Logistic growth
- MSY
- Catch-effort
- How to fit, examples
- Alternatives
- Chapter 7 in text
2Fishery (single-species) models
- Examine impact of fishing and other non-natural
sources of mortality on the growth, mortality,
and reproductive potential of fish populations
3Surplus production models
- View population as one unit of biomass subject to
constant growth and mortality rates
4Surplus production models
- View population as one unit of biomass subject to
constant growth and mortality rates - Basic theory of sustainable exploitation
5Surplus production models
- View population as one unit of biomass subject to
constant growth and mortality rates - Basic theory of sustainable exploitation and
capture the basic logic of density-dependence
6Surplus production models
- View population as one unit of biomass subject to
constant growth and mortality rates - Basic theory of sustainable exploitation and
capture the basic logic of density-dependence - Production models, stock production models,
surplus yield models, biomass dynamic models
7Surplus production models
- View population as one unit of biomass subject to
constant growth and mortality rates - Basic theory of sustainable exploitation and
capture the basic logic of density-dependence - Peaked in popularity during the 1950s-1970s
8Dynamic pool models
- recognize that growth, mortality, and
reproductive potential may vary by age
9Dynamic pool models
- recognize that growth, mortality, and
reproductive potential may vary by age - still used today to examine reproduction and
recruitment potential.
10Cohort models
- trace the decline in abundance of groups of fish
of similar age (cohorts) as they age through the
population,
11Cohort models
- trace the decline in abundance of groups of fish
of similar age (cohorts) as they age through the
population, and use this decline to determine
mortality rates
12Cohort models
- trace the decline in abundance of groups of fish
of similar age (cohorts) as they age through the
population, and use this decline to determine
mortality rates - their popularity has grown since the early 1970s.
13Surplus production models
- rely on the principle that fish populations, on
the average, produce more offspring than
necessary to replenish the populations abundance
of spawning adults
14Surplus production models
- rely on the principle that fish populations, on
the average, produce more offspring than
necessary to replenish the populations abundance
of spawning adults - On the average, fisheries may be able to crop
this excessive (or surplus) production without
endangering the population.
15Surplus production models
- On the average, fisheries may be able to crop
this excessive (or surplus) production without
endangering the population - ideally, the population could be fished at a
level that maximizes the harvest biomass every
year
16Surplus production models
- On the average, fisheries may be able to crop
this excessive (or surplus) production without
endangering the population - ideally, the population could be fished at a
level that maximizes the harvest biomass every
year - Termed maximum sustainable yield (MSY)
17Surplus production models
- Population biomass depends on growth,
reproduction, natural and fishing mortality
Fig 7.1
18Surplus production models
- Density dependence allows population to sustain
fishery mortality
Fig 7.2
19Surplus production models
Fig 7.3a
20- Growth is max at intermediate levels
Fig 7.3b
21- Growth is max at intermediate levels
22early
- Growth is max at intermediate levels
middle
late
23- Growth is max at intermediate levels
24Fig 7.3c
25 26- If catch and effort are proportional to biomass,
then MSY can be derived on a catch vs effort plot
27 28SY vs Catch-effort curves
- logistic equation (rate of change of biomass)
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
29SY vs Catch-effort curves
- logistic equation (rate of change of biomass)
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- catch rate, catch or yield (Y) per year is
deducted - dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
30SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- catch rate, catch or yield (Y) per year is
deducted - dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- At equilibrium, removals growth, (dB/dt0)
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
31SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- catch rate, catch or yield (Y) per year is
deducted - dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- At equilibrium, removals growth, (dB/dt0)
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- Parabola describing yield vs biomass
32SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- At equilibrium, removals growth, (dB/dt0)
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- Yield catchabilityeffort biomass, (YqfB),
and sinceY/fCPUE, CPUEqB - BCPUE/q (2)
33SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- Yield catchabilityeffort biomass, (YqfB),
and sinceY/fCPUE, CPUEqB - BCPUE/q (2)
- Substituting 2 in 1
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-(CPUE/q)/(CPUE8/q)
- where CPUE8 is CPUE at max biomass (B8) of the
stock
34SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-(CPUE/q)/(CPUE8/q)
- Dividing by CPUE
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
35SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-CPUE/q)/CPUE8/q)
- Dividing by CPUE
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
- CPUECPUE8-CPUE8q/r f
36SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-CPUE/q)/CPUE8/q)
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
- CPUECPUE8-CPUE8q/r f
- Which is a straight line, CPUE a bf
37SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-CPUE/q)/CPUE8/q)
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
- CPUECPUE8-CPUE8q/r f
- Which is a straight line, CPUE a bf
- slope, b -CPUE8q/r
- intercept, a CPUE8
38SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-CPUE/q)/CPUE8/q)
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
- CPUECPUE8-CPUE8q/r
- CPUE a bf
- Multiplying by effort and since Yf(CPUE)
- Yaf bf2
39SY vs Catch-effort curves
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8
- dB/dt r B 1-B/B8-Y
- Y r B 1-B/B8 (1)
- BCPUE/q (2)
- Yf(CPUE)r(CPUE/q) 1-CPUE/q)/CPUE8/q)
- fr/q 1-CPUE/CPUE8
- CPUECPUE8-CPUE8q/r f
- Yaf bf2 (3)
- Schaefers model where yield is related to
fishing effort
40Catch-effort curvesan example sea bass (Lates
calcalifer) data
hmnd 100 m of net used per day
41Catch-effort curvesan example sea bass (Lates
calcalifer) data
slope, b -0.0002047
Y-int 25.6
Effort (hmnd)
42Catch-effort curvesan example sea bass data
43Catch-effort curvesan example sea bass data
44Catch-effort curvesMSY and fmsy
- How to solve for MSY and fmsy?
- Take the derivative of Yield equation and equal
to zero (i.e. when is slope 0?) - a 2bfmsy 0
- fmsy -a / (2b) (4)
- Substitute (4) into the Schaefer equation (3)
- MSY -a(a/2b) b (a/2b)2 -a2/(4b)
45Catch-effort curvesMSY and fmsy
- Applying these to the bass example
- fmsy -a /(2b) 62,530 hmnd
- MSY -a2/(4b) 800,390 kg
- A SY of approximately 800t may be taken by 62,500
hmnd or by 42 fishers using 1500m of gill net,
and fishing for an average of 100d/yr
46Catch-effort curvesMSY and fmsy
MSY
fmsy
47Schaefer curveseffects of reducing effort
- Fishing effort increased dramatically between
1972-1979 (see table)-using these data
MSY994
79
fmsy69,129
48Schaefer curveseffects of reducing effort
- In 1980 fishing effort was reduced yield after
1980 remained low and approached the original
yield curve from below a new equilibrium?
49Schaefer curvesregulating a fishery
- 2 general methods
- Fixed quota setting a limit, Q, on the number of
fish harvested per season regardless of the
number in the population
Q1
Q2
Q1
50Schaefer curvesregulating a fishery
- 2 general methods
- Fixed effort limiting effort (e.g. number of
permits, length of season, spatial restrictions,
etc)
High effort
Low effort
51Schaefer curvesregulating a fishery
- 2 general methods
- Fixed effort 5 different efforts in 5 different
years and resulting catches
Yield
Effort 3
Effort 1
52Schaefer curvesregulating a fishery
- 2 general methods
- Fixed effort those same catches plotted against
effort
Effort
53Catch-effort curvesstability of Schaefer model
7.4a
54Catch-effort curvesstability of Schaefer model
- Populations should never be exploited at MSY
using constant catch rates, why? - Any reduction in Bmsy will crash the population,
- i.e. the MSY equilibrium is not stable
- However, the MSY equilibrium is stable when
constant proportions of biomass (i.e. fixed
effort) are caught, - But only if the effort curve crosses the yield
curve
55Catch-effort curvesstability of Schaefer model
7.4b
56Catch-effort curvesalternatives to Schaefer
- Fox curve (7.3) is more appropriate for biomass
measurements (logistic usually with numbers)
57Catch-effort curvesalternatives to Schaefer
- Fox curve (7.3) is more appropriate for biomass
measurements (logistic usually with numbers) - MSY to the left of logistic level
58Catch-effort curvesFox curve example
59Catch-effort curvesalternatives to Schaefer
- Pella-Tomlinson model (7.4) allows for
flexibility in shape of production curve
60Catch-effort curvesalternatives to Schaefer
- Pella-Tomlinson model (7.4) allows for
flexibility in shape of production curve - MSY to the left or right logistic level (m)
61Surplus production approachassumptions
- instantaneous reaction of stock
- symmetric parabola
- need large range of efforts (high and low)
- stock is self-contained
- any loss is mortality
- no interspecific interactions
- the environment is constant
- fishing is density-independent
62Surplus production approachadvantages
- calculate MSY and Fopt without catchability
- uses only catch and effort data
- do not need ages
- cheap
63Surplus production approachdisadvantages
- not incorporate ecosystem environmental factors
- exclusion of trophic linkages
- assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing
64Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- index of abundance related to true abundance
65Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- Equilibrium methods
- Assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing
66Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- Equilibrium methods
- Assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing - Non-equilibrium methods
- Process-error methods
- No equilibrium assumption
67Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- Equilibrium methods
- Assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing - Non-equilibrium methods
- Process-error methods
- No equilibrium assumption
- All error in population growth relationship
68Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- Equilibrium methods
- Assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing - Non-equilibrium methods
- Process-error methods
- No equilibrium assumption
- All error in population growth relationship
- Catch and effort data measured without error
69Surplus production approachfitting models to
data
- Equilibrium methods
- Assumes stock has stabilized at current rate of
fishing - Non-equilibrium methods
- Process-error methods
- No equilibrium assumption
- All error in population growth relationship
- Catch and effort data measured without error
- Observation-error methods
- All error in catch and effort data
70Surplus production approachequilibrium models
the Peruvian anchovy
Fig 7.6
GRT gross registered tonnage
71Surplus production approachcomparing fitting
techniques
data
equilibrium
process error
observation error
7.7
72Surplus production approachlessons
- Fisheries are rarely at equilibrium
- Stability is the exception
- CPUE is problematic
- Best way to find Fopt is to overfish
- Pooling ages isnt always advisable
73Surplus production approachdelay-difference
models
- Deriso/Schnute
- Lag between spawning and recruitment
- Only 2 age groups
- Include natural mortality, body growth, and
recruitment - Derivation in box 7.1
- Can produce good fits but show sensitivity to
parameter uncertainty and large errors
74Surplus production approachdelay-difference
models
yellowtail flounder
7.8