Title: EXAMINING THE U'S' ELECTORAL COLLEGE: VARIANTS AND PROBLEMS
1EXAMINING THE U.S. ELECTORAL COLLEGE VARIANTS
AND PROBLEMS
- Nicholas R. Miller
- UMBC
- LSE/VPP Talk
- May 6, 2008
- http//userpages.umbc.edu/nmiller/ELECTCOL.html
2Origins of the Electoral College
- The mode of appointment of the Chief Magistrate
of the United States is almost the only part of
the system, of any consequence, which has escaped
without severe censure, or which has received the
slightest mark of approbation from its opponents.
. . . I venture somewhat further, and hesitate
not to affirm that if the manner of it be not
perfect, it is at least excellent. (Publius
Alexander Hamilton, Federalist 68) - Many subsequent evaluations (and the many
proposed constitutional amendments) suggest a
less favorable assessment of the mode of
appointment of the Chief Magistrate, which has
been variously viewed as - part of a generally elitist and anti-democratic
constitution or - a last-minute jerry-built compromise or
- a well designed compromise among diverse
considerations, or possibly - the embodiment of well-thought selection criteria.
3Origins of the Electoral College (cont.)
- The Electoral College the term is not used in
the Constitution was a compromise between - legislative election of the President (which
might make the President subservient to Congress)
and - national popular election (which presented
formidable practical difficulties at the time). - The perceived advantage of the Electoral College
was that (unlike Congress) it would perform a
single task i.e., cast votes for President --
and would then disband. - A new Electoral College of unknown composition
would re-elect (or not) the President four years
later.
4The Original Electoral College
- Each state selects a number of intermediate
electors equal in number to its total (House
Senate) representation in Congress (H 2). - The legislature of each state determines the mode
of selection of the electors from that state, the
most likely alternatives being - election by the legislature itself,
- popular election from districts, and
- popular election on a state-wide general
ticket. - Electors were originally required to
- cast two votes for two different candidates,
- at least one of whom had to be a resident of
another state. - To be elected by the Electoral College, a
candidate was required to receive - votes from a majority of electors and
- more votes than any other candidate.
- Given the double vote system, these are logically
distinct requirements.
5The Original Electoral College (cont.)
- If no candidate met the above requirement, the
election would be thrown into the House of
Representatives. - The House could choose
- between two (or more) tied candidates, in the
event both (or all) receive votes from a majority
of electors, or - among the top five candidates, in the event no
candidate receives votes from a majority of
electors. - Voting in the House is by state delegation, each
delegation casting one vote. - Balloting continues until some candidate is
supported by a majority of state delegations. - In any event, the runner-up Presidential
candidate becomes Vice President.
6The Original Electoral College (cont.)
- This original Electoral College system was
designed to operate in a non-partisan
environment. - It was generally hoped and expected that electors
would typically be - popularly elected
- from single-member districts (like most state
legislators, delegates to the state ratifying
conventions, members of the British House of
Commons, and as was expected also for members of
the new U.S. House and - that they would be well-informed local notables
who would act as representative trustees of their
states and districts. - It was further expected that
- there would typically be multiple potential
Presidential candidates, and - electors would choose among these candidates on
the basis of their character and connections, not
party affiliation or policy promises. - It was therefore expected that the House
contingent procedure would be needed 19 times
out of 20, so - big states would have the dominant role in
screening/nominating candidates, while - small states would have equal role in most final
elections.
7Duvergers Law and Crackup of the Original
Electoral College
- These expectations did not anticipate the
development of a national two-party system. - Duvergers Law Given politically ambitious
candidates, single-winner elections produce (in
equilibrium) two-candidate (or two-ticket
Pres.VP) contests (the wasted vote argument
and all that) and then sustain a two-party
system. - Given the development of a two-party Federalist
vs. Republican system, the double-vote
runner-up-is-VP provisions of the original
Electoral College turned out to be a fatal flaw.
- In 1796 the Presidential candidate (Jefferson) of
the losing (Republican) party became Vice
President. - In 1800 an electoral vote tie between the two
(Presidential and Vice Presidential) candidates
of the winning (Republican) party was broken by a
House of Representatives controlled by the losing
(Federalist) party.
8The 12th Amendment
- After the 1800 fiasco, Congress proposed, and the
states quickly ratified (in time for 1804
election), the 12th Amendment to the
Constitution. - Electors now cast separate votes for President
and Vice President. - The required electoral vote majority for
President (and for Vice President) is a simple
majority of votes cast ( number of electors). - If no candidate receives the required simple
majority for President, the House (still voting
by state delegations) chooses from among the top
three vs. top five candidates. - If no candidate receives the required majority
for Vice President, the Senate (voting
individually) chooses from among the top two
candidates.
9The Transformation of the Electoral College
- By the 1830s, the Electoral College as formally
modified by the 12th Amendment had been further
transformed into the kind of (essentially)
automatic popular vote counting system that
exists today. - This transformation
- was driven largely by the development of a
two-party system, and - was brought about without any further
constitutional amendments or (with one minor
exception) any change in federal law.
10Elements of the Transformation
- Beginning with the first contested Presidential
election in 1796, elector candidates almost
invariably party men, pledged (and faithful) to
the (Presidential and Vice Presidential) nominees
of their party. - Put otherwise, electors became party delegates
rather that trustees of their states or districts
cf. regular delegates vs. superdelegates - Pledged electors were almost universal as early
as 1796. - Notably, Samuel Miles (Fed., PA) violated his
pledge and voted for Jefferson rather than Adams. - An angry Federalist supporter complained What,
do I choose Samuel Miles to determine for me
whether John Adams or Thomas shall be President?
No! I choose him to act, not to think. - Once pledged and faithful electors have been
selected, the prospective electoral vote for
Presidential candidates is also known. - The 12th Amendment took effect in 1804.
- A nationwide Presidential election day (i.e., day
for selecting Presidential electors) was
established by Congress in 1845.
11Elements of the Transformation (cont.)
- In early elections, the mode of selecting
Presidential electors was regularly manipulated
by party politicians in each state, on the basis
of partisan calculations. - Madison to Monroe (1800) All agree that an
election by districts would be best if it could
be general, but while ten states choose either by
their legislatures or by a general ticket so the
dominant party wins all of a states electoral
votes, it is folly or worse for the other six
not to follow. - By 1832, Presidential electors were almost
universally selected by popular (vs. legislative)
vote (and by much expanded electorates). - With popular election of pledged electors,
American voters may be forgiven for thinking they
are actually voting for Presidential candidates
on election day. - By 1836, the mode of popular election in every
state is (following Madisons strategic analysis
above) the general ticket (or party slate),
rather than election from districts (or by any
kind of propor-tional representation). - This induces winner-take-all at the state
level. - However, at the present time two small states (ME
and NE) use the Modified District Plan (discussed
later).
12Elements of the Transformation (cont.)
- Moreover, the two-party system has effectively
bypassed the House contingent procedure. - On this point, the election of 1824 (the second
and last time an election was thrown into the
House) was the exception that proved the rule. - The Federalist Party had collapsed and the
Democratic-Republican Party was unchallenged. - Consequently there was no longer pressure for
Democratic-Republicans to unite behind a single
candidate (or Presidential-Vice Presidential
ticket). - Four candidates, all nominally belonging to the
same party, sought the Presidency. - Unsurprisingly, no candidate received a majority
of the electoral votes and the election was
thrown into the House (for the second and last
time). - However, whenever there is a serious
third-party ticket (especially one with a
geographical base of support, e.g., George
Wallace vs. Ross Perot), fears of the election
being thrown into the House arise. - Moreover, since the 23rd Amendment, giving the
District of Columbia three electoral votes, was
ratified in 1961, the total number of electoral
votes has been an even number (538), - so an electoral vote tie (269-269) is possible,
and - an election might be thrown into the House even
in the absence of a third-party candidate winning
election votes.
13The Electoral College as a Vote-Counting Mechanism
- On election day (November 4), voters in each
state vote for either the Democratic or
Republican (or possibly other) slates of elector
candidates, who are pledged to their partys
(Pres. VP) nominees. - The elector slate receiving the most votes wins.
- The electors meet in their state capital in
mid-December and cast their electoral votes (as
pledged). - Electoral vote tallies are transmitted from each
state capital to Congress and counted before a
joint session on January 5. - The President of the Senate the incumbent Vice
President of the U.S. announces the vote and
proclaims the President-elect. - So in (almost invariable) practice, everything is
determined on election night in November, and the
remaining steps are merely ceremonial that is,
TV prognosticators can - report the popular vote winner in each state,
- add up the corresponding electoral votes, and
- declare a President-elect.
14(Alleged) Problems with the Electoral College as
a Vote-Counting Mechanism
- The Voting Power Problem. Do voters in different
states have unequal voting power? - If so, the EC violates the criterion of One
Person, One Vote (OPOV). - The Election Reversal Problem. The candidate who
wins the most popular votes nationally may fail
to be elected. - The election 2000 provides an example (provided
we take the official popular vote in FL at face
value). - The Partisan Bias Problem. Does the Electoral
College as a vote counting system favor one party
over the other? - This is essentially a generalization of the
Election Reversal Problem. - The Battleground States Problem. The Electoral
College focuses the Presidential election contest
on a few battleground states, which get very
disproportionate attention from the candidates
and parties.
15A Priori Voting Power
- The Electoral College itself generates a
51-player weighted voting game susceptible a
priori voting power analysis using an appropriate
voting power measure. - In addition, there is an simple majority voting
game within each state to select members of the
Electoral College. - So the overall Presidential election is a
two-tier voting game. - The measurement and interpretation of a priori
voting power has been a major focus of the LSE
program on Voting Power and Procedures. - Though VPP research has focused primarily on
voting power with respect to the EU Council of
Ministers (and other EU institutions). - Measures of a priori voting power applied to the
Electoral College take account of the its formal
rules plus the population of each state and the
mathematical formula used to apportion House
seats among the states, - but not demographics, historic voting patterns,
ideology, polling results, election forecasts,
etc.
16Voting Power (cont.)
- With a measure of voting power, we can address
questions that arise with respect to voting power
in the Electoral College, in particular - How much (if any) does individual voting power
vary from state to state? - In so far as it does vary, are voters in larger
or smaller states favored? (A priori, population
is the only way states differ.) - How would voting power change under various
proposed (and other) alternatives to the existing
Electoral College?
17Voting Power (cont.)
- With respect to the second question, directly
contra-dictory claims are commonly made. - The Electoral College . . . gives greater voting
power to voters in states with less than average
population and less to those with greater than
average population. (Gary Parish, The Electoral
College Source of Inequality and Social
Injustice in America) - According to a frequently published argument . .
. , there is an intrinsic large-state advantage
in Presidential elections. (Howard Margolis,
The Banzhaf Fallacy) - Partly because the Electoral College is viewed by
some as favoring small states and by others as
favoring large states, it is commonly asserted
that a constitutional amending modifying or
abolishing the Electoral College can never by
ratified by the required 38 states. - Hence the National Popular Vote Plan (to use an
interstate compact to bypass the constitutional
amendment process).
18Voting Power (cont.)
- First, we need to define and distinguish between
- voting weight and
- voting power.
- Second and specifically with respect to the
Electoral College, we also need to distinguish
between - how electoral votes are apportioned among the
states (which determines voting weight), and - how electoral votes are cast within states
(which, in conjunction with voting weight,
determines voting power).
19The Apportionment of Electoral Votes
- Remember that each state has electoral votes
equal to its total (House Senate)
representation in Congress, - which guarantees every state at least three
electoral votes and - more generally produces a systematic and
substantial small-state advantage in the
apportionment of electoral votes (relative to the
apportionment population). - This is the basis of the argument that the
Electoral College advantages voters in smaller
(rural, etc.) states. - The magnitude of this small-state apportionment
advantage is not fixed in the Constitution. - It varies (inversely) with the size of the House
(relative to the Senate), which is determined by
Congress. - If the House had been sufficiently larger than
435, Gore would have won the 2000 election (even
while losing Florida).
20The Small-State Apportionment Advantage
21Another View of the Small-State Advantage
22The Casting of Electoral Votes
- Remember that state choice of the general ticket
for electing electors produces the
winner-take-all practice that produces the
weighted voting game noted at the outset. - Many have believed that this practice produces a
large-state advantage in voting power that
counteracts (in some degree) the small-state
advantage in apportion-ment. - This is the basis for the argument that the
Electoral College gives disproportionate voting
power to voters in larger (urban, etc.) states.
23Voting Weight vs. Voting Power
- Suppose that four parties receive these vote
shares Party A, 27 Party B, 25 Party C, 24
Party 24. - Seats in a 100-seat parliament are proportionally
awarded, so - Party A 27 seats Party C 24 seats
- Party B 25 seats Party D 24 seats
- While seats (voting weights) have been
apportioned in a way that is precisely
proportional to vote support, voting power has
not been proportionally apportioned (and cannot
be). - Since no party controls a majority of 51 seats, a
governing coalition of two or more parties must
be formed. - A partys voting power is reflects its
opportunity to create (or destroy) winning
(governing) coalitions. - But, with a small number of parties, coalition
possibilities -- and therefore different patterns
in the distribution of voting power -- are highly
restricted.
24Voting Weight vs. Voting Power (cont.)
- A 27 seats B 25 seats C 24 seats
D 24 seats - Once the parties start negotiating, they will
find that Party A has voting power that greatly
exceeds its slight advantage in seats. This is
because - Party A can form a winning coalition with any one
of the other parties and - the only way to exclude Party A from a winning
coalition is for Parties B, C, and D to form a
three-party coalition. - The seat allocation above (totaling 100 seats) is
strategically equivalent to this much simpler
allocation (totaling 5 seats) - Party A 2 seats
- Parties B, C, and D 1 seat each
- Total of 5 seats, so a winning coalition requires
3 seats, i.e., (32,1,1,1) - So the original seat allocation is strategically
equivalent to one in which Party A has twice the
weight of each of the other parties (which is not
proportional to their vote shares).
25Voting Weight vs. Voting Power (cont.)
- Suppose at the next election the vote and seat
shares change a bit - Before Now
- Party A 27 Party A 30
- Party B 25 Party B 29
- Party C 24 Party C 22
- Party D 24 Party D 19
- While seats shares have changed only slightly,
the strategic situation has changed
fundamentally. - Party A can no longer form a winning coalition
with Party D. - Parties B and C can now form a winning coalition
by themselves. - The seat allocation is equivalent to this much
simpler allocation - Parties A, B, and D 1 seat each
- Party D 0 seats
- Total of 3 seats, so a winning coalition requires
2 seats, i.e., (21,1,1,0) - Party A has lost voting power, despite gaining
seats. - Party C has gained voting power, despite losing
seats. - Party D has become powerless (becoming a
so-called dummy), despite retaining a substantial
number of seats.
26Felsenthal and Machover, The Measurement of
Voting Power
- In this book, Dan Felsenthal and Moshé Machover
(both members of the VPP Board of Directors)
present the most conclusive study of voting power
measures. - They conclude that the so-called Absolute Banzhaf
Measure is the appropriate measure for evaluating
power in typical voting situations, including the
Electoral College. - They further show that this measure has the
following a probabilistic interpretation - A voters absolute Banzhaf voting power is the
voters a priori probability of casting a
decisive vote, i.e., one that determines the
outcome of an election (for example, breaking
what otherwise would be a tie). - In this context, a priori probability means, in
effect, given that all voters vote randomly,
i.e., vote for either candidate as if they
independently flip fair coins), so that every
point in the Bernoulli space (every combination
of voters) is equally likely to occur. - I call such a two-candidate elections Bernoulli
elections
27Calculating Power Index Values
- There are mathematical formulas and algorithms
can calculate or estimate voting power values. - Various website make these algorithms readily
available. - One of the best of these is the website created
by Dennis Leech (University of Warwick and
another VPP Board member) Computer Algorithms
for Voting Power Analysis, - http//www.warwick.ac.uk/ecaae/
- which was used in making the calculations that
follow. - It is apparent that
- with 51 states (as opposed to 4 parties in the
earlier example) voting power is in fact closely
proportional to voting weight (electoral votes),
though - the largest states (especially California) are
somewhat advantaged. - Remember that (for example) Californias value of
.475 means that, if all states other than CA
repeatedly cast their electoral votes by
independently flipping coins, almost half of the
time they would split their 483 votes
sufficiently equally that Californias 55 votes
determine the winner).
28(No Transcript)
29State Voting Power in the Existing EC (cont.)
- It is evident from the following charts that
- only Californias share of voting power
substantially deviates from (and exceeds) its
share of electoral votes - the modest large-state advantage in voting power
(relative to voting weight) is not sufficient to
balance out the small-state advantage in
apportionment indeed, - even Californias distinctive advantage in terms
of voting power (relative to voting weight) is
not sufficient to give it voting power
proportional to its population.
30Share of Voting Power by Share of Electoral Votes
31Share of Voting Power by Share of Population
32The 125 Million Two-Tier Voting Game
- But as previously noted, a U.S. Presidential
election really is a two-tier voting system, in
which the casting of electoral votes is
determined by a simple majority voting games
within each state. - In such a two-tier system, individual a priori
voting power is the probability of double
decisiveness, i.e., - that a voter casts a decisive vote within his or
her state (i.e., that there is tie among the
other voters in the state), - and
- that his or her state casts a decisive bloc of
electoral votes (i.e., that neither candidate
wins 270 electoral votes from the other states). - Put otherwise, individual voting power in the
two-tier system is equal to - individual voting power in the unweighted (but
large number) majority voting game within the
state - times
- the states voting power in the 51-state weighted
voting game. - We have already determined the second term in
this product as shown in the last column of the
previous table.
33The Two-Tier Voting Game (cont.)
- Probability theory and the properties of Banzhaf
measure tell us that the individual voting power
in the first tier voting game is inversely
proportional (to excellent approximation once n
gt 25) to the square root of the number of voters
in the state. - We previously saw that a states voting power in
the second tier voting game is approximately
proportional to its electoral vote (and
therefore, apart from the small state
apportionment advantage, roughly proportional to
its population. - Putting these two considerations together, it
follows that individual a priori voting power in
the two-tier system - increases with the population of the voters
state, and - is approximately proportional to the square root
of the number of voters in the voters state.
34The Two-Tier Voting Game (cont.)
- This effect (first noted with explicit reference
to the Electoral College by Banzhaf) may be
dubbed the Banzhaf effect. - It had been noted in a more general context
twenty years earlier by Penrose, and it is a
consequence of what Felsenthal and Machover call
the Penrose square-root rule. - With specific respect to the Electoral College,
the Banzhaf effect - is in some degree counterbalanced by the (quite
substantial) small-state advantage in
apportionment, - in small degree reinforced by the (quite weak)
large-state advantage in voting power, and - among the smallest states is largely hidden by
the unavoidable rounding error in apportioning
House seats into small whole numbers.
35(No Transcript)
36Individual Voting Power Under the Existing
Electoral College
37Individual Voting Power Under the Existing
Electoral College (cont.)
- The chart also shows mean individual voting power
nationwide. - Note that the individual voting power values
plotted in the chart must be weighted by ELECT
SIZE in order to determine mean voting power
nationwide. - The chart also shows individual voting power
under direct popular vote (calculated in the same
manner as individual voting power within a
state). - This is necessarily uniform over the nation.
- It is substantially greater than mean individual
voting power under the Electoral College. - Indeed, it is greater than individual voting
power in every state except California. - By the criterion of a priori voting power, only
voters in California would be hurt if the
existing Electoral College were replaced by a
direct popular vote.
38Alternatives to the Existing Electoral College
- We now consider two categories of alternatives to
the existing Electoral College - those that keep the state-level winner-take all
practice but use a different formula for
apportioning electoral votes among states, and - those that keep the existing apportionment of
electoral votes but use something other than
winner-take-all for the casting of state
electoral votes. - Almost all Electoral College reform plans (and
certainly all reforms that can be implemented at
the state level) fall in the second category. - Methodological note in these each charts,
individual voting power is scaled so that the
voters in the least favored state have a value of
1.000, so - numerical values are not comparable from chart to
chart, and - the scaled value of individual voting power under
direct popular vote changes from chart to chart.
39Alternative EV Apportionment Rules
- Keep the winner-take all practice in 2000, Bush
271, Gore 267 in 2004, Bush 286, Kerry, 252 but
use a different formula for apportioning
electoral votes among states. - Apportion electoral votes in whole numbers on
basis of House seats only Bush 211, Gore 225
Bush 224, Kerry 212 - Apportion electoral votes fractionally to be
precisely proportional to population Bush
268.96092, Gore 269.03908 Bush 275.67188, Kerry
262.32812 - Apportion electoral votes fractionally to be
precisely proportional to population but then add
back the constant two Bush 277.968, Gore
260.032 Bush 285.40695, Kerry 252.59305 - Apportion electoral votes equally among the
states in the manner of the House contingent
procedure Bush 30, Gore 21 Bush 31, Kerry 20
40Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationHouse Electoral Votes Only
41Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Precisely
Proportional to Population
42Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Proportional
Population, plus Two
43Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationElectoral Votes Apportioned Equally
Among States
44Alternative Rules for Casting Electoral Votes
- Apportion electoral votes as at present but use
something other than winner-take-all for casting
state electoral votes. - (Pure) Proportional Plan electoral votes are
cast fractionally in precise proportion to
state popular vote. Bush 259.2868, Gore
258.3364, Nader 14.8100, Buchanan 2.4563, Other
3.1105 Bush 277.857, Kerry 260.143 - Whole Number Proportional Plan e.g., Colorado
Prop. 36 electoral votes are cast in whole
numbers on basis of some apportionment formula
applied to state popular vote. Bush 263, Gore
269, Nader 6, or Bush 269, Gore 269 Bush 280,
Kerry 258 - Pure District Plan electoral votes cast by
single-vote districts. - Modified District Plan two electoral votes cast
for statewide winner, others by district
present NE and ME practice. Bush 289, Gore
249, if CDs are used no data for 2004 - National Bonus Plan 538 electoral votes are
apportioned and cast as at present but an
additional bloc of electoral votes e.g., 100
are awarded on a winner-take-all basis to the
national popular vote winner. Bush 271, Gore
367 Bush 386, Kerry 252
45Alternative Rules for Casting Electoral Votes
(cont.)
- Calculations for the Proportional Plan, the
Whole-Number Proportional Plan, and the Pure
District Plans are straightforward. - Under the Modified District Plan (and the
National Bonus Plans), each voter casts a single
vote that counts both within a district (or
state) and also at-large (state or nation). - Calculating individual voting power in such
systems is far from straightforward. - I have made approximations by simulating
Bernoulli elections.
46The (Pure) Proportional Plan
- Electoral votes are retained but the office of
elector is abolished. - A states electoral votes are cast fractionally
in precise proportion to the candidates shares
of the popular vote in the state (which is why
the office of elector must be abolished). - If proportionality is sufficiently refined, such
a system becomes a 122-million single-tier
weighted voting game, - where the weights applied to individual votes
reflect their states electoral votes per voter. - As proportionality becomes less refined, such a
system begins to resemble a whole-number
proportional system (considered next).
47The (Pure) Proportional Plan (cont.)
- The constitutional amendment for a proportional
system Lodge-Gossett Plan proposed in the
1950s specified that candidates would be credited
with fractional electoral votes calculated out to
four decimal places. - The following chart assumes that proportionality
is sufficiently refined to create a single-tier
weighted voting game. - We can invoke the Penrose Limit Theorem to
justify the assumption that voting weight
voting power in this single-tier very large-n
weighted voting game.
48Individual Voting Power by State
Population(Pure) Pure Proportional System
49(Pure) Proportional Plan (cont.)
- The small-state apportionment advantage carries
through very strongly to voting power. - Voters in Wyoming in have almost four times the
voting power of voters in California. - Nevertheless, voters in Montana (the largest
state with only three electoral voters) have less
voting power than voters in Rhode Island (the
smallest state with four electoral votes). - Close inspection of the chart shows that similar
but less striking inversions exist with respect
to a number of larger states. - Since sufficiently refined proportionality
creates what is effectively a (weighted)
single-tier voting game, mean individual voting
power is equal to individual voting power under a
direct (unweighted) popular vote.
50The Whole-Number Proportional Plan
- Such a plan was proposed by Colorados
Proposition 36 in 2004. - This plan divides a states electoral votes
between (or among) the candidates in a way that
is as close to proportional to the candidates
state popular vote shares as possible, given that
the apportionment must be in whole numbers. - Unlike the (Pure) Proportional Plan, whole-number
proportionality allows for the retention of
electors. - Accordingly, it is the only proportional plan
that can be implemented at the state level (as
Colorado Prop. 36 proposed).
51The Whole-Number Proportional Plan (cont.)
- In principle, there are as many such plans as
there are apportionment formulas. - In addition, candidates might be required to meet
some vote threshold in order to win any electoral
votes. - Colorado Proposition 36
- had no explicit vote threshold, and
- used a distinctly ad hoc apportionment formula
- that was overtly biased toward the strongest
candidate and against the weakest candidates. - But, in the event there are just two candidates
(as we assume here), all apportionment formulas
work in the same straightforward way - multiply each candidates share of the popular
vote by the states number of electoral votes and
then round off in the normal manner (to the
nearest whole number of electoral votes).
52Whole-Number Proportional Plan (cont.)
- In this two-tier system, individual a priori
voting power is the probability that - the voter casts a decisive vote within his or her
state in the sense that - other votes are so divided that the individuals
vote determines whether a candidate gets k or k1
electoral votes from the state, - and
- this single electoral vote is decisive in the
Electoral College. - where, as usual, these probabilities result from
the Bernoulli elections. - The following chart shows that this plan produces
a distinctly odd distribution of a priori
individual voting power. - Note. I have discovered that similar
calculations and chart have been produced,
independently and earlier, by Claus Beisbart and
Luc Bovens, A Power Analysis of the Amendment 36
in Colorado, University of Konstanz, May 2005,
and Public Choice, forthcoming. -
53Individual Voting Power by State
PopulationWhole-Number Proportional Plan
54Whole-Number Proportional Plan (cont.)
- As can be seen, this plan produces a truly
bizarre allocation of voting power. - Voters in a large number (17) of states are
rendered (essentially) powerless. - These are voters in states with an even number of
electoral votes. - Heres why this happens.
- Given Bernoulli elections and any fairly large
number of voters, the vote essentially always is
almost equally divided between the two
candidates. - As previously noted, the expected (i.e., the mean
over repeated coin flipping elections) vote share
for each candidate is .5, and - the standard deviation of the distribution of
vote shares is .5vn .
55Equal Apportionment vs. Whole-Number Proportional
56The Pure District Plan
- All electors are elected by popular vote in
single-member districts, so winner-take-all is
applied at the district, rather than state,
level. - Historical Note 1 this is how the most of the
framers thought electors would (and should) be
selected. - Historical Note 2 this mode of selection was
prescribed in early drafts of what became the
12th Amendment. - Accordingly, there are 538 electoral districts
and the popular vote winner in each district is
awarded one electoral vote. - All districts are subdivisions of states.
- All districts in the same state have equal
numbers of voters. - Districts in smaller states have smaller numbers
of voters than those in larger states, because of
the small-state advantage in the apportionment of
electoral votes.
57The Pure District Plan (cont.)
- Individual voting power within states is equal,
- because the number of voters in each district is
equal. - All districts have equal voting power in the
Electoral College, - because they have equal weight, i.e., 1 EV, and
the second tier voting game entails 538 equally
weighted voters. - Individual voting power across states is not
equal, - because districts in different states have
unequal numbers of voters.
58Individual Voting Power by State PopulationPure
District System
59The Pure District Plan (cont.)
- We see that the small-state advantage in
apportionment carries through in terms of voting
power. - Voters in Wyoming have an almost 2 to 1 voting
power advantage over voters in California. - While Wyoming districts have only about ¼ as many
voters as California districts, the Banzhaf
effect means that California voters have about ½
the voting power as Wyoming voters. - Nevertheless, voters in Montana (the largest
state with only three electoral voters) have less
voting power than voters in Rhode Island (the
smallest state with four electoral votes). - Close inspection of the chart shows that similar
but less striking inversions exist with respect
to a number of larger states.
60Supplementary Slides
61Can Electoral Vote Apportionment Equalize
Individual Voting Power?
- The question arises of whether electoral votes
can be apportioned so that (even while retaining
the winner-take-all practice) the voting power of
individuals is equalized across states? - One obvious (but constitutionally impermissible)
possibility is to redraw state boundaries so that
all states have the same number of voters (and
electoral votes). - This creates a system of uniform representation.
- Methodological Note since the following chart
compares voting power under different
apportionments, voting power must be expressed in
absolute (rather than rescaled) terms.
62Individual Voting Power when States Have Equal
Population (Versus Apportionment Proportional to
Actual Population)
63Uniform Representation
- Note that equalizing state populations not only
- equalizes individual voting power across states,
but also - raises mean individual voting power, relative to
that under apportionment based on the actual
unequal populations. - While this pattern appears to be typically true,
it is not invariably true, - e.g., if state populations are uniformly
distributed over a wide range. - However, individual voting power still falls
below that under direct popular vote. - So the fact that mean individual voting power
under the Electoral College falls below that
under direct popular vote - is not due to the fact that states are unequal in
population and electoral votes, and - is evidently intrinsic to a two-tier system.
- Van Kolpin, Voting Power Under Uniform
Representation, Economics Bulletin, 2003.
64Electoral Vote Apportionment to Equalize
Individual Voting Power (cont.)
- Given that state boundaries are immutable, can we
apportion electoral votes so that (without
changing state populations and with the
winner-take-all practice preserved) the voting
power of individuals is equalized across states? - Yes (at least to close approximation), electoral
votes can be apportioned by applying the Penrose
Square Root Rule in reverse (as an engineering
principle, rather than as a descriptive law) - Individual voting power is equalized when
electoral votes are apportioned so that state
voting power is proportional to the square root
of state population. - But such Penrose Apportionment is tricky, because
what must be made proportional to population is
not electoral votes (what we directly apportion)
but state voting power (a consequence of the
apportionment of electoral votes).
65(Approximately) Equalized Individual Voting Power
66EV Apportionment to Equalize VP (cont.)
- These two methods of apportionment that equalize
individual voting power equalize it at
(essentially) the same level, namely - 0.00005785 (vs. 0.00007215 for direct popular
vote). - If the Penrose square root rule is used but
apportion-ment of electoral votes must be in
whole numbers, - individual voting power is imperfectly equalized
(especially among small state voters), and - mean individual voting power is reduced ever so
slightly (to 0.00005784).
67State Voting Power When EVs are Apportioned on
the Basis of SQRT of Population (cont.)
- Under such square-root apportionment rules, the
outcome of the 2004 Presidential elections would
be - Fractional Apportionment Bush 307.688, Kerry
230.312. - Whole-Number Apportionment Bush 307, Kerry 231
- Actual Apportionment Bush 286, Kerry 252
- Electoral Votes proportional to popular vote
Bush 275.695, Kerry 262.305 - Clearly equalizing individual voting power is not
the same thing as making the electoral vote
(more) proportional to the popular vote.