Title: Standards Wars in Wireless Communications
1Standards Wars in Wireless Communications
David J. Salant March, 2005
2Introduction
- Mobile wireless communications industry has been
locked in a series of standards battles for
approximately 20 years. - Currently, there are over 1.3 billion people
using cellular and PCS service in the world. - Gross new adds are approximately 500 M per year,
and annual IP royalties likely exceed 5 billion. - Licensing fees accrue to developers of standards
in handsets and in terminal equipment. - Network effects suggesting standardization
include communication between individuals,
geographical area of coverage and cost of
complementary products (handsets). - Telecommunications policy makers adopt different
approaches - Market approaches market can find the standard.
- Government mandate.
- Trade associations, not always voluntary.
- Competitive dynamics suggest tipping eventually
result in a standard. - Yet, at least in wireless, the market has yet to
settle on any one standard for very long. -
3Some Related Literature
- Arthurs (1989) tipping effect of network
externalities. - Economides, Matutes and Regibeau on
compatibility. - Church and Gandal, on variety of complementary
components with network effects. - Farrell Saloner, Katz and Shapiro, Budd, Harris
Vickers and Cabral Riordan on competitive
dynamics and network effects. - David Greenstein survey types of standard
setting processes. - Farrell on converters.
4The Wireless Industry
- The EC has mandated a harmonized standard, GSM,
for 2nd generation mobile services - North America, and other countries, have allowed
the market to determine standards - In North America, and especially the US, there is
coverage with multiple 2g standards - Economic theory, and experience in other
industries, suggest that mandated standards has
some advantages and market standards has other
advantages
5Competing 2nd Generation Standards
- First wave of digital, second generation,
wireless standards includes - GSM Global Standard for Mobile Communication,
based on a time division multiple access protocol - CDMA Code Division Multiple Access or IS95
- TDMA/DAMPS Time Division Multiple Access or
Digital AMPS, another standard based on a time
division multiple access protocol
61G to 2G Migration in the US and EC
- The US mandated the analog AMPS standard for 1G
- In the EC, countries did not use a uniform
approach, using both AMPS and NMTS and in
different bands - EC chose GSM for 2G
- US chose market based approach
72G in US
- In US the FCC
- Initially allocated two, 25 MHz, or 2x12.5 MHz,
licenses for 1G AMPS networks - Mandated the AMPS, analog, standard
- Subsequently, FCC allocated 120 MHz or 2x60 MHz
for PCS - First 60 MHz in 51 MTAs auctioned in 4Q 94,
service began sometime later - Subsequently, additional 60 MHz auctioned in a
series of auctions beginning 95 in 493 BTAs - Most recent auction was concluded in January 2001
- No PCS standard mandated, only out of band
interference, service (had to be PCS) and modest
build out requirements - FCC allowed refarming of AMPS frequencies
82G in the EC
- The EU has delegated choice of wireless standards
first to CEPT and then to ETSI - GSM was selected in the 900 MHz band in 1987 as
the harmonized standard - GSM service was introduced in EC as early as 1989
(in Germany) - DCS1800, an upbanded version of GSM, was
introduced in 1993 - EC had over 1M GSM subs by 1993
- By 1995 all EC countries had at least one GSM
license in operation
92G Elsewhere
- A number of other countries have followed EC
(e.g., Greece, Turkey, South Africa, most of
Eastern Europe) - Some countries allowed multiple standards
- Australia started with only GSM and has now
allocated spectrum which is being used for CDMA - Japan has PHS standard unique to Japan
- China and India have permitted allocated spectrum
for both GSM and CDMA - Israel has TDMA, GSM, and CDMA
10The Competition
- Competition occurs at several levels
- Network infrastructure Lucent, Motorola,
Nortel, Ericsson, Siemens, Alcatel. - Terminals/handsets Motorola, Sony/Ericsson,
Nokia, Samsung, Kyocera. - Operator
- Chipsets Qualcomm, Nokia, TI, NTT
- IP Qualcomm, patent pool for GSM
- Network equipment and handsets are both spectrum
and technology specific.
112G to 3G in EU
- Initial ETSI Special Mobile Group (SMG) planned a
variant of 2G CDMA for 3G. - New 3G CDMA standard would be backwards
compatible with 2G CDMA. - Backwards compatibility would benefit US chipset
suppliers and also CDMA handset suppliers, which
were largely non-European. - European handset suppliers preferred
non-compatible standard.
12EU Spectrum Management Policy
- EU, and especially UK and Germany, were anxious
to allocate 3G spectrum. - Tipping effect of first to deploy a standard was
thought to have an effect on subsequent global
adoptions. - EU designates CEPT/ETSI to set telecom standards.
- ETSI voting power weighted by European turnover
- SMG decided to make a few small adjustments basic
3G CDMA standard - SMG included Nokia, Siemens and Ericsson.
- New 3G standard, UMTS aka WCDMA was incompatible
with basic 3G CDMA standard, renamed cdma2000 - US (QUALCOMM) complained
- ETSI standard setting policy explicitly favored
EU suppliers over non-EU ones. - ETSI standard setting process violated US/EU
competition policy treaty. - EU agreed to some modifications.
13Band Plan Conflicts
- Equipment is specific to bands and technology.
- For 1G,
- AMPS was deployed 824 849 x 869 894 MHz.
- EU used both AMPS and NMTS bands at 450MHz
- For 2G
- US 1G 1850 1910 x 1930 1990 MHz
- EU 880 915 x 925 970 MHz 1710 1785 x
1805 1880 MHz. - For 3G
- US TBD 700 MHz AWS (1710 1755 x 2110
2155 MHz) - EU 1920 1980 x 2110 2170 MHz
- EU has not allowed re-farming, US has
- Other countries left to decide.
- GSM works in US, CDMA not available for EU bands,
and has not been permitted in EU.
14Spectrum for Broadband Voice and Data Services
152G and 3G Spectrum Over 1700 MHz
16Coverage vs. Compatibility
- Theory is incomplete discusses network effects
and compatibility - Compatibility is of limited importance in
wireless standards - Matters to the extent that compatibility affects
production scale, and therefore costs, of network
infrastructure and terminals - Reduces risk of orphans, but does not eliminate
it, e.g., CT2 - Coverage determines value much more than
compatibility
17Mandated Standards vs. Market Determined Standards
- For Harmonization
- Costs, due uniformity
- Enhances coverage
- Reduced risk of orphan technology
- Reduced consumer uncertainty
- For Market Based Standards
- Competition
- Product/quality differential can enhance value
- Costs, due to competition
- No risk of locking into wrong standard
- Harmonization can lead to higher or lower
penetration - If harmonization improves end user welfare, it
should result in higher penetration, other things
equal
18Dynamic Factors
- When the market, and not regulatory mandate,
determines standards, early adoption decisions
can have a tipping effect - For wireless networks, interconnection means that
compatibility is not essential - Two or more standards can be viable, and tipping
effect is less persistent - When there are different firms deciding on
standards in different regions, the choice in one
region can affect optimal choice of standards by
all firms in another region
19Coordination Across Regions
- In each region, there are multiple licenses
available - With market based standards, different firms will
make decisions in each region - One firm will not usually want to adopt a
standard that will not have coverage in other
regions - Multiple equilibrium can exist, depending on the
sequencing of the decisions - Equilibrium can exist in which all standards are
in use in each region - Equilibrium can also exist in which there is
complete harmonization
20A Simple Duopoly Model
- Technology starts at base level, 0, and can
progress to new level 1. - Two periods, and each has two stages.
- First stage firms determine whether or not they
will produce to the same specifications. - Second stage, firms invest in RD
- Probability of success ½ ?2
- Let ?S(j) each firms profit with a common
technology j 0, 1. - Let ?D(j,k) profit for a firm with technology j
when its rival has technology k and they
disagree. - We assume
- ?S(j) gt ?D(j,j), j 0,1 and 2 ?S(1) gt ?D(0,1)
?D(1,0) - At state (1,0) or (0,1), bargaining is costless
and perfectly efficient, so that industry profits
are the same as at (1,1).
21Model Features
- If one firm gets new technology, it will earn an
advantage. - Firms cannot capture all benefits of investment.
- Can be under-incentives to invest if firms agree
to one standard.
22Incentives to Disagree
- Proposition
- If ?S(0) - ?D(0,0) is small , then
standardization occurs in all states other than
(0,0). - In other words, firms have incentives to
deviate from any single proposed standard. - Result does not require differentiation or
inefficient bargaining. - Result should extend to dynamic models.
23Data
- Data for 1994-9 from 25 countries, Australia,
Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Hong Kong, Iceland, Ireland,
Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg,
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal,
Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom,
United States. - Â Six countries had multiple standards, Australia,
Hong Kong, Japan, Israel, New Zealand, and the
USA - Test to see if impact of multiple standards on
penetration was positive or negative - In most cases, multiple standards meant possibly
higher overall market penetration
24Variables
- Number of subscribers in each year
- Price is cost in US for 120 minutes of peak
service - Analog dummy is 1(0) if analog service was
(un)available - Multiple was 1(0) if multiple (one) digital
standards were available - Connect is the connection charge for residential
service - Payphone_100 is number of payphones available per
100 people - Also, Yn, n 1995,6,7,8,9, is a year n dummy,
POP is population, GDP_capita is per capita gross
domestic product
25Summary Statistics
26Model 1
Dependent variable, subscribers/log subscribers
27Model 2 Results
Dependent Var. Log of Installed Base R2 .929,
Adj. R2 .923
28Model 3 Results
Dependent Var. penetration R2 .870, Adj. R2
.860
29Model 4 Results
Dependent Var. penetration R2 .718, Adj. R2
.655