Essential Facilities and Trinko: Should Antitrust and Regulation be Combined

1 / 12
About This Presentation
Title:

Essential Facilities and Trinko: Should Antitrust and Regulation be Combined

Description:

Regulation constrains profit at monopoly level ... Regulation shifts out antitrust 'demand curve' ... Trinko gets that right at least outside regulation ... –

Number of Views:54
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 13
Provided by: timb178
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Essential Facilities and Trinko: Should Antitrust and Regulation be Combined


1
Essential Facilities and Trinko Should
Antitrust and Regulation be Combined?
  • Tim Brennan
  • Professor, Public Policy and Economics, UMBC
  • Senior Fellow, Resources for the Future,
    Washington, DC
  • brennan_at_umbc.edu
  • THE ENDURING LESSONS OF THE BREAKUP OF ATTA
    TWENTY-FIVE YEAR RETROSPECTIVE
  • Center for Technology, Innovation, and
    CompetitionUniversity of Pennsylvania Law School
  • April 18, 2008

2
Outline
  • U.S. v. ATT, Verizon v. Trinko same but for
    outcome
  • Effective change from plain repugnance standard
  • Not just dicta Credit Suisse
  • Regulation matters From Baxter to Klein
  • Regulation, antitrust as complements, not
    substitutes
  • Essential facilities The hypothetical
    regulator test
  • EFD, Trinko both gt Same agency does AT,
    regulation
  • A good idea?

3
The same case, but for the outcome
4
Changes in attitudes from 1983
  • MCI v. ATT, 708 F.2d 1081, 1102 (7th Circ.,
    1983)
  • It is well established, however, that regulated
    industries "are not per se exempt from the
    Sherman Act." Georgia v. Pennsylvania R.R., 324
    U.S. 439, 456 (1945). "Repeal of the antitrust
    laws by implication is not favored and not
    casually to be allowed. Only where there is a
    'plain repugnancy between the antitrust and
    regulatory provisions' will repeal be implied."
    Gordon v. New York Stock Exchange, 422 U.S. 659,
    682 (1975), (quoting United States v.
    Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 350-51
    (1963). As a further limitation, repeal is to be
    regarded as implied only where necessary to make
    the regulatory scheme work, and even then, only
    to the minimum extent necessary. Silver v. New
    York Stock Exchange, 373 U.S. 341, 357 (1963).
    Citations abbreviated.

5
to 2004
  • Verizon v. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398, 406 (2004)
  • Indeed, a detailed regulatory scheme such as that
    created by the 1996 Act ordinarily raises the
    question whether the regulated entities are not
    shielded from antitrust scrutiny altogether by
    the doctrine of implied immunity. In some
    respects the enforcement scheme set up by the
    1996 Act is a good candidate for implication of
    antitrust immunity, to avoid the real possibility
    of judgments conflicting with the agency's
    regulatory scheme "that might be voiced by courts
    exercising jurisdiction under the antitrust
    laws."
  • Congress, however, precluded that interpretation.
    Section 601(b)(1) of the 1996 Act is an
    antitrust-specific saving clause providing that
    "nothing in this Act or the amendments made by
    this Act shall be construed to modify, impair, or
    supersede the applicability of any of the
    antitrust laws." This bars a finding of implied
    immunity. Citations omitted.

6
Not just dicta
  • Credit Suisse v. Glen Billing, 127 S. Ct. 2383,
    2389, 2394 (2007)
  • Where regulatory statutes are silent in respect
    to antitrust, however, courts must determine
    whether, and in what respects, they implicitly
    preclude application of the antitrust laws. Those
    determinations may vary from statute to statute,
    depending upon the relation between the antitrust
    laws and the regulatory program set forth in the
    particular statute, and the relation of the
    specific conduct at issue to both sets of laws.
  • to permit antitrust actions such as the present
    one allegations of collusion still threatens
    serious securities-related harm. For one thing,
    an unusually serious legal line-drawing problem
    remains unabated. In the present context only a
    fine, complex, detailed line separates activity
    that the SEC permits or encourages (for which
    respondents must concede antitrust immunity) from
    activity that the SEC must (and inevitably will)
    forbid (and which, on respondents' theory, should
    be open to antitrust attack).

7
The role of regulation From Baxter to Klein
  • Bill Baxter, regarding U.S. v. IBM
  • The IBM case is without merit and should be
    dismissed. Jan. 8, 1982 (Christopher Byron,
    Time, Jan. 18, 1982)
  • Same date as announcement of divestiture
    settlement in U.S. v. ATT
  • Joel Klein, supporting (then) accepted proposed
    divestiture in U.S. v. Microsoft
  • I don't want to make light of it, it's a big
    thing, but it is a one-time division that will
    then enable the companies to grow and move on. If
    you think about it -- think about the ATT
    breakup again. You know how long they tried to
    regulate ATT (NewsHour, PBS, June 8, 2000)
  • Unfortunately, Microsoft not regulated

8
Regulation, antitrust as complements
  • Why does antitrust matter more in regulated
    sectors?
  • Regulation constrains profit at monopoly level
  • Incentive to evade through normally benign
    vertical integration
  • Discrimination Tying unregulated service to
    regulated service
  • Cross-subsidization Misallocating costs to
    drive up regulated rates, capture profit
    elsewhere
  • Otherwise incredible predatory threats become
    credible
  • Baxters rationale Regulation shifts out
    antitrust demand curve
  • But who should do antitrust in regulated
    industries?

9
That brings us to essential facilities
  • Trinko gets that rightat least outside
    regulation
  • But how do we know when a facility is essential?
  • The long-standing Section 2 market power
    conundrum
  • Price, elasticity doesnt work Cellophane
    fallacy
  • Theory asks What would a firm do facing a small
    but significant, non-transitory reduction in
    price?
  • No market power Reduce output
  • Market power Increase output
  • Hypothetical regulator implementation problems
  • Data on exogenous price limit rarely if ever
    present
  • Puts regulatory cart before EF horse

10
EFD, Trinkos common institutional implication
  • EFD Antitrust agencies should be price
    regulators
  • The only remedy is regulation
  • Hypothetical regulation needed to identify EF
  • Trinko Regulatory agencies should enforce
    antitrust laws
  • Only a savings clause precluded simple implied
    immunity
  • The regulator can do it, if authority in place
  • Supported by Credit Suisse
  • Both say, So, lets put them together!

11
Is combining roles a good idea?
  • It could be, after all
  • Complementarity gt potential virtues in
    coordination
  • Nature of the Firm
  • On the other side The culture clash
  • Do we want antitrust agencies thinking about
    central planning rather than markets as an
    option?
  • Do we want regulators responsible for policing
    competitive performance in unregulated markets?
  • The debate surely will go on

12
Read more about it?
  • Why Regulated Firms Should Be Kept Out Of
    Unregulated Markets Understanding the
    Divestiture in U.S. v. ATT, Antitrust Bulletin
    32 (1987) 741-93.
  • Does the Theory Behind U.S. v. ATT Still Apply
    Today? Antitrust Bulletin 40 (1995) 45582.
  • Making Sense of the Telecommunications Act of
    1996, Industrial and Corporate Change 5 (1996)
    94161.
  • Promoting Telephone Competition A Simpler Way?
    in Gillete, Susan and Ingo Vogelsang (eds.),
    Competition, Regulation, and Convergence Current
    Trends in Telecommunications Policy Research
    (Mahwah, NJ Lawrence Erlbaum, 1999) 85103.
  • Do Easy Cases Make Bad Law? Antitrust Innovation
    or Missed Opportunities in U.S. v. Microsoft,
    George Washington Law Review 69 (2001)
    1042-1102.
  • Regulation and Competition as Complements, in
    Crew, Michael and Menahem Spiegel (eds.),
    Obtaining the Best from Regulation and
    Competition (Norwell, MA Kluwer Academic Press,
    2004) 1-20.
  • Trinko v. Baxter The Demise of U.S. v. ATT,
    Antitrust Bulletin 50 (2006) 635-64.
  • 2006 in Competition Policy and Enforcement An
    Economic Perspective (with Alan Gunderson),
    Canadian Competition Record 22, no. 4 (Summer
    2007) 67-93.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com