Title: Econ 240C
1Econ 240C
2Part I. VAR
- Does the Federal Funds Rate Affect Capacity
Utilization?
3- The Federal Funds Rate is one of the principal
monetary instruments of the Federal Reserve - Does it affect the economy in real terms, as
measured by capacity utilization
4Preliminary Analysis
5The Time Series, Monthly, January 1967through
May 2003
6Federal Funds Rate July 1954-April 2006
7Capacity Utilization Manufacturing Jan. 1972-
April 2006
8Changes in FFR Capacity Utilization
9Contemporaneous Correlation
10Dynamics Cross-correlation
11Granger Causality
12Granger Causality
13Granger Causality
14Estimation of VAR
15(No Transcript)
16(No Transcript)
17(No Transcript)
18(No Transcript)
19(No Transcript)
20(No Transcript)
21(No Transcript)
22(No Transcript)
23Estimation Results
- OLS Estimation
- each series is positively autocorrelated
- lags 1 and 24 for dcapu
- lags 1, 2, 7, 9, 13, 16
- each series depends on the other
- dcapu on dffr negatively at lags 10, 12, 17, 21
- dffr on dcapu positively at lags 1, 2, 9, 10 and
negatively at lag 12
24Correlogram of DFFR
25Correlogram of DCAPU
26We Have Mutual Causality, But We Already Knew That
DCAPU
DFFR
27Interpretation
- We need help
- Rely on assumptions
28What If
- What if there were a pure shock to dcapu
- as in the primitive VAR, a shock that only
affects dcapu immediately
29Primitive VAR
30The Logic of What If
- A shock, edffr , to dffr affects dffr
immediately, but if dcapu depends
contemporaneously on dffr, then this shock will
affect it immediately too - so assume b1 is zero, then dcapu depends only on
its own shock, edcapu , first period - But we are not dealing with the primitive, but
have substituted out for the contemporaneous
terms - Consequently, the errors are no longer pure but
have to be assumed pure
31DCAPU
shock
DFFR
32Standard VAR
- dcapu(t) (a1 b1 a2)/(1- b1 b2) (g11 b1
g21)/(1- b1 b2) dcapu(t-1) (g12 b1
g22)/(1- b1 b2) dffr(t-1) (d1 b1 d2 )/(1-
b1 b2) x(t) (edcapu (t) b1 edffr (t))/(1-
b1 b2) - But if we assume b1 0,
- then dcapu(t) a1 g11 dcapu(t-1) g12
dffr(t-1) d1 x(t) edcapu (t) -
33- Note that dffr still depends on both shocks
- dffr(t) (b2 a1 a2)/(1- b1 b2) (b2 g11
g21)/(1- b1 b2) dcapu(t-1) (b2 g12
g22)/(1- b1 b2) dffr(t-1) (b2 d1 d2 )/(1-
b1 b2) x(t) (b2 edcapu (t) edffr (t))/(1- b1
b2) - dffr(t) (b2 a1 a2)(b2 g11 g21)
dcapu(t-1) (b2 g12 g22) dffr(t-1) (b2 d1
d2 ) x(t) (b2 edcapu (t) edffr (t))
34Reality
edcapu (t)
DCAPU
shock
DFFR
edffr (t)
35What If
edcapu (t)
DCAPU
shock
DFFR
edffr (t)
36EVIEWS
37(No Transcript)
38Interpretations
- Response of dcapu to a shock in dcapu
- immediate and positive autoregressive nature
- Response of dffr to a shock in dffr
- immediate and positive autoregressive nature
- Response of dcapu to a shock in dffr
- starts at zero by assumption that b1 0,
- interpret as Fed having no impact on CAPU
- Response of dffr to a shock in dcapu
- positive and then damps out
- interpret as Fed raising FFR if CAPU rises
39Change the Assumption Around
40What If
edcapu (t)
DCAPU
shock
DFFR
edffr (t)
41Standard VAR
- dffr(t) (b2 a1 a2)/(1- b1 b2) (b2 g11
g21)/(1- b1 b2) dcapu(t-1) (b2 g12
g22)/(1- b1 b2) dffr(t-1) (b2 d1 d2 )/(1-
b1 b2) x(t) (b2 edcapu (t) edffr (t))/(1- b1
b2) - if b2 0
- then, dffr(t) a2 g21 dcapu(t-1) g22
dffr(t-1) d2 x(t) edffr (t)) - but, dcapu(t) (a1 b1 a2) (g11 b1 g21)
dcapu(t-1) (g12 b1 g22) dffr(t-1) (d1
b1 d2 ) x(t) (edcapu (t) b1 edffr (t))
42(No Transcript)
43Interpretations
- Response of dcapu to a shock in dcapu
- immediate and positive autoregressive nature
- Response of dffr to a shock in dffr
- immediate and positive autoregressive nature
- Response of dcapu to a shock in dffr
- is positive (not - ) initially but then damps to
zero - interpret as Fed having no or little control of
CAPU - Response of dffr to a shock in dcapu
- starts at zero by assumption that b2 0,
- interpret as Fed raising FFR if CAPU rises
44Conclusions
- We come to the same model interpretation and
policy conclusions no matter what the ordering,
i.e. no matter which assumption we use, b1 0, or
b2 0. - So, accept the analysis
45Understanding through Simulation
- We can not get back to the primitive fron the
standard VAR, so we might as well simplify
notation - y(t) (a1 b1 a2)/(1- b1 b2) (g11 b1
g21)/(1- b1 b2) y(t-1) (g12 b1 g22)/(1- b1
b2) w(t-1) (d1 b1 d2 )/(1- b1 b2) x(t)
(edcapu (t) b1 edffr (t))/(1- b1 b2) - becomes y(t) a1 b11 y(t-1) c11 w(t-1) d1
x(t) e1(t)
46- And w(t) (b2 a1 a2)/(1- b1 b2) (b2 g11
g21)/(1- b1 b2) y(t-1) (b2 g12 g22)/(1-
b1 b2) w(t-1) (b2 d1 d2 )/(1- b1 b2) x(t)
(b2 edcapu (t) edffr (t))/(1- b1 b2) - becomes w(t) a2 b21 y(t-1) c21 w(t-1) d2
x(t) e2(t) -
47Numerical Example
y(t) 0.7 y(t-1) 0.2 w(t-1) e1(t) w(t)
0.2 y(t-1) 0.7 w(t-1) e2(t) where e1(t)
ey (t) 0.8 ew (t) e2(t) ew (t)
48- Generate ey(t) and ew(t) as white noise processes
using nrnd and where ey(t) and ew(t) are
independent. Scale ey(t) so that the variances of
e1(t) and e2(t) are equal - ey(t) 0.6 nrnd and
- ew(t) nrnd (different nrnd)
- Note the correlation of e1(t) and e2(t) is 0.8
49Analytical Solution Is Possible
- These numerical equations for y(t) and w(t) could
be solved for y(t) as a distributed lag of e1(t)
and a distributed lag of e2(t), or, equivalently,
as a distributed lag of ey(t) and a distributed
lag of ew(t) - However, this is an example where simulation is
easier
50Simulated Errors e1(t) and e2(t)
51Simulated Errors e1(t) and e2(t)
52Estimated Model
53(No Transcript)
54(No Transcript)
55(No Transcript)
56(No Transcript)
57(No Transcript)
58Y to shock in w Calculated 0.8 0.76 0.70
59Impact of shock in w on variable y
60(No Transcript)