Title: Competition audit of the economic policy making process
1Competition audit of the economic policy making
process
Advocacy and Capacity Building on Competition
Policy and Law in Asia (7up2 Project) 16-17
August 2005, Hanoi, Vietnam
- Dr. Lucian Cernat
- UNCTAD
- lucian.cernat_at_unctad.org
2 Contents
- 1. Competition audit role and priorities
- 2. Key areas for competition audit
- - horizontal policies (trade, FDI, etc.)
- - sectoral policies
- 3. Way forward
3Competition audit
- Part of competition advocacy, together with
public advocacy - not only private anti-competitive conduct like
collusion and abuse of dominance, that can hinder
competition but also regulatory intervention and
rule making by public officials - Competition agencies (CAs) - active in promoting
competitive, market-oriented policy-making and
regulatory processes
4Key areas for competition audit
- General economic policies
- Trade policies (tariffs, AD, CVD, standards,
etc.) - Promote pro-competitive FDI
- RD policies (transfer of technology, licensing,
patents) - Regulated sectors
- promoting competition in sectors where
privatization has left regulated monopolies with
the incentive and ability to hinder competition
in their base and related markets
5Potential gains from competition audit of
economic policy making
- When accompanied by competition policy, trade and
FDI openness may have a greater contribution to - technological spillovers and increased
productivity as a result of economies of scale - increased production efficiency as a result of
further specialization in accordance with
national comparative advantage - efficiency gains due to increased competition
6Trade, FDI, and competition linkages
71. Why competition audit of trade policies?
- Both theoretically and empirically uncertain
(e.g. under collusion, increased imports lead to
higher price-cost margins - Although multilateral trade liberalization and
regional integration may provide significant
welfare gains, there is still need for
complementary regulatory and competition policies
to ensure that the predicted benefits are not
impaired by private anti-competitive practices
8Potential gains from trade liberalization
- At regional level
- Several South-South RTAs more than doubled trade
among members (Cernat 2001) - At multilateral level
- Agriculture liberalization, elimination of tariff
peaks and escalation affecting developing country
exports, as well as other trade-distorting
policies are important objectives in the DDA. - E.g. 50 per cent reduction of tariffs in
agriculture would increase world welfare by about
20 billion ( 13,4 billion for developing
countries) in all sectors, will double the
amount (Cernat, Laird, Turrini 2003). - But In 1997, developing countries imported US
81 billion of goods from industries which had
been affected by price fixing conspiracies during
the 1990s (Levenstein and Suslow 2001), i.e.
approx. 20-25 billion in excessive prices
(Jenny 2003).
9Example 1 Costa Rican 1996 case
- Scaffolding manufacturers teamed up to request
the Ministry of Commerce to raise import tariffs - in return, they offered undertakings not to raise
their prices for certain time - the MoC agreed
- The CA declared the agreement harmful to
competition and imposed fines upon the colluding
firms
10Example 2 US ferrosilicon cartel
- In early 1990s the largest US based producers of
ferrosilicon formed a cartel, set a collusive
price and withdrew capacity from the market. - The drop in their sales was used to prove injury
from dumping and AD duties were imposed in
against existing foreign competitors.
11Why competition audit of FDI policies?
- As in the case of trade in goods and services,
open and contestable markets for FDI do not
destroy all market power of incumbents - a wide range of RBPs - both horizontal and
vertical - could affect potential entrants'
investment decisions and impede FDI flows - Moreover, MNCs strong competitive position can
lead to anti-competitive structures and behaviour
and thus to the establishment of new entry
barriers, especially when FDI is accompanied by
MAs
12Trade, FDI and competition the case of services
- Services represent the fastest growing sector of
the global economy and account for 60 of global
output, 30 of global employment and nearly 20
of global trade. - more than half of world trade in commercial
services is made up of travel and transportation
services - The close relationships between services trade,
investment and competition policy have long been
recognized, given the underlying role played by
the services sector in supplying other economic
activities
13Example 1 the telecom sector
- FDI barriers to entry in foreign markets reduce
competition. - This is especially important in the case of
services and other non-tradeables.
Source Warren, T. 2000, 'The identification of
impediments to trade and investment in
telecommunications services', in Findlay, C. and
Warren, T. (eds.) 2000, Impediments to Trade in
Services Measurement and Policy Implications,
Routledge, London and New York. Notes The
restrictiveness indexes are calculated from
Warren 2000. The domestic and foreign
restrictiveness index scores range from 0 to 1.
The higher the score, the greater are the
restrictions for an economy.
14Example 2 the New Economy
- Improving the competitive environment by 50
(based on World Bank ranking) may increase
Internet intensity by approximately 30 and
mobile phone subscriptions by 63. - Without competition policy, the same progress
would require about nineteen years of economic
growth at average rate for low-income countries
(2.8)
15Example 2 the New Economy
Source Cernat, L. (2003) Trade and Competition
Policy in the Digital EraTowards a Regulatory
Framework for Global e-Business, Journal of World
Investment 46, pp.988-1010.
16Competition agency vs. sectoral regulators Is
there an optimal solution?
- One size does not fit all, but some rules of
thumb - Any specific sectoral exemptions from the
competition law for any of the regulated sectors? - If yes, sectoral regulators should have a leading
role - If not, CAs in charge of anti-competitive
practices, in cooperation with the
sector-specific regulators - In both cases
- neet to have comity principles between sectoral
regulators and CAs - Allow for competition audit during judicial
review, including for regulated sectors - Most importantly binding recommendations
17Binding recommendations
Source Based on ICN (2004)
18Conclusions
- OBJECTIVES
- Competition policy should become an integral part
of the broader macroeconomic policy apparatus - Thus pro-competitive thinking can better inform
the many other policy areas that can promote
economic growth and competitiveness - SOME REQUIREMENTS
- Credibility
- Formal but also informal cooperation mechanisms
with other agencies
19Credibility
- Advocacy is probably more effective when it is
one part of a larger strategy that includes
enforcement. - But many CAs have been unable to establish a
credible record of penalties that would function
as an effective deterrent. - E.g. the Mexican experience during its first 10
years, only 10 of the fines imposed by the CA
have been collected - However, even enforcement failures may support
competition audit. E.g. if an action brought
against clearly anti-competitive behaviour must
be dismissed because of a regulatory exclusion,
the failure can support a call to eliminate the
exclusion
20Informal cooperation rather than formal adversity
- Competition principles could be integrated into
other regulatory policies more effectively if
formal competition audit is supplemented by
informal processes - staff-level consultations
- shared values and ideas among political-level
appointees - Exchanges of staff
21What kind of competition audit?
- Establishing adequate competition audit
mechanisms that - are responsive to market complexities
- are cognizant of proper pacing and sequencing of
reform - adopt participatory, multi-stakeholder approaches
in the formulation of policies - Strengthen enforcement actions