Title: P3s IN CANADA: THEORY AND EVIDENCE Aidan Vining
1P3s IN CANADA THEORY AND EVIDENCEAidan Vining
Anthony Boardman
2THIS PAPER
- This paper examines 10 infrastructure P3s in
Canada (basically the ones we could get
reasonable information on and which are somewhat
complete. - P3s really began to take hold in the mid-1990s.
- What has happened to these initial P3s?
- How should we judge their effectiveness?
- What lessons can be learned for future?
- These questions are important for Canadian policy
because emerging case study evidence in a number
of countries, including the United Kingdom
(Broadbent and Laughlin, 2004 Grout and Stevens,
2003 230 Pollitt, 2005 Shaoul, 2005), Ireland
(Reeves, 2003), the Netherlands (Klijn and
Teisman, 2003), Denmark (Greve and Ejersbo, 2003)
and Australia (English, 2005 Hodge, 2005)
suggests considerable dissatisfaction with P3
outcomes.
3PAPER OUTLINE
- Reviews the posited major government (normative)
rationales for P3s. - Reformulates and broadens the normative rationale
to adopt a broader view of costs. - Presents a positive theory perspective on P3s
based on public choice theory, transaction cost
economics, emerging empirical evidence from other
jurisdictions, and experience with
contracting-out by government and mixed
enterprises. - Presents the case study evidence (10 Canadian
infrastructure P3s). - Assesses the case evidence in terms of the
positive theory perspective. - Bottom line transaction costs, including ex ante
contracting and negotiation costs, as well as ex
post costs (i.e. after formal contract
agreement), such as monitoring and renegotiation
costs, have proven to be high. These costs may be
borne either by the private sector or
government. There can also be significant
external costs. - Conclusion P3s work best when they are closest
to old-fashioned Build-Transfer construction
contracts.
4SUMMARY OF FINDINGS
- Canadian governments have generally found it
difficult to effectively reduce either their
budgetary risk exposure through the use of P3s. - At the same time, the for-profit private sector
partners have had difficulty generating adequate
rates of return, although this is a tentative
conclusion as they have usually had incentives to
publicly emphasize losses and to be secretive
about profits. - One surprisingly common outcome is the
dissolution of the P3 more quickly than
envisioned in the original contract, whether
through a government buy-out, private entity
bankruptcy or otherwise. - An even commoner outcome is protracted conflict,
with high contracting costs borne by one party or
both. - These findings throw into doubt the social
utility of P3s as a mechanism for delivering
public infrastructure in contexts where
transaction costs or negative externalities can
be expected to be high.
5Major Canadian P3 Projects
6GOVERNMENT RATIONALES FOR P3s
- Governments have used 3 major (articulated)
rationales for entering into P3s (Vining, - Boardman, and Poschmann, 2006)
- The minimization of on-budget government
expenditures and/or formal government debt. - The provision of infrastructure and services at
lower cost as a result of scale and learning
efficiencies and other sources of technical
efficiency of large, specialized firms. Also
superior incentives of these firms versus public
sector bureaucracies because of X-inefficiency
(Frantz, 1992). - Reduce the public sectors risk exposure to
construction costs, maintenance costs and usage
levels. The U.K. government has been a leader in
arguing that the various dimensions of risk
transfer should be the primary benefit from P3s.
- A fourth usually unstated rationale is that
governments believe (or at least want to believe)
that private-sector operation means that it is
politically easier to impose user fees, resulting
in lower net budgetary outlays to government.
The reasoning is that voters are more willing to
accept that the private sector needs to raise
revenue to cover its costs, repay its debt or
make a profit than to accept the argument that
the public sector needs to do so.
7OFF-BUDGET RATIONALE FOR P3s
- There are clearly political benefits of keeping
expenditures and/or formal debt off-the-books
(Marlow Joulfaian, 1989 Joulfaian Marlow,
1991) in most circumstances. - However, the underlying economic reality is not
altered public sector (whether government or
users) have to pay for it (Quiggen, 2005).
8OFF-BUDGET RATIONALE FOR P3s (continued)
- P3s obviously can spread governmental payment
obligations over a longer period of time. - Per se, however, this does not reduce the present
value of costs and is therefore a weak normative
rationale for P3 usage. - Caveat 1 time-shifting could be justified for
very long-lived projects on intergenerational
equity and efficiency grounds. - Caveat 2 P3 as mechanism may also be somewhat
justified by institutional barriers that thwart
explicit government capital financing mechanisms.
However, these barriers are best addressed
directly. - In practice, 3. and 4. are rarely the budget
arguments that are made by governments.
9COST-EFFICIENCY RATIONALE FOR P3s
- Private sector firms can have superior scale,
scope and learning economies because they are
more specialized and larger. - This cost advantage is greatest vis-à-vis smaller
provincial, regional or municipal governments. - Cost advantage likely to be most significant for
construction (rather than operations/maintenance).
- May have a cost advantage in terms of financing
costs because of greater access to better
expertise on pricing risk consequently ability
to lower financing costs - Also superior incentives (given well-designed
contract) to reduce/minimize costs likely to be
most significant in dynamic aspects of projects,
such as latest production technology. - Public sector monopoly bureau employees usually
have weak incentives to forecast costs or use
levels accurately. - This rationale is buttressed by weak government
performance on controlling costs (Flyvbjerg, Holm
Buhl, 2002, etc.). - However, really big caveat first-order result of
lower costs is higher private sector profits
rather than lower public sector costs.
10RISK EXPOSURE RATIONALE FOR P3s
- Specialized private sector firm may be able to
spread risk over a greater number of similar
projects. - Public sector, however, is usually able to spread
risk over a greater number of dissimilar
projects. - Either way, not a great normative rationale for
P3s. - Caveat except to the degree that the private
sector is more efficient at pricing and
allocating the risk.
11REFORMULATION OF COST-EFFICIENCY RATIONALE
- Problem with the cost-efficiency argument as a
normative rationale is that its normal focus on
production costs is too narrow. - First, needs to include transaction costs (TC)
the costs of negotiating, monitoring and
re-negotiating contracts. These often do not show
up as project costs. - Second, needs to include external costs (and
benefits) deadweight losses from pricing,
project failures, etc.
12TC PERSPECTIVE
- Transaction cost economics (TCE) provides a
useful framework for addressing the components of
total social costs. - TCE emphasizes that total social costs equal
production costs plus transaction costs
(Williamson, 1975). - Transaction costs (TC) include the cost of
negotiating, monitoring and, if necessary,
re-negotiating contracts with profit-maximizing
firms. - TC language is more appropriate than agency
language because P3s have the character of a
relationship between independent organizational
entities. Agency, or principal-agent theory,
language is appropriate for intra-organizational
hierarchical contexts.
13APPROPRIATE COST-EFFICIENCY CRITERION
- This suggests the following criterion
- Minimize the sum of production costs, transaction
costs and net externalities (holding constant
quality). - This then raises the question How are P3s likely
to perform in terms of this broader formulation? - To address this, we need a positive theory
perspective.
14WHOS MAXIMIZING WHAT?
- While the language of partnership is endemic to
P3s, the basic premise of this paper is that the
public and private participants have conflicting
interests (Teisman Klijn, 2002 Reeves, 2003
Trailer et al., 2004). - The two objective functions
- Private sector participants wish to maximize
risk-adjusted profits. - Public sector participants wish to minimize the
sum of expected on-budget net public expenditures
and political costs.
15NUANCES OF THE OFs
- The nuances in these objective functions are
important - Risk-adjusted aspect of private sector
participants They are willing to forego profits
if they can reduce risk sufficiently. - Indeed, private sector participants may be
considerably more risk-averse than public sector
participants expect, at least ex ante. This is
especially so with use/revenue risk because (1)
they are not familiar with it (2) They recognize
that it is largely controlled by public sector
actors (even absent opportunism by their partner)
(3) It opens them up to greater opportunism. As a
result, the private sector requires a high
premium to accept risk. - In order to minimize risk, sophisticated private
sector partners are likely to (1) form
stand-alone P3 corporations, thereby reducing
their worst-case costs by declaring the
stand-alone corporation bankrupt, if necessary
and/or by (2) limit their equity participation
through the utilization of extensive third-party
debt financing (Roll and Verbeke, 1998).
16THE CASE STUDIES
- We able to review ten Canadian P3 projects in
depth. - The case studies were selected because of the
availability of information, the size and profile
of the projects, the jurisdictional coverage that
they present and the lessons they offer for P3
contract theory, design and implementation. - They are Alberta Special Waste Management System
(Alberta), Confederation Bridge (Federal),
Highway 407 (Ontario), Highway 104 Western
Alignment Project (Nova Scotia), Evergreen Park
School (New Brunswick), OConnell Drive
Elementary School (Nova Scotia), Britannia Mine
Water Treatment Plant (British Columbia), Moncton
Water Treatment Facility (New Brunswick),
Cranbrook Multiplex (British Columbia) and
Waterloo Landfill Gas Power Plant (Ontario).
17ALBERTA WASTE
- In 2000, BOVAR issued a notice of intent to cease
operations due to its inability to make a profit.
- In 2001, the facility was returned to the
province, and capital assets of approximately 34
million were written off by BOVAR (BOVAR, 2000).
- In 2003, the Alberta government signed a 10-year
operations contract with Earth Tech Inc., a
division of Tyco International Ltd. - Because there was no effective risk transfer,
enormous contracting costs and the eventual
demise of the P3, it is hard to classify Swan
Hills as a success.
18CONFEDERATION BRIDGE
- This P3 clearly delivered a functioning bridge on
schedule. - However, the project had high financing costs
the bonds were sold at a 4.5 interest rate, at a
time when similar federal issues were priced at
4.1. Moreover, SCFI paid a sales commission of
1.75, compared to a typical rate of 0.6 for
federal real return bonds. These higher rates
might be justifiable if the government had
eliminated equivalent risk through them (in other
words, if the federal government had acquired a
put option against the risk of project default)
or if the consortiums capital requirement had
imposed upon the private partners an incentive to
minimize project capital. - However, these funds were guaranteed by
government and there was no net reduction in risk
exposure. It is difficult to escape the
conclusion that the P3 was chosen primarily to
achieve off-balance sheet financing. Success
depends on the trade-off between a functioning
bridge and the relatively un-P3-like project that
emerged with relatively little risk transfer.
19THE 407
- Did deliver a highway on time and on budget.
- The major initial weakness of 407 as a P3 was the
failure of the government to effectively transfer
financing risks the construction phase became a
conventional develop, design and build contract.
- Even so, ongoing transaction costs were extremely
high including litigation. The 407 operator, not
surprisingly, was interested in maximizing
profits rather than optimizing metropolitan
Toronto traffic flows and was interested in
increasing tolls. The end result is the province
managing the tolls. - On the other hand, there were also opportunistic
elements to provincial behaviour as political
costs escalated because of the toll increases. - Those who focus on the lack of risk transfer,
such as Bose (1993), regard it as a P3 failure.
Mylvaganam and Borins (2004), more charitably,
present a mixed assessment. Transaction costs
could be considered very high.
20HIGHWAY 104
- Major conflicts arose relating to the allocation
of risk. - Although touted as a P3, the private partner is
really a government entity (so much so that the
AG argues its debt is provincial debt). - The private partner assumed the risks
associated with cost overruns on construction due
to factors such as design flaws or other
interruptions (Van Adel, 1999). The risk for low
traffic volume and resulting revenue flow
initially also fell entirely on them. - The government also assumed that the private
sector partner would bear most of the project
risk, including those associated with
environmental permitting, archeological and
geotechnical risks and any cost overruns. - The government assumed that providing the
right-of-way for the land for the project was its
only major obligation. However, after the
participants had reached an agreement on the
terms of the contracts, the lenders renegotiated.
- Although the private sector had initially assumed
the revenue risk for the project, this risk was
largely offset by legislation that essentially
required trucks to use the new toll highway by
prohibiting trips on the old highway (Van Adel,
1999). - An assessment by the AG argues that the highway
project did deliver benefits to N.S. However,
the AG argued that debt service charges for the
loan would have been notably lower if the
province had directly borrowed the funds for the
project, rather than using a P3. Political
factors have obviously raise transaction costs in
this case. Hard to see this a P3 success.
21EVERGREEN SCHOOL
- The school did get built on time.
- This case study illustrates some of the
difficulty of even calculating the costs of P3
financing compared to direct government
provision, especially when the private sector
partner engages in activities that the public
sector would not. - On one hand, these activities may be innovative
on the other hand, they may involve externalities
(in this case, foregone use of school property
outside of regular school hours). - In the big scheme of things, this is a small
project. Could be argued to be a reasonable
success. But, province seems to have
underestimated the externalities (real and
political) of a private partner have control of
school after hours. Transaction costs have been
substantial.
22OCONNELL DRIVE SCHOOL
- A school did get built.
- While it is difficult to conclusively conclude
that there were no construction cost savings (an
appropriate counterfactual on direct government
procurement would necessarily be speculative), it
is certainly unlikely that were major cost
savings. - Risk transfer was minimal (AG argued)
- Transaction costs appear to have been high.
- Clearly, OConnell Drive was not successful from
a political perspective. While political costs
of the P3 appeared low ex ante, they certainly
turned out to be high ex post and essentially
forced the abandonment of P3 for school
construction.
23BRITANNIA MINE
- Some degree of risk transfer, because the private
partner has to meet volume and quality targets to
get paid. - Indeed, given the specialized technical
requirements of the project, it is hard to
conceive of this project being conducted in-house
by government. Would always be contracted to
specialized firm. - Britannia appears to represent a reasonably
successful P3. - On the other hand, this is the kind of project
that has traditionally been contracted-out in one
form or another.
24MONCTON WATER
- The plant got built on time.
- Again, as with Britannia, given the specialized
technical requirements of the project and the
proprietary knowledge of USFilter, it is hard to
conceive of this project being conducted in-house
by government. - Again, as with Britannia, this is the kind of
project that has traditionally been
contracted-out in one form or another. - Transaction costs appear to have been
significant, although not as high as in many of
the other case studies. - Moncton Water appears to represent a reasonably
successful P3.
25CRANBROOK MULTIPLEX
- As a result of the contractual changes, the
citys auditor had included the 22 million lease
on the citys financial statements, resulting in
a substantial decreasing in the citys borrowing
power. - After dealing with legal disputes, cost overruns
and construction delays, five years after the
project began, the P3 officially failed. Vestar
withdrew in 2004 after paying the city 1.7
million to take ownership of the complex
(Cloutier 2004). - Overall, the project proved to be much more
costly than projected. When the project failed
the city found itself with the highest debt level
in the province. This project is clearly a P3
failure.
26WATERLOO GAS POWER
- Plant built on time.
- Relatively simple contract. Build the plant, sell
the gas, give royalty to RMOV depending on
volume. - Again, this appears to a successful, relatively
small, straightforward P3.
27FRAMEWORK FOR FINDINGS
- Degree of asset specificity?
- Construction complexity?
- Construction cost risk transferred?
- Use (revenue) uncertainty?
- Use risk transferred?
- Level of government contract management skill?
- Externalities?
- Level of transaction costs?
- Success?
- Table on next slide summarizes this
-
28TABLE 2 Key Factors in Assessing P3 Case Studies
29CONCLUSION HIGH TRANSATION COSTS
- Given conflicting goals, transaction costs are
high - On public sector side changing political risk
and opportunism raise transaction costs. - On private sector side firms desire to maximize
profits and avoid risk, especially use risk,
raise transaction costs. - Transaction costs are aggravated by
- Complexity.
- Ability to transfer risk.
30Figure 1 Revenue Uncertainty and Effective
Revenue Risk Transfer
Revenue (Use) UncertaintyHigh
Highway 407 3.1 B
Confederation Bridge 730 M
Highway 104 113 M
Britannia Mine Water Treatment 27.2 M
Revenue Risk Transfer High
Cranbrook Rec Plex 226 M
Alberta Waste Mgmt ?
Low
Moncton Water Treatment 85 M
Evergreen Park School 14.7 M
OConnell Drive School 8 M
Waterloo Landfill Gas Power Plant7.5 M
Low
31CONCLUSION WHERE P3s WORK.
- P3s seem to work where contracting out has always
worked best for government - Technically specialized projects where firm has
expertise (Economies of scale, scope, learning). - BOT format.
- No, or very limited, use risk transfer.