Title: TRUST, FEAR, RECIPROCITY, AND ALTRUISM: Theory and Experiment
1TRUST, FEAR, RECIPROCITY, AND ALTRUISM Theory
and Experiment
- James C. Cox
- University of Arizona
- and Indiana University
2Central Objective of the Research
- Improve theory through a program of
- Experimental testing and
- Theoretical modeling motivated by data
3Implications of Parsimony
- Design experiments to identify
- When the economic man model does not predict
well and models of other-regarding
preferences are needed - When the other-regarding preferences need to
include beliefs and intentions
4Parsimony (cont.)
- Develop an integrated approach to modeling
behavior that is - Unconditional on intentions or
- Conditional on others revealed intentions
5Contents
- Experimental designs that discriminate among
unconditional altruism, positive reciprocity,
trust, negative reciprocity, and fear -
- Effects of social distance and decision context
on reciprocal behavior
6Contents (cont.)
- Direct tests of alternative models
-
- New models of patterns of behavior that
- (a) are conditional or
-
- (b) are not conditional on others intentions
and status
7An Example The Investment Game
- Subjects are paired
- Each subject in each pair is given 10
- Second movers are told to keep their 10
- First movers can either
- Keep their 10 or
- Give some or all of it to the second mover
- Any amount given is multiplied by 3 by the
experimenter
8Investment Game (cont.)
- Second movers can either
- Keep all of any amount received or
- Return part or all of it to the first mover
- All of the above is common information given to
all subjects - The game is played only once
9Predictions ofthe Economic Man Model
- Since second movers care only about their own
material gain, they will keep any tripled amount
sent by first movers - Since first movers care only about their own
material gain, and know that second movers have
the same kind of preferences, first movers send
nothing
10Predictions (cont.)
- Zero returned and sent is the subgame perfect
equilibrium of this game, given the economic man
assumption about preferences - The predicted outcome is inefficient Each
subject pair is predicted to get 20 in payoff
just the endowment when it could have gotten as
much as 40
11Behavior in the Investment Game
12Definitions
- Self-regarding (or economic man) preferences
are characterized by positively monotonic utility
for ones own material payoffs and indifference
about others material payoffs - Other-regarding preferences are characterized by
utility that is not constant with respect to
variations in ones own or others material
payoffs - Altruistic preferences are characterized by
utility that is monotonically increasing in
others material payoffs and ones own payoffs
13Definitions (cont.)
- (direct) Positive reciprocity is a motivation to
adopt a generous action that benefits someone
else, at ones own material cost, because that
persons intentional behavior was perceived to be
beneficial to oneself - Trust is a belief that one agent has about
another. A trusting action is one that creates
the possibility of mutual benefit and the risk of
loss of ones own utility if the other person
defects
14Definitions (cont.)
- (direct) Negative reciprocity is a motivation to
adopt an action that harms someone else, at ones
own material cost, because that persons
intentional behavior was perceived to be harmful
to oneself - Fear is a belief that one agent has about
another. An action that is fearful of another is
one that forgoes an otherwise preferred action
because of a belief that the other agent will
inflict costly punishment as a response to choice
of the otherwise-preferred action
15Investment Game Triadic Design
- Treatment A is the investment game
- Treatment B is a dictator game that gives
dictators the same choices that first movers have
in the investment game - Treatment C is a dictator game that gives
dictators the same choices that second movers
have in the investment game -
16Comparison of the Amounts Sent in Treatments A
and B
17Comparison of the Amounts Returned in
Treatments A and C
18Conclusions about Behavior
- Behavior in the investment game is known to
exhibit trust because first movers send - significantly more in the investment game than
in the first-mover dictator control treatment - Behavior in the investment game is known to
exhibit positive reciprocity because second
movers return significantly more in the
investment game than in the second-mover dictator
control treatment
19Implications for Theory
- Data-consistent models of first-mover behavior in
the investment game must incorporate beliefs
about others behavior - Data-consistent models of second-mover behavior
in the investment game must incorporate others
intentions
20Conclusions from Many Other Experiments with Game
Triads
- Positive reciprocity is significant in the
moonlighting game but negative reciprocity is not
significant - Trust is significant in the moonlighting game but
fear is not significant - Positive reciprocity is significant in the trust
game with a single blind protocol but not with a
double blind protocol - Positive reciprocity in the trust game is
invariant with a doubling of money payoffs
21Conclusions from Triads (cont.)
- Negative reciprocity and fear are not significant
in the punishment mini-ultimatum game (MUG) - Play in the punishment MUG is invariant with
framing the task as market exchange - Negative reciprocity is significant in the
punishment MUG if it is embedded within a context
of similar games
22Conclusions from Triads (cont.)
- Females are less positively reciprocal in the
investment game than are males - Groups are less generous in the investment game
than are individuals
23Models of Other-regarding Preferences
- Inequality aversion models (Fehr Schmidt, QJE,
1999 Bolton Ockenfels, AER, 2000) utility is
increasing with ones own money payoff but
decreasing with the difference between ones own
and others money payoffs - Quasi-maximin model (Charness Rabin, QJE,
2003) utility is increasing with an agents own
money payoff, with the lowest of all agents
payoffs, and with the total of all agents payoffs
24Alternative Model Motivated by Data
- Egocentric altruism model (Cox Sadiraj)
other-regarding preferences characterized by
monotonicity, convexity, and egocentricity -
25Exp.1 A Direct Test of Inequality Aversion
- This test is provided by the first-mover
dictator control treatment for the investment
game triad - The dictator is given 10
- The anonymously-paired subject is given 10
- The dictator can keep all of his 10 or give any
integral part of it to the paired person - Any amount given is tripled by the experimenter
26Prediction of the Fehr-Schmidt Model
27Prediction of the Bolton-Ockenfels Model
28Behavior in Experiment 1
29Behavior in Experiment 1 (cont.)
- 19 of 30 or 63 of the dictators gave positive
amounts to the other person. -
- The average amount given was 3.63
- The average payoff of dictators was 6.37 and the
average payoff of non-dictators was 20.89
30The Quasi-Maximin Model
31Direct Tests of Quasi-Maximin
- Experiment 2
- m y1 y2 y3
- 10 0 6 6
- 10 0 15 15
- 10 0 2 33
-
32Direct Tests of Quasi-Maximin (cont.)
- Experiment 3
- m y1 y2 y3
- 10 0 15 15
- 10 3 12 15
- 10 4 5 21
33Subjects Choices in Experiments 2 and 3
34Behavior in Experiments 2 and 3 (cont.)
- The choices of 85 of the subjects in experiment
2 are inconsistent with quasi-maximin preferences -
- The choices of 94 of the subjects in experiment
3 are inconsistent with quasi-maximin preferences
35More Information about Subjects Preferences
- Experiment 4 differs from experiment 1 only by
introduction of the opportunity to take money as
well as give it - Amounts given are multiplied by 3
- Amounts taken are not transformed
- Amounts taken cannot exceed 5 (first-mover
control for the moonlighting triad)
36Choices in Experiments 1 and 4
37Behavior Changes Character when the Feasible Set
Changes
- In experiment 1, 67 of dictators gave money to
others who would, as a result, have significantly
higher payoffs than the dictators - In experiment 4, 70 of dictators took money from
the others who would, as a result, have
significantly lower payoffs than the dictators -
- How can such behavior be explained?
38With a Model of Egocentric Altruistic
Preferences
39The Two-Agent Egocentric Altruism Model
40Properties of the Model
- Monotonicity
- Convexity
- Egocentricity
- Two Agent Special Case of Egocentricity
-
- for all
41Consistency with Data
- The egocentric altruism model is consistent with
data for - 100 of subjects in experiments 1 and 4
- 85 of subjects in experiment 2
- 88 of subjects in experiment 3
42The Model is Robust
- The model can also rationalize behavior in
experiments with - Proposer competition
- Responder competition
- Voluntary contributions to public goods
43Incorporating Intentionsin a Tractable Way
Note that MRS WTP 1/MRS at an
allocation on the 45 line where m
y Convexity implies higher WTP if and lower
WTP if
44Reciprocity and Status
- We assume
-
- where
- r is a reciprocity variable
- s is a status variable
45Definition of r
-
- where m(x) is the max. payoff for the second
mover, given the first movers choice x - and is m(x) when x is neutral
46Definition of s
-
-
- where and are the status of the
first and second movers in the context of the
game currently played
47Assumptions Used in Estimation
- A.1 Individuals choose so as to maximize a
utility function of the given form - A.2 The emotional state function ? (r, s) is
identical across individuals and there is a
zero-mean idiosyncratic term such that -
48Model Assumption that is Tested
- A.3 ? (r, s) is weakly increasing in r and s
49Data Used in Estimating the Model
- Dictator games, with and without a status
treatment - Stackelberg duopoly games
- Mini-ultimatum games with variable reference
- payoff conditions
- Ultimatum games with random and earned
- entitlements to be first mover
- Moonlighting games
-
50Summary Conclusions from Estimation
- The model captures baseline altruism in dictator
games - The model explains how status affects altruism in
dictator games - The model explains reciprocal responses
- in Stackelberg duopoly games
51Summary Conclusions (cont.)
- The model explains how changing perceptions of
property rights affect reciprocity in
mini-ultimatum games - The model explains the interaction of status and
reciprocity in ultimatum games - The model explains reciprocal behavior in
moonlighting games -
52Work in Progress A Nonparametric Model of
Revealed Altruism
- Elements of the Model
- Partial Ordering of Preferences more altruistic
than (MAT) - Partial Ordering of Budget Sets more generous
than (MGT) - Reciprocity Axiom more generous choices by the
first mover induce more altruistic preferences in
the second mover
53Applications of the Model
- Stackelberg duopoly game data
- Stackelberg mini-game data
54.
55Behavior in Fairness Games Exhibits
- Unconditional altruism others payoffs matter
- Trust and fear beliefs matter
- Reciprocity intentions matter
56Whether Trust, Fear, Reciprocity or Altruism is
Exhibited Depends on
- Single-blind vs. double-blind protocol who is
observing matters - Context in which a specific game is embedded
fairness is a relative concept - Type of agent
- Group or individual
- Male or female
57Modeling Fairness Games
- Behavior is not generally characterized by
- Inequality aversion
- Maxi-min
- Efficiency
58Modeling (cont.)
- Behavior is characterized by other-regarding
preferences that are - Egocentric
- Convex
- Positively monotonic in others payoffs, except
when they are conditional on intentions
59Modeling (cont.)
- Intentions (reciprocity) and status can be
incorporated in a tractable model of
other-regarding preferences - Individual-subject differences can be
parsimoniously incorporated in a model of
other-regarding preferences
60References
- James C. Cox, Trust, Reciprocity, and
Other-Regarding Preferences Groups vs.
Individuals and Males vs. Females, in R. Zwick
and A. Rapoport, (eds.), Advances in Experimental
Business Research, Kluwer Academic Publishers,
2002. - James C. Cox, How to Identify Trust and
Reciprocity, Games and Economic Behavior, 46,
no. 2, 2004, pp. 260-281 - James C. Cox and Cary A. Deck, On the Nature of
Reciprocal Motives, Economic Inquiry,
forthcoming. - James C. Cox, Daniel Friedman, and Steven
Gjerstad, A Tractable Model of Reciprocity and
Fairness, University of Arizona Discussion
Paper, 2005. - James C. Cox and Vjollca Sadiraj, Direct Tests
of Models of Social Preferences and Introduction
of a New Model, University of Arizona Discussion
Paper, 2005. - James C. Cox, Klarita Sadiraj, and Vjollca
Sadiraj, Implications of Trust, Fear, and
Reciprocity for Modeling Economic Behavior,
University of Arizona Discussion Paper, 2004.