Title: PARETO OPTIMALITY AND THE EFFICIENCY GOAL
1PARETO OPTIMALITY AND THE EFFICIENCY GOAL
2SOCIAL GOALS AND THE ROLE OF THE RATIONAL
INDIVIDUAL
- CBA is based on neoclassical welfare economics
- CBA embodies (classic) Liberal philosophy with
following components - 1. individual is fundamental unit of society
- Individual preferences count
- 2. rational decision-making by individuals
- 3. rational individuals preferences can be
meaningfully aggregated in some manner to make
social decisions about resource allocation in
society
3THE INDIVIDUAL AND SOCIETY
- Society essentially composed of individuals
motivated by self-interest - Law and government provide security against
equally self-interested fellows - Government and society exist to preserve the
individuals rights - Individuals acting in enlightened self-interest
lead to the maximum common good - Public interests are conceived in terms of
private well-being
4THE INDIVIDUAL AND ECONOMY
- Individuals gain satisfaction or utility fromo
consumption - These individuals have preferences
- The values or strengths of this utility is
manifested in prices formed in the market place - The more individuals value or demand or derive
satisfaction/utility, the higher the price and
their willingness to pay
5THE INDIVIDUAL AND ECONOMY
- Thus, money valuations express individual
preferences
6THE INDIVIDUAL AND ECONOMY
- Collective Rationality and Aggregation of Money
Valuations - Basic question is how to aggregate individual
money valuations to form collective or social
valuations - These social valuations are used to make social
(collective) decision-making - Basic approach is to simply sum the individual
money valuations - Summation gives net benefits to society
7DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND WEALTH
- Judgements about the distribution of income and
wealth are largely implicit in CBA - Implicitly, the desired income distribution is
the one prevailing at the time of CBA - Because money valuations reflect willingness to
pay - But willingness to pay as reflected by market
behavior is a function of ability to pay
8VALUES WHEN MARKETS DO NOT EXIST
- Individuals preferences are measured as prices
and willingness to pay - Gives the level of economic welfare from
consumption - Prices and hence values are formed by market
activity
9VALUES WHEN MARKETS DO NOT EXIST
- Sometimes markets do not exist
- Biodiversity is one example
- No prices exist in a market that individuals are
willing to pay - However, prices and willingness to pay can, in
principle, be imputed from observed behavior
10SUMMARY TO THIS POINT
- Benefit-cost analysis is based on neoclassical
welfare economics - CBA and welfare economics embody the philosophy
of individual consumer sovereignty - Social economic welfare is assumed to be the sum
of self-expressed welfares of all individuals in
society - Expressed through market prices and WTP
11SUMMARY TO THIS POINT
- A benefit is considered a gain in welfare
- A cost is considered a loss in welfare
- Net benefits are an aggregation of all benefits
minus an aggregation of all costs - In making judgements about optimal resource
allocations, decision criterion is required to
evaluate alternative economic states
12SUMMARY TO THIS POINT
- That is, alternative economic states, i.e.
alternative allocations of scarce social
resources, each have corresponding summed net
benefits - Some criterion is required to evaluate these
alternative economic states - In welfare economics, and thus CBA, this
criterion is Pareto optimality - A value judgement
13THE CONCEPT OF PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Paretian System
- Concept of Pareto optimality underlies the value
judgements used to choose among alternative
resource allocations alternative economic
states with the greatest net benefits
14PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Paretian System
- Two fundamental components of Paretian value
system - 1. Individual preferences count
- 2. Prevailing income distribution is desireable
15PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Pareto Criterion
- Purpose
- Pareto criterion is a technique for comparing or
ranking alternative states of the economy - Definition of Pareto Criterion
- If it is possible to make at least one person
better off in moving from state A to state B
without making anyone else worse off, state B is
ranked higher by society than state B
16PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Pareto Criterion
- Pareto Improvement
- A movement from state A to state B
- Pareto Criterion vs.Unanimity
- Pareto criterion allows indifference by some
individuals (some not made worse off)
17PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Pareto Optimum
- A state of the economy from which it is
impossible to make one person better off without
making another person worse off. - If society finds itself in a position from which
there is no Pareto improvement, then there is a
Pareto optimum - If economy is not in Pareto optimum, some
inefficiency in the economy
18PARETO OPTIMALITY
- Weak Pareto Criterion
- Everyone is made better off.
- Strong Pareto Criterion
- Some people are made better off, while noone is
made worse off. - Pareto criterion breaks down if even one
individual is made worse off.
19PARETO OPTIMALITY
Utility Person B
Set of Pareto improvements
- Utility Possibility
- Curve
- Corresponds to all
- possible combinations of
- utility for individuals A and
- B for given production
- possiblity frontier
Pareto-inefficient starting point
Utility Person A
20PARETO OPTIMALITY AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION
- Pareto optimality gives an efficient resource
allocation and maximum social welfare for a given
income distribution - If change existing income distribution, then new
Pareto optimum - Hence, many Pareto optimum may exist associated
with different factor endowments (incoome
distributions)
21PARETO OPTIMALITY AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION
- Implies cannot solve problem of efficiency and
income distribution in two stages by - 1. First, Pareto-efficient resource allocation
- 2. Optimum distribution
- No solution by Pareto criterion
22PARETO OPTIMALITY AND INCOME DISTRIBUTION
- Two different distributions of income give
- two different Pareto optimums, A and B
- All such combos of utility, for given income
- distribution, gives UPF
- How to choose A vs. B?
- Cannot by Paerto criterion
- Need social welfare function
- But Arrows Impossibility Theorem says
- cannot for democratic society
Utility Individual A
Contract curve A
A
Utility Possibility Frontier
B
Contract curve B
Utility Individual B
23LIMITATIONS TO PARETO CRITERION
- 1. Breaks down if single individual made worse
off - 2. Many alternatives simply not comparable
- Alternative Pareto optimum (corresponding to
different income distributions) not Pareto
comparable - Pareto criterion does not allow choosing between
alternative income distributions - 3. Favors status quo
- 4. Not all first-best Pareto-optimal choices are
superior to some second-best (Pareto-inefficient)
choices - Second-best may have superior income distribution
24POTENTIAL PARETO CRITERION
- Potential Pareto criterion is a way out of the
limitations of the (pure) Pareto criterion - Is modification of Pareto criterion and forms the
basis for comparing or ranking alternative states
of the economy by CBA - Sometimes called Kaldor-Hicks Compensation Test
- Relies on compensation principle
25POTENTIAL PARETO CRITERION
- Definition of Potential Pareto Criterion
- State A is preferable to state B if it is
potentially possible to for the gainers to
compensate the losers and still remain better off - Actual compensation is not required
26POTENTIAL PARETO CRITERION
- Example
- Gainers in state A receive 100 units of benefit
- Losers in state A penalized 90 units (their cost)
- If gainers potentially compensate losers by 90
units, gainers receive net benefit of 10 units
27POTENTIAL PARETO CRITERION
- In market economies, compensation is not
typically direct - Instead, various forms of transfer payments
- Purpose of potential compensation is to separate
efficiency and equity components of a policy
change under consideration
28POTENTIAL PARETO CRITERION
- I to any point between S0 and S1 is Pareto
improvement - All points on UPF in range S0S1 is
Pareto-superior to I - Move from I to E is not Pareto improvement in
itself
Utility A
E
S0
- Potential Pareto Criterion ranks a
- Pareto-optimal allocation, such as E,
- superior to any allocation not Pareto
- optimal, such as I
- Potential Pareto Criterion allows point
- Such as E to be reached by potential
- compensation
S
S1
I
Utility Possibility Fronter
Utility B