Title: Economic Theories of Fertility
1Economic Theories of Fertility
2Thomas Malthus (early 19C)
- fertility determined by the age at marriage and
frequency of coition during marriage. - an increase in peoples income would encourage
them to marry earlier and have sexual intercourse
more often. - Gary Becker generalized and developed the
Malthusian theory.
3Child Quality
- Gary Beckers seminal contribution pointed out
that the psychic satisfaction parents receive
from their children is likely to depend on the
amount that parents spend on children as well as
the number of children that they have. - Children who have more spent on them are called
higher quality children. - Basic idea is that if parents voluntarily spend
more on a child, it is because they obtain
additional satisfaction from the additional
expenditure.
4Current state of theory
- Now child quality is usually identified with the
lifetime well-being of the child. - Can be increased by investing more in the childs
human capital or by the direct transfer of wealth
to the child. - Thus, we could think of child quality as the
childs quality of life, as an adult as well as
during his or her childhood.
5Home Production of Child Quality
- Define a production function for child quality
(Q), or income as an adult, in terms of parents
time and purchases of good and services. - Assume that parents choose the same level of
child quality for each. - Q f(xc/N, tmc/N, tfc/N), where
- xc is the total amount of goods and services and
tmc and tfc are the total amounts of mothers and
fathers time devoted to the production of child
quality. - N is the number of children.
- Constant returns to scale production function.
6Expenditure on Children
- Total expenditure on children is, therefore,
?CNQ ?Cf(xc, tmc, tfc), where - ?C is the marginal cost of children.
- Marginal cost of children depends on the prices
of inputs into its production, namely - dln(?C) (pcxc/?CNQ)dln(pc) (wmtmc/?CNQ)dln(wm)
(wftfc/?CNQ)dln(wf) - wj is the wage rate of parent j and pc is the
price of purchased goods and services - assumes that both parents work in the market
sometime during the childrearing period.
7Parents standard of living (Z), or parental
consumption for short
- Produced by combining parents time and purchased
goods and services. - Zg(xz,tmz,tfz)
- where g(?) exhibits constant returns to scale.
- Consensus Preferences U(Z,N,Q).
- Ignore different preferences for simplicity.
8Parents Decision
- Choose N, Q and Z to maximize their utility
subject to the lifetime budget constraint - Y ?ZZ ?CNQ
- where ?Z is the marginal cost of parental
consumption, which depends on input prices,
analogously to ?C. - Note product NQ in budget constraint.
9Characteristics of solution
- UN ??CQ ?pN
- UQ ??CN ?pQ
- UZ ??Z
- where pN and pQ are the marginal costs of the
number and quality of children respectively. - The marginal utility of income is ?.
10Implications
- Cost (or shadow price) of an additional child
is proportional to the level of child quality - Cost (shadow price) of raising child quality is
proportional to the number of children the
parents have. - Important interaction between family size and
child quality.
11Figure 6.1
- The optimal choice of N and Q is given at point
A, at which the indifference curve U0 is tangent
to the budget constraint C0NQY-?ZZ(Y,?Z,?C)/?C
, where - C0 is the parents real expenditure on children.
- Z(Y,?Z,?C) is the demand function for parents
consumption. - At the optimum UN/UQpN/pQQ/N.
12(No Transcript)
13- Maximization of utility implies that the
indifference curve must be more convex than the
budget constraint, which means - that child quality and quantity cannot be close
substitutes for one another. - Increase in income (Y) produces
- A pure income effect (A?B)
- An induced substitution effect (B?C)
- Latter can be large enough to produce a fall in
fertility when income increases.
14A negative income elasticity of demand for
children?
- The income elasticity of fertility can be
negative, even though children are normal
goods, in the sense that parents want more of
them when parental income increases. - The reason is that the true income elasticity is
defined with relative prices constant, but,
because of the interaction, we cannot hold the
ratio of the shadow price of an additional child
to that of child quality (pN/pQ) constant when we
measure the elasticity.
15The cost of children
- Determined by the cost of the inputs that
determine the cost of child quality relative to
the cost of the parents living standard. - dln(?C/?Z) (qmC-qmZ)dln(wm)
- (qfC-qfZ)dln(wf) where pCpZ1 (numeraire)
- qmC(wmtmc/?CNQ) and qfC(wftfc/?CNQ)
- qmZ(wmtmz/?ZZ) and qfZ(wftfz/?ZZ)
- These are parents respective cost shares in
producing Q and Z, respectively.
16Children time-intensive
- Rearing of children is assumed to be mothers
time-intensive relative to other home production
activities in the sense that qmCgtqmZ. - Implies relative cost of children (?C/?Z) is
directly related to the mothers wage. - The relative cost of children also depends on the
fathers wage as long as qfC?qfZ.
17Lifetime budget constraint
- In terms of full income
- Y (wmwf)T y (tmctmz)wm (tfctfz)wf
xCxZ ?ZZ ?CNQ. - Let U(Z,N,Q) U(Z,NQ) for simplicity.
18Demand function for children
- dln(NQ) ?CSyYdln(y)
- ?CSmY-?SZ(qmC-qmZ)dln(wm)
- ?CSfY-?SZ(qfC-qfZ)dln(wf)
- where ? is the elasticity of substitution in
consumption between Z and NQ (?gt0) - ?C is the elasticity of NQ with respect to full
income - SZ?ZZ/Y and SyYy/Y and
- SiYwi(T-tjc-tjz)/Y, jm,f, are shares of full
income.
19Effects of mens and womens wages
- Income effects represented by the terms ?CSmY and
?CSfYare proportional to that parents earnings
share of full income. - Substitution effect of -?SZ(qjC-qjZ)
- Negative for mothers if qmC-qmZgt0
- Could be near zero for fathers if qfC-qfZ is
small. - Could be positive for fathers , because of his
wifes comparative advantage in child-rearing
i.e. qfC-qfZlt0
20Purchased child care and fertility
- Assume that fathers are not involved in home
production (tfctfz0). - Use tmc in the child quality production function
to denote total time for child care (rather than
just mothers time). - tmc H h(M), 0lth?(M) lt1, h??(M)lt0, h(0)0
(h?(M)dh/dM etc.). - H is the amount of the mothers time devoted to
children, M is the amount of time purchased in
the market at price p.
21Choice of purchased child care
- Because each child may require a minimum amount
of mothers time, k, there are constraints H?kN
as well as M?0. - At optimum,
- h?(M) (p-?M/?)/wm - ?H/?N
- ?H and ?M are the Lagrange multipliers (shadow
prices) associated with these two inequality
constraints. - These are zero when the constraint is satisfied
with an inequality and positive if satisfied with
an equality.
22(No Transcript)
23Different cases
- Because mothers time and purchased care are not
perfect substitutes, it is likely that the
parents use both sources of care. That is, HgtkN
and Mgt0 then h?(M) p/wm. Tangency point A in
Figure. - If the price of market child care is sufficiently
low, or mothers wage high, wm gt p/h?(M) for all
values of M and Mtmc-kN. Point B in Figure. - If the mothers wage is low or the market price
of child care is high, wMlt p/h?(0), and no child
care would be purchased. Point C in Figure.
24Demand function for children
- dln(NQ) ?CSyYdln(y)
- ?CSmY-?SZ(qHC-qmZ)dln(wm)
- - qMC?CSC?SZdln(p)
- qHCwmH/?CNQ, qMCwmh(M)/?CNQ, SC?CNQ/Y and now
SmYwm(T-H-tmz)/Y. - Higher price of child care has a negative effect,
unless M0.
25Implications
- Even though children may be more time intensive
than the production of Z in the sense that
wmtmc/?CNQ gt qmZ, the substitution effect of a
higher mothers wage could be positive if
purchased child care time is a large enough
proportion of child care time so as to make qHClt
qmZ. - A tendency for the impact of the mothers wage on
fertility to vary with the level of wages and the
price of market child care.
26- There is a tendency for qHC-qmZ to fall as the
mothers wage increases or the price of child
falls - This reduces the size of the (negative)
substitution effect. - Women with very high wage levels find that
wmgtp/h?(M) for all values of HgtkN, so that HkN.
In this situation, the marginal cost of children,
?C, is not affected by changes in the wage, only
the price of child care.
27Child mortality risk and fertility
- Failure to survive is ultimate manifestation of
low quality. - Does lower child mortality risk help account for
the demographic transition from high
fertility-high mortality environment to a low
fertility-low mortality one?
28Simple model
- Parents utility function, Uu(z) v(n),
- where z denotes parental consumption, n is the
number of children who survive to become adults. - That is, children who die in childhood are not a
source of utility to their parents. - Each birth has survival chances, which can be
represented by a probability distribution with
mean equal to the survival probability s.
29- Surviving children n is the outcome from
subjecting the number of births, b, to this
random survival process. - Denote the probability density function of n,
conditional on b and s, as f(n,b,s). - Then the expected utility of parents is given by
E(U)u(z) g(b,s) - where g(b,s) is the expected utility from having
b births when on average sb survive - (i.e comes from integrating v(n)f(n,b,s) over n
from 0 to b).
30Parents optimisation
- Assume that each birth has a fixed cost c.
- Parents choose b to maximize
- E(U)u(y-cb) g(b,s).
- Implies cgb/u'
- gb?g/?b is the marginal expected utility from an
additional birth and u' is the marginal utility
of parents consumption.
31Implications
- db/ds -gbs/D 0
- Where D c2u''gbb lt0 and gbs0
- A higher probability of child survival reduces
the price of a surviving birth, thereby
encouraging higher fertility. - Thus, lower child mortality does not lower
fertility in this model. - There must be some other consideration.
32Richer model
- Cigno suggests that parents can influence the
chances that their own children survive to become
adults (an element of child quality) by spending
more on each child. - That is, c is now chosen by the parents and it
affects the survival distribution, f(n,b,s,c). - It is now possible that db/dslt0
- if exogenous factors affecting s substitute for
parents expenditure to improve child survival.
33Effects of contraceptive costs
- When family size and child quality are net
substitutes - Lower cost of averting births
- Reduces fertility (if income effect is small)
- Raises human capital investment (child quality)
- A higher return to human capital investment in
children - Raises human capital investment.
- Reduces fertility.
34Impacts of technical change
- Contraceptive costs/rate of return effects work
through quantity-quality interaction, tending to
magnify initial impacts because of effects on
pN/pQ. - Technical change (e.g. green revolution) has
affected rate of return to human capital
investment and contraception. - Can account for important stylised facts of
economic development.