Title: Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition
1Industrial Organization or Imperfect Competition
- Univ. Prof. dr. Maarten Janssen
- University of Vienna
- Summer semester 2008
- Week 3 (March 31- April 1)
22. Price Discrimination
- Incentives for price discrimination
Price cost
Price cost
Economic Surplus not appropriated by the seller!
PM
PM
D(p)
D(p)
MC
M
QM
MR
Q
Q
3Price Discrimination
- First Degree (or perfect)
- Personalised pricing
- Third Degree (group pricing)
- Observe a group signal and charge different
prices to different groups - Second degree (menu of contracts, versioning)
- Offer a menu of price-quantity (quality,)
bundles and let consumers choose
4 First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimination
- Practice of charging each consumer the maximum
amount he or she will pay for each incremental
unit - Permits a firm to extract all surplus from
consumers
5First-degree optimal pricing rule
- P(x) is the inverse demand function
- When charging for each additional unit x price
P(x) the firms profit equals - Optimisation yields P(x) C(x)
- Which is the definition of the perfectly
competitive price - Hence, efficient allocation
6Perfect price discriminationTwo-Part Tariff
Implementation
1. Set price at marginal cost. 2. Compute
consumer surplus. 3. Charge a fixed-fee equal to
consumer surplus.
7Two-Part Tariff optimal pricing rule
- Total price for x units T(x) A px, where A is
fixed fee and p price per unit - When consumer buys x units, net utility equals
U(x) A px. - Given T(x), consumer buys x units, where U(x)
p - Participation constraint U(x) A px 0
- Max A (p-c)x by choosing A and p given
participation constraint and optimal consumer
choice - Obviously, in the optimum PC binds and we should
have U(x) p c. Moreover, A U(x) cx
8Caveats with perfect pricediscrimination
- Even though it leads to an efficient outcome, is
it a fair distribution of wealth in the society? - In practice, transactions costs and information
constraints make it difficult to implement (but
car dealers and some professionals try to come
close). - Arbitrage Price discrimination wont work if
consumers can resell the good.
9Third Degree Price Discrimination
- The practice of charging different groups of
consumers different prices for the same product - Examples
- Journals, software institutions, individuals,
students - International pricing
- Physicians rich and poor patients
10Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Suppose the total demand for a product is
comprised of two groups with different
elasticities, ? 1 lt ? 2 - Notice that group 2 is more price sensitive than
group 1 - Profit-maximizing prices?
- P1 1/(1 - 1/?1) ? MC
- P2 1/(1 - 1/?2) ? MC
- More price sensitive consumers pay lower prices
- Usually, people with lower incomes (students)
- Even if firms have no redistribution intention
11Welfare aspects ofThird Degree Price
Discrimination
- Firms are better off - Low (high) elasticity
consumers are worse (better) off
12Welfare aspects I Analysis constant MC
- Without discrimination charge Pm, sell Si Qmi
Si Di(Pm). Profit p (Pm c) Si Qmi - With discrimination charge Pi, sell Qi D(Pi)
and p Si (Pi - c)Qi - ?W Si (Pi - c)Qi - (Pm - c)Qmi
Si Si(Pi) - Si(Pm),
where ?W change in welfare because of
discrimination and Si surplus of group i - Note that dSi/dp - Di(p) and d2Si/dp2 - d
Di(p)/dp gt 0 (surplus is convex)
13Welfare aspects Analysis II
- Convexity implies that Si(Pi) - Si(Pm)
Si(Pm)Pi - Pm - QmiPi - Pm - So, ?W Si (Pi - c)Qi - (Pm - c)Qmi Qmi(Pi
Pm) Si (Pi - c)(Qi - Qm). - Also, Si(Pm) - Si(Pi) Si(Pi)Pm - Pi
- Implying ?W (Pm - c)Si (Qi - Qmi).
- So, if price discrimination does not result in
more output being sold, then welfare declines - No surprise discrimination leads to marginal
rates of substitution being different among
different consumers. Generally, inefficient from
distributional perspective.
14Welfare aspects Linear Demand Analysis
- Qi ai - biPi
- Straightforward calculations for the
discrimination case give - Pi (ai cbi)/2bi
- Qi (ai - cbi)/2
- Without discrimination (assuming all consumers
are served (buy)) - Pm (Si ai c Sibi)/2(Sibi )
- Qm (Si ai - c Sibi)/2
- As Si (Qi - Qmi) 0, price discrimination does
not lead to welfare improvement (with linear
demand), or can it?
15Welfare aspects when some markets are not served
Price Cost
Pb
P
Db(p)
Pa
DaDb
MC
Da(p)
Qa
Qb
Qb
Q
Qa
16Caveats with third degree pricediscrimination
- In practice, the seller needs to be able to
observe the characteristics of different
consumers. - Price discrimination wont work if consumers can
resell the good (arbitrage) or (successfully)
pretend to be of a different group - Interesting angle to discuss economic aspects
around the issue of privacy (cf., Google
internet) price discrimination can only work if
firms have some information about consumers
17Second Degree Price Discrimination
- The practice of offering a menu of contracts
intended to sort out (screen) consumers of
different types - For example, by setting a two-part tariff T(x)
A px, where consumers can choose any quantity
they want - Examples
- Insurance companies, airlines, utilities (water,
electricity, telephony), etc.
18Exercise on Price Discrimination in class
- Consider the model of second degree price
discrimination with 2V(x) 1-(1-x)2. Show that
for any linear tariff with T px (with p gt c),
there is a two-part-tariff T A px such that
if consumers are offered the choice, then both
types of consumers and the firm prefer T to T.
192nd Degree Price Discrimination at work
Linear two part tariff TA pq Charge p
c Charge fixed fee A CS1(c)
Fixed Fee CS1(c)
20What is the optimal two-part tariff ?
Preliminary results
- Two groups of consumers, with utility function
?iV(x) T, ?1 lt ?2 and ? (1- ?) consumers of
group 1 (2) - Consumers demand such that p ?iV(x). To make
demand linear assume 2V(x) 1-(1-x)2 Di(p) 1
p/?i - Si(p) ?iV(Di(p)) A - pDi(p) (?i-p)2/2?i A
- Define 1/? ?/?1 (1- ?)/?2 harmonic mean
- D(p) ?D1(p) (1- ?)D2(p) 1 p/?
21What is the optimal two-part tariff ? II
- Participation constraints ?iV(x) T 0
- Obviously if it holds for ?1 then also for ?2
- Highest fixed fee compatible with group 1 buying
is A (?1-p)2/2?1 - Thus, optimal two-part tariff when everyone buys
has this A and a price p that maximizes ?A
(p-c)D1(p) (1-?)A (p-c)D2(p) A
(p-c)D(p) - Yields p c / (2 ?/?1) gt c
- Thus, optimal price per unit is larger than
marginal cost! - and smaller than the monopoly price provided all
both groups buy at this price, i.e., (c ?2)/2 lt
?1
22Intuition why c lt p
Loss on group 1 consumers
Gain on group 2 consumers
23Math why c lt p
- Loss on group 1 (p - c)(p/?1 - c/?1)/2
(p-c)2/2?1 - Gain on group 2 (p - c)(p/?1 - p/?2) -
(p-c)2/2?1 - Sum is (p - c)(c/?1 - p/?2)
- Derivative wrt p is positive for p close to c and
?2 gt?1
24Intuition why p lt Pm
- By reducing p a little bit (starting from Pm)
reduction on variable profits (p-c)D(p) is only
of second-order by definition - However, increase in consumer surplus (which can
be extracted) is in order of D1(p) (first-order)
25Is a linear tariff optimal?
T
T A px
?2V(x) T
?1V(x) T
x
Single crossing property (or sorting condition)
When two indifference curves intersect, group 2s
curve is steeper
26Incentive Compatibility
- It is as if monopolist constructed contract
T1,x1 for group 1 and T2,x2 for group 2 - Clearly, group 1 does not want to buy contract
T2,x2 and vice versa, i.e., incentive
compatible (IC) contract designed for group I
is bought by group I - Viewed in this way, van we design better
contracts? - Especially, because none of the IC constraints is
binding
27Monopolist can extract more from group 2 worse
off without effecting group 1
Monopolists indifference curve T cx is constant
28Optimal contract - graphically
T2
Incentive compatbility implies that one cannot
make group 2 consumers worse off than this
otherwise they switch to group 1 contract
x2
29Remarks
- How to get this either just set menu of two
contracts, or non-linear set of contracts - In optimal contract incentive compatibility
constraint must be binding - That is why linear contract is not optimal
- In optimal contract, indiffernec curve monopolist
and high demand consumer are tangent group 2s
consumption is socially optimal (x2 D2(c))
30Non-linear menu- graphically
312nd Degree Price Discrimination at work
Non-linear two-part tariffs still better
Price Cost
Non-Linear two part tariffs Offer menu
A1,p1,A2,p2 Charge p1 gtc A1 CS1(p1
) Charge p2 c A2 A1BCD
P2(Q)
P1(Q)
A1
p1
D
B
C
MC
p2
Q
Q1
Q2
32Conclusion
- First degree price discrimination
- Efficient from TS perspective, but extreme
distribution of welfare - Third degree price discrimination
- Yields higher profits than single pricing
- Ambiguous welfare results vis-Ã -vis monopoly
pricing (depending on whether or not total output
increases) - Second degree price discrimination
- Yields higher profits than single pricing
- Better for all consumers than single pricing
- Two part-tariffs are also better for all