Title: Elasticities of demand and supply
1Elasticities of demand and supply
2The price responsiveness of demand
- The price elasticity of demand is the
percentage change in the quantity demanded
divided by the corresponding percentage change in
its price.
3- Although we later introduce other demand
elasticities - the cross-price elasticity and
the income elasticity - the (own)-price
elasticity is the most often used of the three.
If economists speak of the demand elasticity they
mean the price elasticity of demand, as defined
above. - If a 1 per cent price rise reduces the quantity
demanded by 2 per cent, the demand elasticity is
2. The minus sign tells us quantity falls when
price rises. If a price fall of 4 per cent
increases the quantity demanded by 2 per cent,
the demand elasticity is 1/2 since the quantity
change (2 per cent) is divided by the price
change (-4 per cent). Since demand curves slope
down, price and quantity changes always have
opposite signs. The price elasticity of demand
tells us about movements along a demand curve.
The demand elasticity is a negative number.
4Determinants of price elasticity
- Consider two extreme cases. Suppose the price
of all cigarettes rises by 1 per cent. The
quantity of cigarettes demanded will hardly
respond. People who can easily quit smoking have
already done so. In contrast, suppose the price
of a particular brand of cigarettes rises by 1
per cent, all other brand prices remaining
unchanged. We expect a much larger quantity
response. Consumers switch from the dearer brand
to other brands that also satisfy the nicotine
habit. For a particular cigarette brand the
demand elasticity is quite high. - Our example suggests a general rule. The more
narrowly we define a commodity (a particular
brand of cigarette rather than cigarettes in
general), the higher will be the price elasticity
of demand
5Table 4-1 The demand for football tickets
6- The price elasticity of demand for football
tickets is shown in column (3) of Table 4-1.
Examining the effect of price cuts of 2.50, we
calculate the price elasticity of demand at each
price. Beginning at 10 and 20 000 tickets
demanded, consider a price cut to 7.50. The
price change is 25 per cent, from 10 to 7.50,
the change in quantity demanded is 100 per cent,
from 20000 to 40000 tickets. The demand
elasticity at 10 is (100/25) 4. Other
elasticities are calculated in the same way,
dividing the percentage change in quantity by the
corresponding percentage change in price. When we
begin from the price of 12.50 the demand
elasticity is minus infinity. The percentage
change in quantity demanded is 20/0. Any
positive number divided by zero is infinity.
Dividing by the 20 per cent change in price,
from 12.50 to 10.00, the demand elasticity is
minus infinity at this price.
7- We say that the demand elasticity is high if it
is a large negative number. The quantity demanded
is sensitive to the price. The demand elasticity
is low if it is a small negative number and the
quantity demanded is insensitive to the price.
'High' or 'low refer to the size of the
elasticity ignoring the minus sign. The demand
elasticity falls when it becomes a smaller
negative number and quantity demanded becomes
less sensitive to the price.
8Figure 4-1 The demand for football tickets
9- The demand curve for football tickets is a
straight line with constant slope along its
entire length a 1 cut in price always leads to
8000 extra ticket sales. Yet Table 4-1 shows the
demand elasticity falls as we move down the
demand curve from higher prices to lower prices.
At high prices, 1 is a small percentage change
in the price but 8000 tickets is a large
percentage change in the quantity demanded.
Conversely, at low prices 1 is a large
percentage change in the price but 8000 is a
small percentage change in the quantity. When the
demand curve is a straight line, the price
elasticity falls steadily as we move down the
demand curve.
10- Demand is elastic if the price elasticity is
more negative than 1. Demand is inelastic if
the price elasticity lies between 1 and 0. If
the demand elasticity is exactly 1, demand is
unelastic.
11Measuring price elasticities
Table 4-2 UK price elasticities of demand
12- Table 4-2 confirms that the demand for broad
categories of basic commodities, such as fuel,
food, or even household durable goods, is
inelastic. As a category, only services such as
haircuts, the theatre, and sauna baths, have an
elastic demand. Households simply do not have
much scope to alter the broad pattern of their
purchases. - In contrast, there is a much wider variation in
the demand elasticities for narrower definitions
of commodities. Even then, the demand for some
commodities, such as dairy produce, is very
inelastic. However, particular kinds of services
such as entertainment and catering have much
more elastic demand.
13Using price elasticities
- Price elasticities of demand are useful in
calculating the price rise required to eliminate
a shortage (excess demand) or the price fall to
eliminate a surplus (excess supply). One
important source of surpluses and shortages is
shifts in the supply curve. Harvest failures (and
bumper crops) are a feature of agricultural
markets. Because the demand elasticity for many
agricultural products is very low, harvest
failures produce large increases in the price of
food. Conversely, bumper crops induce very large
falls in food prices. When demand is very
inelastic, shifts in the supply curve lead to
large fluctuations in price but have little
effect on equilibrium quantities
14Price, quantity demanded, and total expenditure
- Other things equal, the demand curve shows how
much consumers of a good wish to purchase at each
price. At each price, total spending by consumers
is the price multiplied by the quantity demanded.
We now discuss the relation between total
spending and price, and show the relevance of the
price elasticity of demand.
15Short run and long run
- The price elasticity of demand varies with time
in which consumers can adjust their spending
patterns when prices change. The most dramatic
price change of the last 50 years, the oil price
rise of 1973-74, caught many households with a
new but fuel-inefficient car. At first, they may
not have expected the higher oil price to last.
Then they may have planned to buy a smaller car
with greater fuel economy. But in countries like
the US few small cars were yet available. In the
short run, households were stuck. Unless they
could rearrange their lifestyles to reduce car
use, they had to pay the higher petrol prices.
Demand for petrol was inelastic. -
16- Over a longer period, consumers had time to
sell their big cars and buy cars with better fuel
economy, or to move from the distant suburbs
closer to their place of work. Over this longer
period, they could reduce the quantity of petrol
demanded much more than initially. - The price elasticity of demand is lower in the
short run than in the long run when there is more
scope to substitute other goods. This result is
very general. Even if addicted smokers can't
adjust to a rise in the price of cigarettes,
fewer young people start smoking and gradually
the number of smokers falls.
17- How long is the long run?
- The short run is the period after prices change
but before quantity adjustment can occur. The
long run is the period needed for complete
adjustment to a price change. Its length depends
on the type of adjustments consumers wish to make.
18The cross-price elasticity of demand
-
- The cross-price elasticity of demand for good i
with respect to changes in the price of good j is
the percentage change in the quantity of good i
demanded, divided by the corresponding percentage
change in the price of good j.
19Table 4-6 Cross-price and own-price
elasticities of demand in the UK
20- Table 4-6 shows estimates for the UK. Own-price
elasticities for food, clothing, and travel are
given down the diagonal of the table, from top
left (the own-price elasticity of demand for
food) to bottom right (the own-price elasticity
of demand for travel). Off-diagonal entries in
the table show cross-price elasticities of
demand. Thus, 0.1 is the cross-price elasticity
of demand for food with respect to travel. A 1
per cent increase in the price of travel
increases the quantity of food demanded by 0.1
per cent. - The own-price elasticities for the three goods
lie between 0.4 and 0.5. For all three goods
the quantity demanded is more sensitive to
changes in its own price than to changes in the
price of any other good.
21The effect of income on demand
- Finally, holding constant the own price of a
good and the prices of related goods, we examine
the response of the quantity demanded to changes
in consumer incomes. For the moment we neglect
the possibility of saving. Thus a rise in the
income of consumers will typically be matched by
an equivalent increase in total consumer spending.
22- The budget share of a good is its price times
the quantity demanded, divided by total consumer
spending or income - The income elasticity of demand for a good is
the percentage change in quantity demanded
divided by the corresponding percentage change in
income.
23Normal, inferior, and luxury goods
- The income elasticity of demand measures how
far the demand curve shifts horizontally when
incomes change. Figure 4-5 shows two possible
shifts caused by a given percentage increase in
income. The income elasticity is larger if the
given rise in income shifts the demand curve from
DD to D"D" than if the same income rise shifts
the demand curve only from DD to D'D'. When an
income rise shifts the demand curve to the left,
the income elasticity of demand is a negative
number, indicating that higher incomes are
associated with smaller quantities demanded at
any given prices.
24- A normal good has a positive income elasticity
of demand. An inferior good has a negative income
elasticity of demand. - We also distinguish luxury goods and necessities.
-
- A luxury good has an income elasticity above
unity. A necessity has an income elasticity below
unity. - All inferior goods are necessities, since their
income elasticities of demand are negative.
However, necessities also include normal goods
whose income elasticity of demand lies between
zero and one.
25Inflation and demand
- Elasticities measure the response of quantity
demanded to separate variations in three factors
-the own price, the price of related goods, and
income. Chapter 2 distinguished nominal
variables, measured in the prices of the day, and
real variables, which adjust for inflation when
comparing measurements at different dates. We end
this chapter by examining the effect of inflation
on demand behaviour.
26Elasticity of supply
- Whereas the analysis of demand elasticities is
quite tricky, the analysis of supply elasticities
is refreshingly simple. We really need only keep
track of the supply response to an increase in
the own price of a good or service. The
elasticity of supply measures the responsiveness
of the quantity supplied to a change in the price
of that commodity. - Supply change in quantity supplied
- elasticity change in price
27Who realty pays the tax?
- By spending and taxing, the government affects
resource allocation in the economy. By taxing - cigarettes, the government can reduce the amount
of cigarettes smoked and thereby improve health.
By taxing fuel it can discourage pollution,
though it may incur the wrath of lorry drivers
and motorists. By taxing income earned from work,
the government affects the amount of time people
want to work. Taxes loom large in the workings of
a mixed economy and have a profound effect on the
way society allocates its scarce resources.
28Consumer choice and demand decisions
29Demand by a single consumer
- The budget constraint
- A consumer's income and the market prices of
goods define her budget constraint. - The budget constraint describes the different
bundles that the consumer can afford. - Consider a student with a weekly budget
(income, allowance, or grant) of 50 to be spent
on meals or films. Each meal costs 5 and each
film 10. What combination of meals and films can
she afford? Going without films, she can spend
50 on 10 meals at 5 each. Going without meals,
she can buy 5 cinema tickets at 10 each. Between
these two extremes lie many combinations of meals
and films that together cost exactly 50. These
combinations are called the budget constraint.
30- The budget constraint shows the maximum
affordable quantity of one good given the
quantity of the other good being purchased.
31- The marginal rate of substitution of meals for
films is the quantity of films the consumer must
sacrifice to increase the quantity of meals by
one unit without changing total utility. -
- Consumers prefer more to less. An extra meal
increases utility. To hold utility constant when
a meal is added, the consumer must sacrifice some
of the other good (films). The marginal rate of
substitution tells us how many films the consumer
could exchange for an additional meal without
changing total utility.
32- Suppose the student has 5 films and no meals.
Having already seen 4 films, she does not enjoy
the fifth film much. With no meals, she is very
hungry. The utility of this bundle is low being
so hungry, she cannot enjoy films anyway. For the
same low amount of utility she could give up a
lot of films for a little food. -
33- This common-sense reasoning about tastes or
preferences is very robust. It can become a
general principle, the third assumption we need
to make about consumer tastes. It is the
assumption of a diminishing marginal rate of
substitution. - Consumer tastes exhibit a diminishing marginal
rate of substitution when, to hold utility
constant, diminishing quantities of one good will
be sacrificed to obtain successive equal
increases in the quantity of the other good.
34Utility maximization and choice
- The budget line shows affordable bundles given
a consumer's market environment (his budget and
the price of different goods). The indifference
map shows his tastes. To complete the model, we
assume the consumer chooses the affordable bundle
that maximizes his utility. - To find which point on the budget line
maximizes utility we examine the consumer's
tastes. Our glutton should pick a point with more
meals and less films than the point our film buff
selects. We first show how to use indifference
curves to find the bundle the consumer chooses.
Then we confirm that our model of consumer choice
captures the different behaviour of the glutton
and the film buff.
35Adjustment to price changes
- The substitution effect of a price change is
the adjustment of demand to the relative price
change alone. The income effect of a price change
is the adjustment of demand to the change in real
income alone.
36The market demand curve
- The market demand curve is the sum of the
- demand curves of all individuals in that market.
- At each price, we find out how much each
consumer demands. Adding the quantities demanded
by all consumers at that price, we get the total
quantity demanded at each price, the market
demand curve. Since, as price is reduced, each
person increases the quantity demanded, the total
quantity demanded must also increase as price
falls. The market demand curve also slopes
downwards. - The market demand curve is the horizontal
addition of individual demand curves. With prices
on the vertical axis and quantities on the
horizontal axis, we must add together individual
quantities demanded at the same price.
37Complements and substitutes
- Income and substitution effects are used to
understand the effects of a price change.
Whatever the direction of the income effect, with
only two goods the substitution effect is always
negative. The pure relative price effect leads
the consumer to substitute away from the good
whose relative price has risen towards the good
whose relative price has fallen. Abstracting from
income effects, goods are necessarily substitutes
for one another in a two-good world.
38- Even with many goods, there is always a
substitution effect away from goods whose
relative price has risen. However, substitution
may not be towards all other goods. Consumers
substitute away from goods consumed jointly with
the good whose price has risen.
39Transfers in kind
- A transfer is a payment, usually by the
government, for which no corresponding service
is provided by the recipient. A transfer in kind
is the gift of a good or service.
40