Title: DETERMINANTS OF DEPOSITINSURANCE ADOPTION AND DESIGN
1DETERMINANTS OF DEPOSIT-INSURANCE ADOPTION AND
DESIGN
February, 2005
- Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, World Bank
- Edward J. Kane, Boston College
- Luc Laeven, World Bank
2- Most countries do not have an explicit
deposit-insurance scheme (EDIS) - A countrys level of economic and financial
development tells partbut only partof the
story. - Most of the poorest and least financially
developed countries have no EDIS at all and most
high-income countries do. - Table 1 partitions 181 sample countries for which
we have per capita income data into quartiles and
shows that the propensity to adopt an EDIS rises
with income
3Table 1 Distribution of Countries with and
without explicit deposit insurance by income
quartile at yearend 2003The data come from the
World Bank Deposit Insurance Database (2004),
compiled from the International Association of
Deposit Insurers (IADI) and national sources. The
total number of countries included is 181.
Blanket guarantees are coded as EDIS.
4(No Transcript)
5- We use logit regressions and hazard models to
investigate the extent to which other economic,
political, and institutional variables help to
explain whether and when a country decides to
install an EDIS. - Treating the logit adoption model as a Heckman
selection equation, we go on to estimate whether
an how country characteristics affect the
effectiveness of the risk-shifting controls that
the scheme embodies.
6Structural Supply and Demand Functions For an
EDIS Cannot Readily Be Identified
- Per capita GDP affects both demand for coverage
and the tax capacity needed to supply EDI in a
credible fashion - Crises and follow-on threats of systemic runs
increase both the demand for EDI by bank
stakeholders and incumbents willingness to
supply it - Political power-sharing increases voice of
sectors seeking EDI subsidies and the benefits to
politicians of supplying these subsidies
7- In some cases, a presumption that an EDIS
represents a hallmark of regulatory best practice
may have outweighed the contrary influence of
internal economic, institutional, and political
counterforces. - To test this hypothesis, our model inserts into
models featuring domestic determinants of
regulatory decisions a proxy for emulation,
reflecting the spread of EDI systems. - It is important to see both that emulation is
an accelerating trend variable and that we are
assigning an interpretation for the trend - Without a potentially testable interpretation,
any trend is an empty concept
8- We also test the complementary hypothesis that
outside (especially IMF) crisis-management advice
might direct countries that experience a systemic
crisis to erect an EDIS as either a myopic way of
containing crises or an overly hopeful way of
formally winding down crisis-generated blanket
guarantees.
9EMULATION
Crisis-Influenced Adoption of EDIS
10Hypothesis-Testing Strategy
- As potential economic determinants, we include
macroeconomic conditions, financial-crisis
events, fiscal costs incurred in crises, and
inefficiencies presumed to be associated with
state-owned banks. - As potential institutional and political
determinants, we include various features of the
countrys private and public contracting
environments - Transparency (T)
- Deterrency (D)
- Bonding (B)
- Accountability (A)
11MTMDMBNA Thought Experiment When Would
Government DI Produce No Benefits at All?
- MAXIMAL TRANSPARENCY (MT)
- MAXIMAL DETERRENCY (MD)
- MAXIMAL BONDING (MB)
- NO ACCOUNTABILITY (NA)
12- Table 2 names the design features our dataset
covers and the country characteristics that the
regression experiments employ. The unit of
observation is a country-year. The table reports
summary statistics on all variables.
13- Table 3. Explicit deposit insurance systems at
yearend 2003 - This table lists the countries that adopted
explicit deposit insurance systems by yearend
2003. The data come from the World Bank Deposit
Insurance Database (2004). GDP and bank deposits
per capita are from International Financial
Statistics (IFS). The following non-adopting
countries are included in our sample
Afghanistan, Angola, Armenia, Australia,
Azerbaijan, Barbados, Belize, Benin, Bhutan,
Bolivia, Botswana, Brunei, Burkina Faso, Burundi,
Cambodia, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African
Republic, Chad, China, Comoro Islands, Costa
Rica, Cote d'Ivoire, Cuba, Djibouti, Egypt,
Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Fiji,
Gabon, Gambia, Georgia, Ghana, Grenada, Guinea,
Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Haiti, Hong Kong (China),
Iran, Iraq, Israel, Kiribati, Kyrgyz Republic,
Laos, Lesotho, Liberia, Libya, Madagascar,
Malawi, Maldives, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius,
Moldovad, Mongolia, Morocco, Mozambique, Myanmar,
Namibia, Nepal, New Zealand, Niger, Pakistan,
Panama, Papua New Guinea, Qatar, Republic of
Congo, Rwanda, Saudi Arabia, Senegal, Seychelles,
Sierra Leone, Singapore, Solomon Islands,
Somalia, South Africa, St. Lucia, Sudan,
Suriname, Swaziland, Syria, Tajikistan, Togo,
Tunisia, United Arab Emirates, Uruguay,
Uzbekistan, Vanuatu, W. Samoa, Yemen, Zaire,
Zambia. The total number of countries covered is
181.
14Evidence from Logit Models of the Adoption
Decision
- Parsimonious models restricted to economic
determinants - GDP per capita shows the strongest influence
- Including the emulation proxy wipes out the other
economic variables, though we carry a few
insignificant variables in subsequent rounds of
testing as a robustness check. - Expanded Models
- Crisis experience proves significant
- Government ownership/privatization does not
- Most variables representing political
power-sharing and social capital prove
significant, but ICRG measures of corruption and
law and order do not. - Effect of emulation is stronger and effect of per
capita GDP is weaker when we exclude countries
with small populations or introduce continent
dummies.
15- Robustness tests employ three kinds of
statistical models and alternative indices of
political and cultural influences. - Qualitative conclusions about the separate
effects of emulation and other types of
determinants prove robust.
16(No Transcript)
17Evidence from Weibull Hazard Models
- As represented by the evolutionary parameter,
emulation is even more significant than per
capita GDP. - Crisis experience and political power-sharing
proxy are also significant
18Hazard models of deposit-insurance adoption
- This table estimates the hazard rate of adopting
explicit deposit insurance over the period
1934-2003. The model considers the adoption of
deposit insurance as a transforming event. The
endogenous variable is the number of years
between 1934 and the adoption date. The
coefficients reported are the logarithms of the
underlying relative-hazard coefficients. The
number of transformations is the number of
countries that adopted deposit insurance during
the observation period.
19EDIS Design Features Shown Empirically to Inhibit
Risk-Shifting
- Enforceable Coverage Limitations
- Coinsurance
- Risk-rated Premiums
- Private Involvement in System Management
- Compulsory Membership
- Funding of Contingent Liabilities Entails Clear
Right to Levy Ex Post Assessments on Insured
Institutions
20Evidence from Heckman Two-Step Models of Design
Features
- Heckman Lambda significantly and favorably
influences the adoption of - Four individual features the ratio of coverage
to GDP per capita compulsory membership
coinsurance absence of permanent funding. - A multifeature moral-hazard exposure composite
extracted via principal-component analysis. - Models for private participation in EDIS
management, private funding, and coverage for
foreign or interbank deposits show a mixed and
marginal influence for per capita GDP and the
two crisis variables.
21- GDP per capita, emulation, and crisis dummy show
a positive (i.e., perverse) and significant
influence on design. Post-crisis adoption is
positive (i.e., also perverse) in the four cases
where it is significant.
22Table 10 Heckman two-step selection model for
adoption of deposit-insurance design features