Title: EMEA4: General Equilibrium Models
1EMEA4 General Equilibrium Models
- A small exchange economy
- A large exchange economy
- A production economy
- Theory and practice
- Applications
- Climate change and agriculture
- Sea level rise
- Biodiversity conservation
- Markets, efficiency, optimality, utilitarianism
- Top-down versus bottom-up models
2Bilateral Exchange
- Consider an economy with two commodities and two
consumers. Each consumer has an initial endowment
of both commodities. - Assume non-satiation, rationality, strict
convexity, no cost of exchange, perfect
information - The exchange rate of commodity 1 for commodity 2
is the inverse of the exchange rate of 2 for 1
3Bilateral Exchange -2
- Consumption cannot exceed the initial endowment
plus whats acquired through exchange. For good
1, consumer 1 - The same holds for good 2
- The last bit follows from the symmetry of prices
4Bilateral Exchange -3
- Add the two constraints
- Divide by two and add
- Or, total consumption (measured in commodity 1)
should not exceed total endowments - Because of satiation, equality
5Bilateral Exchange -4
- Now introducte utility maximisation, subject to
the two constaints just derived this gives the
demand functions - The economy has two constraints
- So, there are 6 equations and 5 variables
- This is no problem because the equations are not
independent (Walras Law)
6Bilateral Exchange -5
- Add the total budget constraints of the two
agents - Subtract the market equilibrium for good 1
- Divide by the price, and you have the market
equilibrium for good 2 - So, five equations, five variables
7General Exchange
- Now consider an economy with m consumers and n
goods. Each consumer has a conventional utility
function. Each consumer has a non-negative bundle
of commodities as an initial endowments. - The exchange rates between the goods can be
written as a matrix
8General Exchange -2
- The exchange rate matrix satisfies all sorts of
constraints. The diagonal elements are unity, and
it is inverse-symmetric - But also
- This allows for normalisation
9General Exchange -3
- A feasible exchange of good i for j meets
- That is, the exchange does not change the value
of the consumers holdings - This holds for all goods, so
10General Exchange -4
- Each consumer maximises under constraint
- Of course, the markets are in equilibrium
11General Exchange -5
- Define market demand
- Define market supply
- Market equilibrium follows from
- Note that there is again a redundant equation!
12Production Economy
- Consider an economy with m consumers, l producers
and n commodities - Assume that producers maximise profits, and that
the production process can be represented by a
regular production function Profits are handed
to consumers - Consumers are rational etcetera
- There is no cost of exchange there is perfect
information Therefore, exchange ratios are
equated by arbitrage normalise all prices with
good 1
13Production Economy -2
- Consumer behaviour follows from
- From which we can derive
- Producer behaviour follows from
- From which we can derive
14Production Economy -3
- Market equilibrium
- There are nm demand functions (and demands), nl
net supply functions (and supplies), l profit
functions (and profits), and n equilibrium
conditions (and only n-1 prices) - Walras Law again ensures identification
15Computable General Equilibrium Models
- We have now seen 3 general equilibrium models
tomorrow, well introduce time - We could analyse under what conditions an
equilibrium exists, is unique, and equals a
social optimum - Instead, we will look at two empirical examples
- Empirical studies use computable general
equilibrium models, because full-fledged general
equilibrium involves more
16CGEs
- CGEs will deliver quantities and prices
- CGEs need a number of inputs
- Typically, there is a representative consumer
- Typically, there is a representative producer for
each good - Consumption, intermediates and prices (for
calibration) are easy to get - The hard bit is the elasticities
- Programming and solving is easy nowadays
17Applied CGEs
- Ill show three examples
- FARM is an 8-region, 11-sector, 13 commodity
static CGE - It uses nested CES production functions
- It distinguished between domestic and foreign
product with Armington elasticities - It is coupled to a GIS of land quantity and
quality - GTAP is another static CGE, adjusted to look at
impacts of climate change
18Production Functions
- Constant Elasticity of Substitution
19(No Transcript)
20Prices and Production in the EC, 10 Land
Retirement
21Sea level rise
- Impact of sea level rise from Hoozemans et al.
(1993) dryland loss and costs of protection - Dryland lost is a loss of the endowment land
- Coastal protection is a defensive investment,
financed by a forced increase in savings note
that we are using a static CGE
22(No Transcript)
23(No Transcript)
24Virtual Water
- How much water is needed for a cup of coffee?
- 125 ml water and 7 g coffee
- In Brasil, you need about 3000 m3 water per tonne
of coffee cherries - After washing, drying, roasting etc., this makes
22500 m3 water per tonne of coffee - That makes 140 l water for 7 g coffee
- 14 buckets, 1100 cups
- This water is not from the environs of Hamburg,
however
25Netherlands Virtual import of water for coffee
Besides for coffee, one could do this for
tee, cotton, wheat and all other products.
26Import and Export of virtual water (absolute)
27Import and Export of virtual water (relative)
28(No Transcript)
29No more fossil water
30Trade liberalisation
31Markets, Efficiency, Optimality, Utilitarianism
- Economic efficiency is also known as Pareto
optimality - A situation is Pareto superior to another
situation if no one is worse off and someone is
better off - It is hard to disagree with Pareto superiority as
a decision criterion - If there are no Pareto improvements possible, the
economy is an Pareto optimum - Under certain regularity conditions, this optimum
is unique
32Markets, Efficiency, Optimality, Utilitarianism
- A market transaction is voluntary, and therefore
mutually beneficial, that is Pareto improving - The market would thus work to exhaust Pareto
improvements until it is in equilibrium this
implies that the market leads to a Pareto optimum
under certain conditions, the Pareto optimum - That is, through individual, selfish action, the
social optimum is established
33Markets, Efficiency, Optimality, Utilitarianism
- Pareto improvements increase the welfare of some,
decrease the welfare of none hence, a Pareto
improvement increases the sum of individual
welfare - In the Pareto optimum, the sum of individual
welfare is maximum - The sum of individual welfare is known as
(strictly) utilitarian welfare - Hence, the market establishes the Pareto optimum,
the utilitarian optimum, and economic efficiency
34Markets, Efficiency, Optimality, Utilitarianism
- Note that Pareto optimality etc is defined
conditional on the starting point, that is, the
initial distribution of income and goods - We take the current situation as given, and seek
to improve on that without harming anyone, that
is, without questioning the current situation - Besides Pareto improvements, there are potential
Pareto improvements that is, someone gains and
someone loses, but the gains are sufficient to
compensate the losses this does not necessarily
happen
35Markets, Efficiency, Optimality, Utilitarianism
- As the outcome of decentralised behaviour in the
market, that is, millions of producers and
consumers acting in their own self-interest,
corresponds to the outcome of a central planner
we may rewrite the market equilibrium as a social
planning problem - The difference is that in the former
representation, you would need to find the
maximum of a million problems or a zero- or
fixed-point in a high-dimensional space
36Top-down and bottom-up
- CGEs are sometimes referred to as top-down
models, as opposed to engineering models that are
known as bottom-up models - Top-down models work under the assumption that
actors are rational and markets are perfect - That implies that every polity that constrains a
resource is necessarily costly the economy is at
its summit, and the only way is down
37Top-down and bottom-up -2
- Bottom-up models include elaborate technologies
as well as their costs - These models typically find that one can save
money while reducing emissions - The rivalry between top-down and bottom has been
bitter - Bottom-up models only include investment and
maintenance costs and tend to use discount rates
that are too low - Bottom-up models optimise a system from an
environmental perspective, not from a welfare
perspective
38Top-down and bottom-up -3
- So, part of the cost savings of bottom-up models
are simply wrong - However, there may be some left
- Particularly, if markets are distorted (e.g.,
coal subsidies) or there are principal agent
problems (e.g., Hamburg U), then money can be
made - CGEs would almost never pick this up
- However, reducing market distortions require very
smart policy interventions, perhaps beyond our
dear leaders