Title: Gift Giving
1Gift Giving
2Your last gift.
- What was the last gift you received (money
counts)? - Who gave it to you (parent, grandparent, friend)?
- What would you estimate the price the person paid
to buy it? - What is the amount of cash such that you are
indifferent between the gift and the cash, not
counting the sentimental value of the gift? - Why do you value or not value this gift?
3Summary of gift survey.
- If you are an aunt, dont give socks!
- Beware of taking a girlfriend on holiday.
- Cash from parents/grandparents was appreciated.
- A bit surprised that a few that a bad DVD cost
them 5, but they wanted 10 for it. - Some thought that the gifts they gave increased
value. - Others thought they would decrease value but the
gave them anyway. Why? - Some listed a bad gift as one that had little
value or showed little thought even though the
yield was okay. Why? - Any suggests for improvement of the survey (such
as understanding email me).
4Todd Kaplan and Bradley Ruffle (2008) "In search
of welfare-improving gifts".
- Motivation
- claim that gift giving is welfare reducing rests
on several assumptions - the giver does not perfectly know the recipients
preferences. - gifts cannot be costlessly refunded.
- gift recipients possess full information as to
whereabouts of goods they desire - gift recipients are able to obtain such goods
costlessly - Kaplan and Ruffle (KR) break with this literature
by relaxing assumptions 3 4 - 1) they add uncertainty about the existence
location of goods and - 2) search costs to resolve this uncertainty
- importance of search-cost savings in modern gift
giving can be heard in common expressions of
gratitude upon receipt of a gift "where did you
find it? I've looked all over for this item."
5Simplified Model
- There is a giver and a receiver.
- The giver is at a store and has to decide whether
or not to buy a gift for the receiver. - The receiver would have to spend c to visit the
store. - The gift costs p to purchase.
- There is an a chance of the good having value v
(gtp) to the receiver (otherwise it is worth 0).
6Two ways of getting the good
- Shopping the receiver travels to the store and
buys the good, the social benefit is a (v-p)-c - Gift Giving the giver gives the good to the
receiver, the social benefit is a v-p - When is gift giving better than shopping?
- a v-pgt a (v-p)-c
- Or cgt(1- a )p
- Thus, we have gift giving if cgt(1- a )p and a vgtp
Gift giving is better than shopping
Giving is not waste of money
7Interpretation of requirements
- Gifts when cgt(1- a )p and a vgtp
- Grandmother effect when a is low, give cash
since a vltp. - When a is high, gifts are better option than
buying it oneself best friends. - When c is high, gifts are better.
- v doesnt affect which method is superior.
- Examples what is the social value of gift
giving, a v-p, and shopping, a (v-p)-c, when - (c,v,p,a)(1,2,1,.6), (1,3,1,.6),(1,6,2,.3),(1,8,2
,.3) - gggt0gtshop, gggtshopgt0, shopgt0gtgg, shopgtgggt0
8Why is gift giving still made?
- If someone has better information, lower search
costs or a location advantage, why do they need
to give gifts? - Cant they just charge money?
9Why not trade instead of give?
- Cant the giver simply make a profit buying from
the store and selling to the receiver? - In such a case, the receiver would only buy the
good if it is worth v (with probability a). - The receiver would bargain to purchase the good
for a price less than v (buying at v would leave
him indifferent). - Go back to (c,v,p,a)(1,2,1,.6).
- If the giver spends 1, and sales it to the buyer
for 1.9 (ltv2), he would on average receive 1.14
for a profit of .14. - How much must the giver get from the receiver in
order to make a profit? - This lack of trade is called the hold-up problem.
10Why not trade (part 2)?
- We can interpret our model as an information
acquisition model. - The giver knows more than the about the good.
- The giver knows this is something the receiver
potential wants (with prob a ). - The giver may at other times see other products
with lower a . - The cost c is what it costs for the receiver to
learn whether it is something he wants. - Trade would not solve this basic problem, since
the receiver would still have to spend c and
without doing so the giver would have incentive
to push unwanted products. (The
stereo/car/fashion salesman.)
11Experiment game
- We ran an experiment on what is called the
Beer-Quiche Game (Cho Kreps, 1987). - Proposer has 2/3 chance of being strong.
- He can eat Beer or Quiche.
- Strong types like Beer. Weak types like Quiche.
- Responder can fight or flee. Responders dont
want to fight a strong type.
12Signalling in the LabTreatment 1
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 2.00, 1.25 1.20, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 2.00, 0.75 1.20, 1.25
- For a strong proposer, (Beer, flee)gt(Beer,
fight)gt(Quiche, flee)gt(Quiche, fight). - For a weak proposer, (Quiche, flee)gt(Quiche,
fight)gt(Beer, flee)gt(Beer, fight). - Strong chooses Beer and Weak chooses Quiche
13Signalling in the LabTreatment 1
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 2.00, 1.25 1.20, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 2.00, 0.75 1.20, 1.25
- Responder now knows that Beer is the choice of
the strong type and Quiche is the choice of the
weak type. - For Beer he flees, for Quiche he fights.
14Signalling in the LabTreatment 1
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 2.00, 1.25 1.20, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 2.00, 0.75 1.20, 1.25
- So the equilibrium is
- For strong, (Beer, Flee)
- For weak, (Quiche, Fight)
- This is called a separating equilibrium.
- Any incentive to deviate?
15Signalling in the LabTreatment 1
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 2.00, 1.25 1.20, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 2.00, 0.75 1.20, 1.25
32
13
What did you do? In the last 5 rounds, there were
32 Strong and 13 Weak proposers
16Treatment 2.
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 1.40, 1.25 0.60, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 1.40, 0.75 0.60, 1.25
- Can we have a separating equilibrium here?.
- If the proposer is weak, he can choose Beer and
get 1.00 instead of 0.60.
17Treatment 2.
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 1.40, 1.25 0.60, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 1.40, 0.75 0.60, 1.25
- Can choosing Beer independent of being strong or
weak be an equilibrium? - Yes! The responder knows there is a 2/3 chance of
being strong, thus flees. - This is called a pooling equilibrium.
18Treatment 2.
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 1.40, 1.25 0.60, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 1.40, 0.75 0.60, 1.25
4
30
3
8
- Did we have a pooling equilibrium?
- In the last 5 rounds there were 34 strong
proposers and 11 weak proposers. - Do you think there is somewhat to help the
pooling equilibrium to form?
19Treatment 2.
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 1.40, 1.25 0.60, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 1.40, 0.75 0.60, 1.25
23
14
3
- At Texas AM, the aggregate numbers were shown.
- In the last 5 periods, 23 proposers were strong
and 17 weak.
20Signalling game
- Spence got the Nobel prize in 2001 for this.
- There are two players A and B. Player A is
either strong or weak. - Player B will chose one action (flee) if he knows
player A is strong - and another action (fight) if he knows player A
is weak. - Player A can send a costly signal to Player B (in
this case it was to drink beer).
21Signal
- For signalling to have meaning,
- we must have either cost of the signal higher for
the weak type. - Or the gain from the action higher for the strong
type.
22Types of equilibria
- Separating.
- Strong signal
- Weak dont signal.
- Pooling.
- Strong and weak both send the signal.
- (or Strong and weak both dont send the signal.)
23Types of equilibria
- Player A is the proposer and B the responder.
- The types of player A are s and w.
- Let us normalize the value to A when B fights to
0. - The values to A when B flees are Vs and Vw.
- The cost to signalling (drinking beer) are Cs and
Cw. - We get a separating equilibria if Vs-Csgt0 and
Vw-Cwlt0. - We get a pooling equilibria if Vs-Cslt0 and
Vw-Cwlt0 (no one signals). - We may also get a pooling equilibria if Vs-Csgt0
and Vw-Cwgt0 and there are enough s types. - For this to happen, there must be enough s types
such that the expected payoff of B is higher
fleeing than fighting.
24Treatment 2 Other pooling?.
Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder Payoffs Proposer, Responder
Flee Fight
Beer (Strong) 1.40, 1.25 0.60, 0.75
Quiche (Strong) 1.00, 1.25 0.20, 0.75
Beer (Weak) 1.00, 0.75 0.20, 1.25
Quiche (Weak) 1.40, 0.75 0.60, 1.25
- How about both proposers eat quiche and the
responder flees? Is this an equilibrium? - If responders think anyone who drinks Beer must
be weak. - Cho-Kreps introduce an intuitive criteria that
says this does not make sense. - Any proposer drinking Beer must be strong,
because the weak type can only lose from doing so.
25How does this relate to gift giving?
- Gift giving can be wasteful. (Why not give ?)
- Basically, you get someone a gift to signal your
intent. - American Indian tribes, a ceremony to initiate
relations with another tribe included the burning
of the tribes most valuable possession.
26Courtship gifts.
- Dating Advice.
- Advice 1 never take such advice from an
economist. - Advice 2.
- Say that there is someone that is a perfect match
for you. You know this, they just havent figured
it out yet. - Offer to take them to a really expensive place.
- It would only make sense for you to do this, if
you knew that you would get a relationship out of
it. - That person should then agree to go.
27Valentines Day
- Who bought a card, chocolate, etc?
- We are forced to spend in order to signal that we
really care. - Say that you are either serious or not serious
about your relationship. - If your partner knew you were not serious, he or
she would break up with you. - A card is pretty inexpensive, so both types buy
it to keep the relationship going. - Your partner keeps the relationship since there
is a real chance you are serious. - No real information is gained, but if you didnt
buy the card, your partner would assume that you
are not serious and break up with you.
28Higher value and/or Lower Cost
- Higher value
- You buy someone a gift to signal that you care.
- Sending a costly signal means that they mean a
lot to you. - For someone that doesnt mean so much, you
wouldnt buy them such a gift. - Lower cost
- The person knows you well.
- Shopping for you costs them less.
- They signal that they know you well.
29Other types of signalling in the world
- University Education.
- Showing up to class.
- Praying. Mobile phone for Orthodox Jews
- Poker Raising stakes (partial).
- Peacock tails.
- Limit pricing.
30Homework
- 2 Questions are due on Friday, Oct 24th.
- Links the them and how to submit them are from
the webpage.