Title: Canberra Skeptics
1Canberra Skeptics
- World Poverty
- Explanations and Proposed Solutions
- Thomas Pogge
- Leitner Professor of Philosophy and International
Affairs, Yale University - with additional affiliations at
- the Australian Centre for Applied Philosophy and
Public Ethics (CAPPE) - and the University of Oslo Centre for the Study
of Mind in Nature (CSMN)
21
3MDG-1 Poverty Progress
4(No Transcript)
5The Grand Promise to Halve Poverty by 2015 First
Version
- 1996 World Food Summit in Rome the number of
extremely poor is to be halved during 1996-2015.
This implies an annual reduction by 3.58 (50
over 19 years). - We pledge our political will and our common and
national commitment to achieving food security
for all and to an on-going effort to eradicate
hunger in all countries, with an immediate !
view to reducing the number of undernourished
people to half their present level no later than
2015. - www.fao.org/docrep/003/w3613e/w3613e00.htm
6The Grand Promise to Halve Poverty by 2015
Second Version
- 1996 World Food Summit in Rome the number of
extremely poor is to be halved during 1996-2015.
This implies an annual reduction by 3.58. - 2000 Millennium Development Goal (MDG) 1 the
proportion of extremely poor among the worlds
people is to be halved 2000-2015. This implies
annual reduction by 3.35 (40 15yrs). - to halve, by the year 2015, the proportion of
the worlds people whose income is less than one
dollar a day and the proportion of people who
suffer from hunger. - www.un.org/millennium/declaration/ares552e.htm
7The Grand Promise to Halve Poverty by 2015 Third
Version
- 1996 World Food Summit in Rome the number of
extremely poor is to be halved during 1996-2015.
This implies an annual reduction by 3.58. - 2000 Millennium Development Goal 1 (MDG-1) the
proportion of extremely poor among the worlds
people is to be halved 2000-2015. This implies
annual reduction by 3.35 (40 15 yrs). - MDG-1 as subsequently revised by the UN
the proportion of extremely poor among the
population of the developing countries is to be
halved 1990-2015. This implies an annual
reduction by 1.25 (27 over 25 years).
8Goal 1 Eradicate Extreme Hunger and Poverty
- Target 1. Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the
proportion of people whose income is less than
US1 a day - Target 2. Halve, between 1990 and 2015, the
proportion of people who suffer from hunger - UN The Millennium Development Goals Report
2008, p.6 www.un.org/millenniumgoals
9www.un.org/millenniumgoals/MDG-Page1.pdf
www.un.org/millenniumgoals/sgreport2002.pdf?OpenEl
ement
8
10A Promise Diluted
112
12Updating the World Banks International Poverty
Line
- The Bank initially fixed its IPL at 1.02
1985-dollars per day, noting that eight poor
countries 1985 domestic poverty lines were close
to this amount. Soon rounded down to 1.00
1985-dollar per day. - In 2000 the Bank reset its IPL to 1.08
1993-dollars per day, noting that this was the
median of the ten lowest domestic poverty lines
in 1993. - In mid-2008 the Bank reset its IPL again to 1.25
2005-dollars per day, noting that this was the
mean of the 15 poorest countries domestic
poverty lines. - Many of the domestic poverty lines used to
anchor all these IPLs are themselves fixed by
the Bank.
13Updating the World Banks International Poverty
Line
- Used from 1990 until 1999
- 1.02 1985-dollar per day, today 2.03 in US
- 1.00 1985-dollar per day, today 1.99 in US
- Used from 2000 until 2008
- 1.08 1993-dollar per day, today 1.60 in US
- Used since August 2008
- 1.25 2005-dollar per day, today 1.37 in US
or 9.59 per week or 500 annually - www.bls.gov/data/inflation_calculator.htm
12
14Is 1.25 (2005) a day enough?
- The US Department of Agriculture has for many
decades published data about what it costs to
adhere to an elaborately designed low-cost food
plan that was variously called the Restricted
Food Plan for Emergency Use, the Economy Food
Plan . . . developed as a nutritionally adequate
diet for short-term or emergency use, and the
Thrifty Food Plan. In 2005, the cost of
purchasing this minimal diet for a household of
two to four people was (depending on household
size and childrens ages) between 3.59 and 4.97
per person per day. - www.cnpp.usda.gov/USDAFoodCost-Home.htm
15Is 1.25 (2005) a day enough?
- The cost of the USDAs Thrifty Food Plan covers
the cost of nutrition only. It includes no money
at all for minimal requirements of clothing,
shelter, medical care, water and other utilities. - But perhaps food and other necessities are
cheaper in the countries in which very poor
people live than they are in the United States?
16Is 1.25 (2005) a day enough?
- The Bank converts its International Poverty Line
(IPL) at purchasing power parities (PPPs) and
thus takes cost of living differences into
account. (The PPPs of poor countries are
calculated to be, typically, between one third
and one half of the currency exchange rate.) The
Banks whole methodology is based on the
assumption that its PPPs for individual
consumption expenditure by households facilitate
accurate comparisons of incomes and consumption
expenditures by poor households anywhere.
17Is 1.25 (2005) a day enough?
- But actually, the much narrower and more
poverty-relevant PPPs for food and nonalcoholic
beverages are considerably higher ? in each and
every one of 88 listed poor countries ? than the
broader PPPs used in the Banks conversion. They
are, on average, 51.6 percent higher. At the
Banks converted IPL, poor people can buy about
as much food as could be bought with US0.83 in
the US in 2005. - siteresources.worldbank.org/ICPINT/Resources/icp-f
inal.pdf, pp. 28-37
18(No Transcript)
19(No Transcript)
20(No Transcript)
21(No Transcript)
22(No Transcript)
23The Impact of the IPL level on the Banks Poverty
Count
- It is very obvious that the lower the Bank sets
its IPL, the fewer poor people it will count. It
is less obvious how the level of the IPL will
affect the charted evolution of poverty a lower
poverty line will reduce the poverty count in
each year and may therefore have no effect on the
assessed poverty trend at all. (The Bank uses
2005 PPPs to convert its IPL into 2005 local
currency units (LCUs), then national consumer
price indices to convert it further into LCUs of
other years.)
24Poverty Definition and MDG-1
23
econ.worldbank.org/docsearch Paper 4703, pp.
34-5
25Another Reality Check
- While the Bank reports a stream of good news from
the poverty front, the FAO has recently reported
that the number of chronically undernourished
people (Target 2 of MDG-1) is exceeding 1 billion
for the first time ever. In the 1990s and until
2006 this number was reported to be around 800
million. One important cause food prices doubled
2006-08 (partly on account of rapidly rising
biofuel demand). - www.fao.org/news/story/en/item/20568/icode/
-
26Would a higher IPL be Hopelessly Unrealistic?
- Using its latest IPL (1.25 per day or 38 per
month, in 2005 intl dollars), the World Bank
counts 1.4 billion poor people living 28 below
this line on average. Total deficit 0.15 of
world product (0.33 at PPP). - With a less inadequate poverty line of 2 per
day or 61 per month (2005 intl dollars), the
Bank counts 2.6 billion poor people living 40
below this line on average. Total deficit 0.6
of world product (1.3 at PPP). - With a more HR-realistic poverty line of 2.50
per day or 76 per month (2005 intl dollars),
the Bank counts 3.14 billion poor living 45
below this line on average. Total deficit 1.1
of world product (2.2 at PPP). - econ.worldbank.org/docsearch Paper 4703, pp. 23,
34-5
25
27Primary Cause Poverty
- Among ca. 6800 million human beings, about
- 1020 million are chronically undernourished (FAO
2009) - 2000 million lack access to essential drugs
(www.fic.nih.gov/about/plan/exec_summary.htm), - 884 million lack safe drinking water
(WHO/UNICEF 2008, 32), - 924 million lack adequate shelter (UN Habitat
2003, p. vi), - 1600 million have no electricity (UN Habitat,
Urban Energy), - 2500 million lack adequate sanitation (WHO/UNICEF
2008, p. 7), - 774 million adults are illiterate
(www.uis.unesco.org), - 218 million children (aged 5 to 17) do wage
work outside their household often under
slavery-like and hazardous conditions as
soldiers, prostitutes or domestic servants, or in
agriculture, construction, textile or carpet
production (ILO The End of Child Labour, Within
Reach, 2006, pp. 9, 11, 17-18).
26
28Millions of Deaths
27
293
- Intranational and Global Inequality
3029
31Global Inequality
- At current exchange rates, the poorest half of
world population, 3,400 million, have less than
3 of global household income ? the same as the
most affluent 300,000 (0.1) in the US. - Spreadsheets from Branko Milanovic, World Bank
- Saez Tables and Figures Updated,
elsa.berkeley.edu/saez/ - At current exchange rates, the poorest half of
the worlds population, some 3,400 million, have
ca. 1 of global wealth ? as against 3 had by
the worlds 1125 billionaires (2008!). - www.iariw.org/papers/2006/davies.pdf, table 10A,
p. 47 - www.forbes.com/2008/03/05/richest-billionaires-peo
ple-billionaires08-cx_lk_0305intro.html
32Shares of Global Wealth2000 poorest versus
richest households
Calculated in market exchange rates so as to
reflect avoidability of poverty. Decile Ineq.
28371. Quintile Ineq. 851. Year 2000, 125
trillion total. (www.iariw.org/papers/2006/davies.
pdf, table 10A, p. 47)
31
33Rising Inequality in the US
- In the last US economic expansion (2002-06),
average per capita household income grew 12. - In the top one percent this growth was 51, in
the remainder of the population 4. - The top percentile captured 73 of the real per
capita growth of the US economy (45 in the
1993-2000 Clinton expansion). - Saez Updated, elsa.berkeley.edu/saez/, Table
1, from IRS Data
32
34Rising Inequality in the US (1978-2005)
- The income share of the bottom half declined
from 26.4 to 12.8. Meanwhile, that of the top
one percent rose from 8.95 to 22.90 (2.6-fold)
that of the top tenth percent from 2.65 to
11.58 (4.4- fold) and that of the top hundredth
percent from 0.86 to 5.46 (6.4-fold Saez Table
A3). The top hundredth percent (30,000 people)
now have nearly half as much income as the bottom
half (150 million) of Americans and nearly half
as much also as the bottom half (3400 million) of
world population.
33
35Kuznets curve is the graphical representation of
Simon Kuznets's theory ('Kuznets hypothesis')
that economic inequality increases over time
while a country is developing, then after a
critical average income is attained, begins to
decrease. One theory as to why this happens
states that in early stages of development, when
investment in physical capital is the main
mechanism of economic growth, inequality
encourages growth by allocating resources towards
those who save and invest the most. Whereas in
mature economies human capital accrual, or an
estimate of cost that has been incurred but not
yet paid, takes the place of physical capital
accrual as the main source of growth, and
inequality slows growth by lowering education
standards because poor people lack finance for
their education in imperfect credit markets.
Kuznets curve diagrams show an inverted U curve,
although variables along the axes are often mixed
and matched, with inequality or the Gini
coefficent on the Y axis and economic
development, time or per capita incomes on the X
axis. Wikipedia
36Whats Happening in China?
- In China, 1990-2004, the income share of the
bottom half declined from 27 to 18 ? while that
of the top tenth rose from 25 to 35. - papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id799844
- Note new inequality figures at WB World
Development Indicators
35
37China
38What is Happening Globally?
- Growth in international inequality has stalled
except with respect to the poorest countries (the
bottom billion). - Global inequality continues to increase, mainly
because of whats happening within countries.
Many more are trapped in severe poverty than just
those bottom billion and, with international
income inequality rising over the last 25 years,
the shares of global top fractiles must have
increased similar to within-US. - Best source Branko Milanovic, World Bank
37
3938
404
- Hypothesis about Competitive/ Adversarial Systems
41Competitive/Adversarial Systems
- ? e.g. real economy, financial markets,
politics and international relations, courts,
academic research, media ? can be highly
efficient when they are properly framed. Proper
framing is achieved when the rewards players seek
from the system are highly correlated with the
creation of social value. Proper framing requires
that the rules of the game are appropriately
designed and that these rules are administered in
a transparent and impartial way.
40
42Competitive/Adversarial Systems
- contain seeds of their own demise /
deterioration insofar as they provide incentives
to various reward-focused players to try to get
ahead by affecting, in their own favor, either
the rules or their impartial application. With
such efforts, the rules and personnel organizing
and constraining the competition become objects
of the competition turf.
41
43Competitive/Adversarial Systems
- can lose much of their effectiveness when such
efforts to corrupt are lucrative resources
invested in corruption are lost to the system
and, insofar as such efforts succeed, they
diminish the degree to which the functioning of
the system tracks its social purpose.
42
44Competitive/Adversarial Systems
- can include rules forbidding and penalizing
efforts to modify the rules or their application.
But these protective rules and their application
are themselves vulnerable to modification
efforts. Example soccer hidden and pretended
fouls.
43
45Competitive/Adversarial Systems
- can, so long as countervailing temptations are
not too strong, help stabilize their own proper
framing by only by? sustaining a moral
attitude toward certain rules and penalties
(which then become punishments). To be effective,
this moral attitude must be ingrained in the
culture and internalized by many of the players
and esp. by most of those who play a role in
formulating or applying central system rules.
44
46Such Moralization has Limited Potential
- The moral character of certain rules and
penalties is a matter of degree (how many
disapprove, and how severely?), and is itself
vulnerable to corruption as players have
self-interested incentives to seek demoralization
or moralization of some prescriptions. The
success of such efforts depends on how morality
is understood and lived in the wider culture.
45
47Long-term Tendency
- Money is becoming the pre-eminent universal
reward, penetrating also the academic world
(through grants, endowments), media
(advertising), politics and international
negotiations (campaign contributions), public
administration (revolving door), and religion.
The judicial system is the best hold-out but
dependent for its rules on legislatures.
46
48Systemic Problem Regulatory Capture with
Inequality Spiral
- Often in concert, the richest players influence
the rules and their application, thereby
expanding their own advantage. Such run-away
inequality strengthens, in each round, both the
incentives and the opportunities for influence.
Public facilities come under the influence of
players with special and often near-term
interests, who buy support from media and
academics for this purpose (venality esp. of
economists who live up to their homo oeconomicus
paradigm). Special interests have been especially
effective in influencing international agreements
(WTO Treaty) and organizations (WIPO, World Bank).
47
49- Digression Financial Crisis
50Systemic Problem Instability
- Insofar as system rules and their application
are privately purchased, the externalities for
other players and the future are disregarded.
Moreover, there is growing incoherence of the
whole scheme of rules because its various
components are shaped by different sets of
players with diverse special interests. Both
phenomena exemplify the structure of collective
action problems (PD) The strongest players are
impelled, by their self-regarding interests, to
seek influence in ways that are detrimental and
dangerous even to themselves collectively (and
even more so, of course, to weaker players). Even
the strongest are worse off in the long run than
they would be if they abandoned their competitive
efforts to manipulate in their own favor the
rules and their application (but how can they?).
49
51Hypothesis
- Even the rich mighty, if only they think a
little more long-term, have an interest in the
reduction of economic inequality, esp. at the top
end. In the long run, they must expect more
damage from the mani-pulation efforts of other
strong players than gain from their own such
efforts.
525
- Responsibility and Solutions
53Three Claims
- Today, most premature human deaths and other
deprivations are causally traceable (but for)
injustice in existing supranational institutional
arrangements - for which we (citizens of the more powerful
countries) are co-responsible - in violation of human-rights-correlative negative
duties of justice.
52
54Counter-Argument
- Poverty is evolving differently in the various
developing countries and regions. This shows that
local (e.g., national) factors account for the
persistence of severe poverty where it persist.
53
55Conceptual Answer to the Counter-Argument
- It merely shows that local factors are
co-responsible for the persistence of severe
poverty. It does not show that local factors are
solely responsible. Example Differential
learning success of students/pupils in the same
class.
54
5655
57Empirical Answer to the Counter-Argument
- Protectionism against the poor
- Pharmaceuticals at monopoly prices
- Privileges Borrowing, Resources, Treaties, Arms
conferred on the basis of effective power alone
entrenchment and perverse incentives - Dirty Money outflows from developing countries of
US850-1000 billion annually - www.ffdngo.org/documentrepository/GFI20Report.pdf
58- Global Institutional Order
4 Privileges
Dirty Money
Protectionism Pharmaceuticals
57