PowerPoint Template

About This Presentation
Title:

PowerPoint Template

Description:

Title: PowerPoint Template Author: PoweredTemplates.com Last modified by: Anca Created Date: 6/13/2006 1:38:55 PM Document presentation format: On-screen Show – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:2
Avg rating:3.0/5.0

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: PowerPoint Template


1
Another Piece In The Feldstein - Horioka Puzzle
Sabie Anca mihaela
2
Introduction
  • In the literature of open-economy macroeconomics,
    defining and measuring capital mobility has been
    one of the most important issues. The traditional
    approach to testing the capital mobility
    hypothesis was proposed by the seminal paper of
    Feldstein and Horioka (1980). The idea behind
    their thesis is quite simple if an economy is
    well internationally integrated, then, its
    accumulation of capital should not be constrained
    by national savings. The equation which
    summarizes their work is the following
  • Feldstein and Horioka studied the relationship
    between saving and investment rates by using
    cross-section data for 16 OECD countries over the
    1960-1974 period and concluded that 85 to 95 of
    the national saving was invested locally. The
    high correlation was interpreted as capital being
    immobile even among developed countries. This
    came to be known as the FeldsteinHorioka
    puzzle
  • Their conclusion has sparked a huge literature on
    trying to explain this puzzle and to reconcile it
    with the overwhelming evidence of high capital
    mobility.

3
Literature Review
  • The Feldstein-Horioka result of a high
    saving-investment association has remained
    remarkably robust in OECD cross-sections although
    the coefficient on saving has shown some tendency
    to decline over recent years. The result persists
    in panels and time-series and has been remarkably
    robust to the addition of other variables and
    different estimation methods in the OECD.
  • However, there is less evidence for a close
    relationship between saving and investment in
    non-OECD samples, particularly in less developed
    countries. Overall, the studies indicate that the
    degree of capital mobility is higher for
    developing economies.
  • As stressed by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2002),
    even in a fully integrated economy - an economy
    in which investment decisions do not depend on
    domestic saving - some shocks will move saving
    and investment in the same direction, generating
    a positive correlation between the two. If these
    shocks dominate, the correlation will be high.
  • The Feldstein-Horioka result may not be
    informative about capital mobility since a range
    of theoretical models can generate high
    saving-investment correlations even under perfect
    capital mobility (Coakley et al., (1998)).

4
Aims of the Paper
  • To investigate the existence of the
    saving-investment correlation in a group of
    developed economies, respectively 22 OECD
    countries and a group of developing economies, 10
    Central and Eastern Europe countries
  • To determine its evolution over time
  • To investigate whether controlling for global
    shocks (either homogenously or heterogeneously
    transmitted across countries) could provide an
    explanation for the puzzle.

5
The Model
  • In line with the work of Giannone and Lenza
    (2004), the following representation of saving
    and investment rates will be considered

6
The Model
  • Following Feldstein and Horioka, the linear
    relationship between the idiosyncratic components
    represents the degree of capital mobility

where ß is the saving-retention coefficient
conditional to idiosyncratic shocks or, in terms
of long run fluctuations,
7
The Model
  • Equations (3) and (4) could be rewritten in terms
    of observable saving and investment rates as

(5)
(6)
8
The Model
  • Methodologies commonly used in the
    Feldstein-Horioka debate
  • Original long-run regression or the between
    model
  • Panel regression with country fixed effects
  • Panel regression with country fixed and common
    time effects, which assumes homogeneity in the
    transmission of global shocks

(7)
(8)
(9)
9
The Data
  • The research focused on 2 groups of countries
  • 22 OECD countries Australia, Austria, Belgium,
    Canada, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Finland, France,
    United Kingdom, Greece, Ireland, Iceland, Italy,
    Japan, Korea, Netherlands, Norway, New Zealand,
    Portugal, Sweden and United States.
  • 10 CEE countries Bulgaria, Czech Republic,
    Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Poland,
    Romania, Slovakia and Slovenia.
  • Data frequency is annual and the sample ranges
    from 1970 to 2007 for the first panel, and from
    1993 to 2008 for the second
  • Investment is Gross Capital Formation. Saving is
    the sum of Consumption of Fixed Capital and Net
    Saving. Saving and investment rates are
    calculated as the ratio of Saving and Investment
    to GDP.
  • Data sources OECD
  • AMECO

10
OECD - The Between Model
Using Feldstein and Horiokas original
regression, the puzzle is further documented.
Although the correlation has obviously decreased
over time, all 3 saving-retention coefficients
are high and significantly different from zero.
Therefore, even in the last two decades, the
capital appears to be far from mobile among these
OECD countries.
11
Panel Regression with Cross-Country Fixed Effects
Again, the results do not suggest that the
puzzle has disappeared, decreasing only slightly
when compared to the between model estimators.
For the last subsample though, there appears to
be evidence of increased capital mobility,
although the coefficient is still statistically
different from zero. The tests reject the null
hypotesis that the fixed effects coefficients are
the same across countries. This suggests that
there is unobserved heterogeneity in the data and
one should use a model with fixed effects.
12
Panel Regression with Country and Period Fixed
Effects
This method relies on the quite strong
assumption that the responses to the common
factors are identical across individuals in the
panel. The results suggest that, even when
controlling for global comovements by assuming
homogeneity of their transmission mechanisms
across countries, the saving retention
coefficient is significantly reduced, even if it
still remains statistically different from zero
in all 3 samples. The redundant fixed effects
tests suggest that all the corresponding effects
are statistically significant.

13
The Factor Model
  • In order to estimate equation (5) the global
    factors will be extracted directly from saving
    and investment rates by cross country aggregation
    (since the idiosyncratic components are driven by
    country or region specific shocks, by worldwide
    aggregation they are ruled out). As shown by
    Forni, Hallin, Lippi and Reichlin (2002), the
    unobserved factors can be estimated provided that
    the number of countries under analysis is large,
    and they are estimated by means of the first r
    principal components.
  • The criteria used for choosing the number of
    factors is the one proposed by Forni and Reichlin
    (1998), who suggest retaining only the principal
    components that explain more than a certain
    threshold percentage of the panel variance
    following their example, the threshold is set at
    10.

(10)
14
Principal Component Analysis
  • The first principal component explains about
    54 and the second principal component about 15
    of the variance of domestic saving and investment
    rates. Therefore, the first two principal
    components will be retained as they capture,
    overall, about 69 of the panel variance. The
    hypothesis of strong cross-country linkages
    between saving and investment rates of OECD
    countries is confirmed.

15
Factor Augmented Panel Regression
The following factor augmented panel regression
is estimated
The results show that, once taken into account
the heterogeneity of the transmission mechanism
of global shocks, the Feldstein-Horioka
coefficient only slightly decreases when
estimated for the whole sample period or for the
first subsample, but is considerably reduced,
becoming insignificantly different from zero, for
the last two decades. This suggests that assuming
an homogenous transmission mechanism has biased
upwards the estimated coefficient.
16
Factor Augmented Panel Regression
Indeed, the homogeneity restriction is strongly
rejected by the data, as the Wald tests confirm.
Also, the high number of significant coefficients
on the second principal component provides
further evidence that the first factor was not
able, alone, to account for the effects of global
shocks on saving and investment rates in OECD
countries.
Significant at 5 level, Significant at 10
level
17
Factor Augmented Panel Regression
  • In addition, by looking at the percentage of
    the variance of domestic saving and investment
    rates explained by global factors, it is obvious
    how their impact varies considerably across
    countries.

18
Economic Interpretation of the Principal
Components
In order to find an economic interpretation for
the principal components, we try to assess their
relation with some economic aggregates. The first
principal component is found to be very similar
to global OECD investment rate, with a
correlation coefficient of 0.86.
In what concerns the second principal component,
one should search for an aggregate driven by
global shocks but not collinear with the global
OECD investment rate. Therefore, we try to assess
its correlation with two proxies of the world
interest rate, G7 long run interest rate and US
long run interest rate, which are found to be
0.78, and 0.71, respectively.
19
Synthesis of the Results
Type of regression   Sample     Sample     Sample  
Type of regression 1970-2007 1970-1989 1990-2007
Between model (Long Run Regression) 0.59 0.68 0.41
Between model (Long Run Regression) 0.11 0.11 0.12
Panel Regression with cross-section fixed effects 0.50 0.52 0.28
Panel Regression with cross-section fixed effects 0.03 0.03 0.03
Panel Regression with cross-section and period fixed effects 0.32 0.40 0.23
Panel Regression with cross-section and period fixed effects 0.02 0.03 0.05
Factor Augmented Panel Regression 0.27 0.28 -0.03
Factor Augmented Panel Regression 0.03 0.05 0.05
20
Other Methods for Estimating Idiosyncratic
Equations
  • Since the factors didnt explain much of the
    correlation on the sample 1970-2007, the
    idiosyncratic relation was re-estimated using
    other two methods developed for filtering out
    unobservable common factors in the panel
    regression the common correlated effects (CCE)
    estimator of Pesaran (2006) and the projected
    principal components (PPC) estimator of
    Greenaway-McGrevy, Han and Sul (2007).
  • Pesaran (2006) suggests filtering out common
    factors by including the cross-sectional averages
    of the regressand and regressors in the panel
    regression. His common correlated effects (CCE)
    estimator of ß can be obtained by least squares
    estimation of the following regression
  • where
    and are used as proxies for the
    common factors to and .

21
Other Methods for Estimating Idiosyncratic
Equations
  • The PPC estimator proposed by Greenaway-McGrevy,
    Han and Sul (2007) consists of
  • estimation of the factor number using a modified
    Bai and Ng (2002) selection criteria
  • For the panel the number of common
    factors h can be estimated consistently by
    minimizing the information criterion.
  • Han et. al. suggest using
    instead
    of zit to account for possible serial correlation
    in the idiosyncratic error.
  • estimation of the common factors for each
    variable using the principal component method
  • partialling out all common factors from each
    cross-sectional unit for each variable
  • estimating the idiosyncratic equation

22
Results
In terms of point estimates, the coefficient is
somewhat lower in the PPC case but overall, the
results sustain the existence of a weakened, but
significant correlation between saving and
investment ratios for the whole time period.
Estimation 1970-2007
Factor Augmented Panel Regression 0.27
Factor Augmented Panel Regression 0.03
Common Correlated Effects 0.28
Common Correlated Effects 0.11
Projected Principal Component 0.23
Projected Principal Component 0.09
23
Models Estimation for CEE Countries
  • The majority of the studies focusing on
    non-OECD samples show that there is less evidence
    for a close relationship between saving and
    investment in these economies, the savings
    coefficients for developing economies being
    generally smaller than those found for
    industrialized economies.
  • The between estimator though suggests that
    there is less than perfect capital mobility in
    the CEE countries

Again, using Feldstein and Horiokas original
regression, there appears to be a high
correlation between saving and investment rates
even among this group of developing countries.
24
Panel Regression with Cross-Country Fixed Effects
The saving retention coefficient remains
significant and comparable with the one estimated
for the OECD countries for the last subsample,
indicating that the CEE countries are neither
perfectly integrated into nor perfectly separated
from the world capital market, according to the
Feldstein-Horioka criterion. The result is also
comparable to the one obtained by Kohler (2005),
who finds a point estimate of 0.32 using a panel
regression with cross-country fixed effects.
The redundant fixed effects tests strongly
reject the null hypotesis that the fixed effects
coefficients are the same across countries.
25
Panel Regression with Country and Period Fixed
Effects
The Feldstein-Horioka coefficient becomes
insignificantly different from zero when common
time effects are assumed. The result may in fact
suggest that the shocks are homogenously
transmitted across the region, yielding similar
effects on the countries in the panel. This
may be the sign that Eastern European countries
financial markets are quite open and countries
are able to invest without having to comply with
the strict constraint of domestic saving.
The redundant fixed effects tests suggest that
all the corresponding effects are statistically
significant.
26
Conclusions
  • Overall, the results show that, irrespective of
    the method employed to test for the existence of
    the puzzle, the saving-investment correlation has
    decreased over time, therefore providing evidence
    of increased capital mobility in the recent
    years.
  • When allowing for heterogeneous responses of
    saving and investment rates to global shocks
    across OECD countries, the correlation between
    saving and investment decreases and becomes
    insignificantly different from zero in the last
    two decades. Imposing the homogeneity restriction
    (which is rejected by the data), biases upwards
    the estimated correlation.
  • The results from the CEE countries suggest that
    the shocks propagate homogenously across
    countries, and again, once controlling for these
    shocks, the saving-investment correlation is
    insignificant. Although future research using
    longer time series would have to further check
    these results, they yet suggest that these states
    are integrated into the international capital
    markets to a degree similar to other OECD
    countries. Problematic is that the panel approach
    only measures the degree of capital mobility for
    a group of countries and not for each country
    separately. Therefore, the degree of capital
    mobility might have been biased by a small number
    of highly integrated countries.
  • These findings are consistent with the empirical
    evidence that international capital mobility has
    increased in the last two decades, and that the
    Feldstein-Horioka puzzle seems to be
    de-emphasized.

27
References
  • Adedeji, O. and Thornton, J. (2007),
    International capital mobility Evidence from
    panel cointegration tests, Economics Letters,
    99, 349352
  • Apergis, N. and Tsoumas, C. (2009), A survey on
    the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle what has been done
    and where we stand, Research in Economics,
    Forthcoming. Also available at SSRNhttp//ssrn.co
    m/abstract993736
  • Artis, M. and Bayoumi, T. (1991), Global
    Financial Integration and Current Account
    Imbalances, in G. Alogoskoufis, L. Papademos and
    R. Portes (Eds.) External Constraints on
    Macroeconomic Policy The European Experience,
    Cambridge Cambridge University Press
  • Bai, J. (2003), Inferential Theory for Factor
    Models of Large Dimensions Econometrica, 71,
    135171
  • Bai, J. (2004), Estimating cross-section common
    stochastic trend in nonstationary panels,
    Journal of Econometrics, 122, 137183
  • Bai, J., and S. Ng (2002), Determining the
    Number of Factors in Approximate Factor Models,
    Econometrica, 70, 191221
  • Bai, J., and S. Ng (2006), Confidence intervals
    for diffusion index forecasts with a large number
    of predictors, Econometrica, 74, 11331150
  • Barro, R. (1991), World interest rate and
    investment, NBER Working Paper 3849
  • Bayoumi, T. (1990), Savings-Investment
    Correlations Immobile Capital, Government Policy
    or Endogenous Behavior?, IMF Staff Papers, 27,
    360-387
  • Blanchard, O., and F. Giavazzi (2002) Current
    account deficits in the Euro Area the end of the
    Feldstein-Horioka puzzle?, Brookings Papers on
    Economic Activity, 22, 147209
  • Buch, Claudia M. (1999), Capital Mobility and EU
    Enlargement, Kiel Working Paper No. 908
  • Coakley, J., Fuertes, A. M. and Spagnolo, F.
    (2004) Is the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle
    history?, The Manchester School, 72, 569-590.
  • Coakley, J., Fuertes, A. M. and Spagnolo, F.
    (2002) The Feldstein-Horioka puzzle is not as
    bad as you think, available at
    http//repec.org/mmfc03/Coakley.pdf.
  • Coakley, J., F. Hasan and R. Smith (1999)
    Saving, Investment and Capital Mobility in
    LDCs, Review of International Economics, 7,
    632-640.
  • Coakley, J., F. Kulasi, and R. Smith (1998) The
    Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle and Capital Mobility A
    Review, International Journal of Finance and
    Economics, 3(2), 16988
  • Coakley, J., F. Kulasi, and R. Smith (1996)
    Current Account Solvency and the
    Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle, Economic Journal, 106,
    620-627.
  • Feldstein, M., and C. Horioka (1980), Domestic
    saving and international capital flows, Economic
    Journal, 90, 314329
  • Forni, M., M. Hallin, M. Lippi, and L. Reichlin
    (2000), The Generalized Dynamic Factor Model
    identification and estimation, Review of
    Economics and Statistics, 82, 540554
  • Forni, M., and L. Reichlin (1998), Lets get
    real a factor analytic approach to business
    cycle dynamics, Review of Economic Studies, 65,
    452473

28
References
  • Glick, R., and K. Rogoff (1995), Global versus
    country-specific productivity shocks and the
    current account, Journal of Monetary Economics,
    35, 159192
  • Greenaway-McGrevy, R., C. Han, and D. Sul (2007),
    Estimating and Testing Idiosyncratic Equations
    Using Cross-Section Dependent Panel Data
    Application to Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle,
    forthcoming, also available at
    http//homes.eco.auckland.ac.nz/dsul013/working/wo
    rking1.htm
  • Katsimi, M. and T. Moutos (2007), Human capital
    and the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle, CESifo
    Working Paper Series No. 1914
  • Hogendorn C. (1998), Capital Mobility in
    Historical Perspective, Journal of Policy
    Modeling, 20(2), 141-161
  • Köhler, M. (2005), International capital
    mobility and current account targeting in Central
    and Eastern European countries, CEER, Discussion
    Paper No. 05-51
  • Levy, D. (1995), Investment-Savings Co-movement
    under Endogenous Fiscal Policy, Open Economies
    Review, 6, 237-254
  • Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff (2000a), The six
    major puzzle in international economics is there
    a common cause?, NBER Working Paper 7777
  • Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff (2000b),
    Perspectives on OECD economic integration.
    Global economic integration Opportunities and
    challenges, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
    Annual Monetary Symposium
  • Obstfeld, M. (1998), The Global Capital Market
    Benefactor or Menace?, NBER Working Papers, 6559
  • Obstfeld, M. and K. Rogoff (1995), The
    Intertemporal Approach to the Current Account,
    in G. M. Grossman and K. Rogoff (Eds.) Handbook
    of International Economics, New York
    North-Holland Publishing Co
  • Payne, J. and R. Kumazawa (2006), Capital
    Mobility and the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle
    Re-Examination of Less Developed Countries, The
    Manchester School, 74, 610-616
  • Pesaran, M. H. (2006), Estimation and Inference
    in Large Heterogeneous Panels with a Multifactor
    Error Structure, Econometrica, 74(4), 9671012
  • Rossini, G., and P. Zanghieri (2002) A Simple
    Test of the Role of Foreign Direct Investment in
    the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle, Applied Economics
    Letters, 10, 39-41.
  • Sachsida, A. and M. Caetano (2000), The
    Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle Revisited, Economics
    Letters, 68, 85-88
  • Sinha, T., and D. Sinha (2004), The Mother of
    All Puzzles Would Not Go Away, Economics
    Letters, 82, 259-267
  • Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (2002),
    Macroeconomic Forecasting Using Diffusion
    Indexes, Journal of Business and Economics
    Statistics, 20, 147162
  • Telatar, E., F. Telatar and N. Bolatoglu (2007),
    A Regime Switching Approach to the
    Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle Evidence from Some
    European Countries, Journal of Policy Modeling,
    12, 523-533
  • Tesar, L. (1991), Saving, Investment and
    International Capital Flows, Journal of
    International Economics, 31, 55-78
  • Vamvakidis, A., and R. Wacziarg (1998),
    Developing Countries and the Feldstein-Horioka
    Puzzle, IMF Working Paper No. 98/2
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)