Title: International Trade and Development
1International Trade and Development
2International Trade and Development
- Lecture Outline
- (1) What do we include in a Growth model?
- (2) Evidence of the relationship between
increased trade (globalisation) and growth
relate to evidence of poverty/inequality and
development. -
3International Trade and Development
- (1) What do we include in a Growth model?
- Based on the work of Levine and Renelt (1992,
AER, 82(4)). - Prior to this paper, empirical papers were not
controlling for appropriate factors. - Levine and Renelt found that many explanatory
variables were not robust to changes to the
inclusion/exclusion of other variables some
even changed sign!!!
4International Trade and Development
- (1) What do we include in a Growth model?
- Following a survey of empirical work LR decide
upon 4 explanatory variables, -
- where INVinvestment share of GDP
is initial level of GDP per capita in 1960 (when
data begins from) SEC is the initial
secondary-school enrollment rate GPOP is the
average annual growth rate of the population
growth.
5International Trade and Development
- (1) What do we include in a Growth model?
- (Q) Why these variables?
- Expect higher initial GDP level in 1960 to have
a negative effect on real GDP/capita growth
testing the hypothesis that a poor country,
ceteris paribus, tends to grow faster than a rich
country. -
-
Growth of initially high GDP country
GDP
Growth of initially low GDP country
Year
6International Trade and Development
- (1) What do we include in a Growth model?
- Expect higher initial level of human capital to
positively effect real GDP/capita growth
consistent with Solow growth model and more
importantly the endogenous growth models. - Increase in INV/GDP expected to positively
effect real GDP/capita growth tests the Solow
model and any other economic growth model.
Investment is a key driver of growth. - Those countries with high rates of population
growth have lower growth rates finding is not
robust to all models.
7International Trade and Development
- (2) The Empirical Debate Trade and Development
- We will discuss a number of papers on, the
relationship between trade and GDP, on the effect
of trade openness on GDP and finally the effect
of trade on poverty and inequality. - Look at Greenaway et al (2002), Irwin and Tervio
(2000) and Dollar and Kraay (2004). - First 2 papers focus on the impact of
international trade on growth/income of countries
using samples of countries over a number of
years. - Dollar and Kraay (2004) focuses on link between
trade and poverty/income inequality.
8International Trade and Development
- The key concern though when estimating the link
between trade and growth is the issue of
endogeneity which prevents a correct estimate of
the impact trade has on growth I.E. - THE POSITIVE CORRELATION BETWEEN TRADE AND
INCOME COULD MEAN THAT COUNTRIES WITH HIGHER
INCOMES ENGAGE IN MORE TRADE RATHER THAN
COUNTRIES WITH MORE TRADE HAVING MORE INCOME
(Taken from Irwin and Tervio, 2000).
9International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001)
- Focus on the issue of trade liberalisation and
its impact on GDP growth so not looking at
impact of trade liberalisation on poverty or
income distribution or development. -
- Reason for the paper is the inconclusive
evidence from previous work argue that reason
for debate is (i) inappropriate methodology and
(ii) how trade liberalisation is measured. - Previous research can be criticised for not
using panel techniques that control for (i)
country-specific effects, (ii) time-effects and
(iii) an unobserved error effect that varies
across both countries and years (time) which is
assumed to be uncorrelated.
10International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- The Core growth model is based on the empirical
work of Levine and Renalt (1992) and theoretical
developments by Romer (1990). - Robust variables included in most core growth
models are - (i) investment, (ii) population growth, (iii)
initial human capital, (iv) initial GDP per
capita. - Greenaway et al also add to this list of
explanatory variables, (v) terms of trade
variable and (vi) trade liberalisation proxies.
11International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- The base specification is,
12International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- Problem with this specification is that it is
inappropriate if looking for dynamic effects.
Include lagged changes in real GDP/capita growth
as well. - Expect an improvement in terms of trade to
positively effect real GDP/capita growth. - Importantly for the paper, is testing the
hypothesis of whether trade liberalisation
effects real GDP/capita growth in any way. If
effect ve then supports the pro-trade
liberalisation group.
13International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- Issue of how to proxy trade liberalisation, with
the suspicion that different proxies can have
different effects. - (1) Use a before and after Structural Adjustment
Loan (SAL) variable (simple binary variable) as
this loan at least signal intent of trade
liberalisation. - (2) Timing of liberalisation is measured using
actual information on levels and changes in
tariffs, quotas, exchange rate misalignment and
export impediments/promoters. Through this can
identify the year when liberalisation has taken
place. Is modelled by a binary variable as is
the SAL based on Dean et al (1994).
14International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- (3) A measure of closed-ness and openness in
trade in terms of average tariff level. If
average tarifflt39 then open, if above 39 then
closed. Very arbitrary but even Sachs and Warner
(1995) who come up with the measurement recognise
this Does just give another measure of
openness/close-ness though. - Results.
15International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) contUsing Sachs and
Warner
16International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) contusing Dean et al
17International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) contUsing SAL
18International Trade and Development
- Greenaway et al (2001) cont
- Finding is that when the simple dummy trade
liberalisation terms are included that in
post-liberalisation period growth in real
GDP/capita is greater than in the
pre-liberalisation period. - Implication is that trade liberalisation (all 3
definitions used) is a good thing for growth but
the effect is not that great. - However, the simple dummy variable approach
represents an average effect over a number of
years. By switching on the liberalisation proxy
for the year liberalisation is introduced only
and then turning it off again we get a direct
growth impact estimate in the first year only,
with lags picking up the impact of reforms in
subsequent years. -
- There are however indications of first and
second order serial correlation!!!
19International Trade and Development
- The second-order serial correlation indicates a
mis-specified model. - Standard way to get around this issue is to
include instruments in the model which here takes
the form of lagged changes in real GDP/capita
from Columns 3 in the above tables we see 2nd
order serial correlation is resolved not
significant - This is an example of the instrumental variables
(IV) approach -
- Column 3 represents the best model in the paper.
The signs on the explanatory variables are all
expected and most remain significant. - There is an element of sensitivity regarding
which trade liberalisation measure is used as to
its impact on growth in real GDP/capita. - However, the evidence does give a more
consistent picture that trade liberalisation has
a positive impact on growth which may take time
to work through (the lagged trade liberalisation
terms) into a growth impact.
20International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002)
- Flag the endogeneity issue of trade and GDP and
the use of an instrument that is expected to
effect trade but not GDP. - The instrument is relatively new to the
literature and was first used by Frankel and
Romer (1999). - They construct an instrument that takes into
account the geographical location of a country
and in particular the countrys distance from
trading partners.
21International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002) cont
-
- They go through the process of constructing the
instrument itself by OLS regression. - Actual trade of country i with country j as
a share of GDP of country i is regressed onto a
number of factors that includes distance between
country i and country j. - This regression will give predicted values for
each country i trade with country j/GDP
ratio. - Explanatory factors include populations of the
countries, area of the two countries, whether
landlocked or not. -
22International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002)cont
- For each bilateral trade between country i and
country j can be calculated.
These are then summed to yield a predicted value
of country is trade share with all sample
countries j this is the instrument. - From this prediction we construct the instrument
necessary to solve the endogeneity problem in the
growth equation. - If the growth model uses (actual trade/GDP) then
the coefficient in the growth equation on this
term will be biased upwards. - Reasons are things like richer countries being
able to afford better infrastructure that means
more trade is physically possible (e.g. ports,
airports, road structure, railway structure). - Technically it means that there is a positive
correlation between the error term in the growth
equation and the trade term. - Need to use IV estimation to get over this issue
this is where the constructed instrument comes
into play!!
23International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002)cont
- Instead of the growth equation being estimated
through OLS, they use a two stage least squares
(2SLS) approach. - The T hat term represents the predicted trade of
country i, that is a function of geographical
distance between trading partners. - In the first stage of this model, trade/GDP is
regressed onto the instrument and a couple of
other variables, i.e. -
-
- The predicted values of trade from this first
stage are calculated for each observation,
represented by . This essentially
represents a constructed trade share which is
determined in large part by the bilateral trade
estimate.
24International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002)cont
- The final growth equation to be estimated is
represented by, -
- where the trade term is constructed from our
regressions and does NOT represent actual
trade/GDP weve determined what causes trade
using a variable that cannot theoretically effect
GDP. - Compare the coefficient on the trade term with
that for the coefficient in the OLS growth
estimation represented by, -
-
25International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002) regression used to
calculate the instrument -
26International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002) Growth models, OLS and
2SLS using IV
27International Trade and Development
- Irwin and Tervio (2002)cont
-
- Conclusions are that the effect of trade on
income/capita of a country is larger using 2SLS
than OLS (the coefficients on the trade variable
are larger) although frequently less
significant. - Conclusion is that trade does positively effect
growth even taking into account the endogeneity
issue. - Criticism of this type of model follows from
Rodrik and Rodriguez (2000) with the model NOT
robust to including distance from equator when
Irwin and Tervio include this variable in the GDP
equation the trade term becomes everywhere
insignificant with the coefficient frequently
negative! - (Q) Is there an economic explanation for why
latitude can be included in growth equations? -
28International Trade and Development
- Dollar and Kraay (2004) paper on Trade and
Development, Poverty and Inequality - Initially estimate a difference model based on
the standard growth equation -
- where LHS is log-level of per capita GDP in
country c at time t. Could use log-level GDP,
but then would clearly not be taking into account
population size. - is log-level of per capita GDP k years ago
(the lag of growth in previous period).
29International Trade and Development
- The matrix X is a set of control variables
measured in averages. Volume of trade
(exportsimports as a of GDP) is included in
X. - The 3 error terms are (i) an unobserved country
effect that does not change over time, (ii) an
unobserved error term that changes over time but
which is common to all countries (e.g. oil
prices), (iii) an unobserved error effect that
varies across both countries and years (time)
which is assumed to be uncorrelated.
30International Trade and Development
- Most studies do not concentrate on levels of GDP
but instead on changes in GDP over periods of
time. - This represents a regression of growth in GDP
onto lagged growth in GDP and on changes in the
set of explanatory variables in the X matrix and
is represented formally by, -
31International Trade and Development
- The differenced growth equation has a number of
desirable characteristics - (1) whilst levels of trade (volume of trade)
reflect more the geography of a country, changes
in trade volume reflect something else since the
geography of a country does not change. - (2) institutional characteristics of a country
also do not change considerably over time (e.g.
racial composition, historical legacy of
colonialism etc) - (3) The difference growth model allows
appropriate lags of the right hand side
variables as instruments (Dollar and Kraay,
2004, f38).
32International Trade and Development
- The identifying assumption is that while trade
volumes may be correlated with lagged shocks to
GDP growth, trade volumes are not correlated with
future shocks to GDP growth. - In practice, this means that when we regress
growth in the 1990s on(to) (i) growth in the
1980s and (ii) the change in trade volumes
(changes in trade as of GDP) between the 1980s
and 1990s, we can use the level of trade volumes
in the 1970s as an instrument for trade
openness, (Dollar and Kraay, 2004, f39),
brackets and italics added.
33International Trade and Development Table from
Dollar and Kraay (2004) Standard Errors in
Brackets
OLS IV IV IV
Initial Income 0.419 0.783 0.765 0.96
(0.071) (0.297) (0.367) (0.397)
Changes in Trade Volume 0.252 0.475 0.514 0.543
(0.095) (0.175) (0.187) (0.210)
Contract Intensive Money 0.232
-0.41
Government Consumption/GDP -1.164
(-1.009)
log(1Inflation Rate) -0.142
(-0.152)
Revolutions -0.025
(-0.084)
F-Statistic for First-Stage Regressions
Lagged Growth Openness 12.46 17.49 8.09 16.17 8.56 10.62
Observations 187 187 153 173
34International Trade and Development
- Interpretation of Table
- The point estimate on Trade volume in the OLS
reads that a 100 increase in trade share of GDP
would raise GDP in the country by 25 over a
decade. - When controlled for instruments on trade volume
(See the significant F-Statistics for Lagged
Growth and Openness), the size of the trade
volume coefficient increases to near 0.5!!! - Conclusion Greater involvement in trade is
related to faster growth in developing nations.
35International Trade and Development
- Cautionary Comment
- Researchers want to test whether lowering trade
barriers to international trade significantly
increases growth, once other factors have been
controlled for implications if evidence
supports this hypothesis is that governments
should dismantle their barriers to trade
(Rodrik and Rodriguez, 2000, pp. 3). - Remember Rodrik and Rodriguez (2000) argue that
applied pieces of work are using inappropriate
indicators of trade policy to systematically
bias quantitative results in favour of finding a
statistically significant relationship between
trade and growth. - Dollar and Kraay (2004) use change in the volume
of trade as a regressor in the change in growth
model and identify the model by assuming that
level of trade has no correlation with change in
GDP in the future. - However is this an appropriate identifier? Can
this assumption be made? - Remember, GDP and trade are clearly determined
by one another and there is question of finding a
variable(s) that determines change in trade but
not a change in GDP.
36International Trade and Development
37References
- Levine, R., and Renelt, D., (1992), A
Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth
Regressions The American Economic Review, Vol.
82, No. 4 (Sep., 1992), pp. 942-963 - Dollar, D., and Kraay, A., (2004), Trade,
Growth and Poverty, Economic Journal, Vol 114,
pp. f22-f49. - Frankel, J., and Romer, D., Does trade cause
growth?, American Economic Review, Vol 89, pp.
379-399. - Greenaway, D., Morgan, W., and Wright, P.,
(2002), Trade liberalisation and growth in
developing countries, Journal of Development
Economics, Vol 67, pp. 229-244. - Irwin, D.A., and Tervio, M., (2002), Does trade
raise income? Evidence from the twentieth
century, Journal of International Economics, Vol
58, pp. 1-18. -
- Rodriguez, F., and Rodrik, D., (2000), Trade
policy and economic growth a skeptics guide to
the cross-national evidence, Working Paper
(available upon request). -
- Winters, A., (2004), Trade liberalization and
economic performance An overview, Economic
Journal, 114 F4-F21. - See Dani Rodriks website at http//ksghome.harva
rd.edu/drodrik/