SIO 295 Common property resources

1 / 20
About This Presentation
Title:

SIO 295 Common property resources

Description:

E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons (Cambridge University Press, 1990) ... The fishers agree to hire someone to ensure that no one cheats ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:1692
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 21
Provided by: jeffreyrob
Learn more at: http://cmbc.ucsd.edu

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: SIO 295 Common property resources


1
SIO 295Common property resources
2
Readings
  • E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons (Cambridge
    University Press, 1990)
  • E. Ostrom, Reformulating the commons, in
    Protecting the Commons, ed. J. Burger et al.
    (Island Press, 2001)
  • J.M. Baland J.P. Platteau, Halting Degradation
    of Natural Resources (Clarendon Press, 1996)
  • J.M. Baland and J.P. Platteau, Economics of
    common property management regimes, in Handbook
    of Environmental Economics, Vol. 1, ed. K.G.
    Mäler and J.R. Vincent (North-Holland, 2003)

3
Collective action
  • Fishers have an incentive to craft an agreement
    with the following key features
  • All fishers agree to limit their effort so that
    the collective effort does not exceed EMEY
  • The fishers agree to hire someone to ensure that
    no one cheats
  • All fishers receive a share of the rent that
    remains after paying costs of policing
  • Why doesnt this self-organization happen?

4
CPRs
  • Actually, it does happen many examples of common
    property resources (CPRs) in developing
    countries, and not just for fisheries
  • Long studied by anthropologists, largely ignored
    by economists until 1990s
  • Tragedy of the Commons model predicts rent
    dissipation in part because it didnt allow
    cooperation or repeated interaction among fishers
  • Prisoners dilemma

5
Example of fishery CPR beach seining in s. Sri
Lanka
  • Rules
  • Village fishing collective controls stretch of
    beach
  • Villagers are allowed to fish only if own a share
    of a net (transferred only through inheritance)
  • Nets require 8 fishermen to operate and are owned
    jointly
  • Ownership carries obligation to work when
    required
  • Each owner/operator receives 1/8th share of catch
  • Rotation system provides equal access to
    different zones of beach

6
Literature on CPRs, per BP
  • A striking feature of most of these studies lies
    in the fact that their authors are generally
    convinced that, given the glaring failure of
    state ownership experiences in developing
    countries, collective, community-based regulation
    holds out the best prospects for efficient
    management of village-level natural resources.
  • Yet, since they recognize at the same time that
    the balance sheet of actual experiences of common
    property management is mixed, the central aim of
    their inquiries is typically to understand the
    reasons that can account for these varying levels
    of performance .

7
  • CPRs dont always evolve
  • Attributes of users (appropriators)
  • Attributes of the resource
  • CPRs dont always endure
  • Example Meg McKeans analysis of common lands in
    Japan (see Ostrom, Governing the Commons)
  • 12 million ha of forests and uncultivated
    mountain meadows during 17th-19th centuries
  • 3 million ha today
  • CPRs are not altruistic utopias
  • Rather, like hard-nosed condominium associations

8
Conditions under which CPRsare likely to evolve
  • Attributes of the resource
  • Spatial extent sufficiently small that users can
    develop accurate knowledge of characteristics
  • Indicators information on condition is regularly
    available and not too costly
  • Predictability flow of goods is relatively
    predictable
  • Feasible improvement not too underutilized or
    too overutilized

9
  • Attributes of the users
  • Salience significantly dependent on resource
  • Low discount rate value future benefits at
    non-negligible level
  • Common understanding of resource attributes
  • Autonomy user group can set access and
    harvesting rules without being countermanded by
    external authority
  • Prior organizational experience and local
    leadership have participated in other local
    associations or learned how other groups have
    organized
  • Trust and reciprocity expect promises will be
    kept

10
Attributes of long-enduring CPRS
  • Minimal recognition of rights to organize
  • Ownership of the uncultivated lands near a
    village devolved from the imperial court to the
    villages through several intermediate stages
    involving land stewards and locally based
    warriors.
  • Counter-example Nepal (Michael Wallace,
    Managing resources that are common property,
    JPAM, 1983)Until 1957, when the forests were
    nationalized, villagers controlled the use of the
    forests in their localities. villagers reacted
    negatively to nationalization, believing that
    their traditional rights of access and use had
    been curtailed. As a result, local
    responsibility for forest protection disappeared.
    Whereas previously there had been communal
    responsibility for managing the forest, after
    nationalization no one took responsibility for
    managing this resource.

11
  • Clearly defined boundaries
  • Resource National cadastral surveys were
    conducted late in the 16th century at a time of
    land reform . As villages asserted their own
    rights to these lands, they shared a clear image
    of which lands were private and which were held
    in common.
  • Users Each village contained a carefully
    recorded, defined number of households. Rights
    were variously based on cultivation rights in
    land, taxpaying obligations, or ownership rights
    in land. In some villages, almost all households
    had rights to the use of the commons. In
    others, such rights were more narrowly held.

12
  • Congruence
  • Appropriation rules and resource conditions A
    village headman usually was responsible for
    determining the date when the harvesting of a
    given product could begin. For abundant plants,
    the date would be selected simply to ensure that
    plants had matured and had propagated themselves.
    No limit was placed on the amount to be
    gathered. For scarce products, various
    harvesting rules were used.
  • Distribution of benefits of appropriation and
    costs of rules There were written rules about
    the obligation of each household to contribute a
    share to the collective work to maintain the
    commons. Accounts were kept about who
    contributed what to make sure that no household
    evaded its responsibilities unnoticed.

13
  • Collective-choice arrangements
  • Individuals affected by rules can participate in
    modifying them Each village was governed by
    an assembly, usually composed of the heads of all
    the households that had been assigned
    decision-making authority in the village.
    village assemblies created detailed authority
    rules specifying in various ways how much of each
    valued product a household could harvest from the
    commons and under what conditions.

14
  • Monitoring
  • Given that the mountain usually was closed,
    except for specific periods, anyone caught in the
    community-owned territories at other times
    obviously was not following the rules. Most of
    the villages hired detectives who daily
    patrolled the commons on horseback in groups of
    two looking for unauthorized users.

15
  • Graduated sanctions
  • An occasional infraction would be handled by the
    detective in a quiet and simple manner. It was
    considered perfectly appropriate for the
    detective to demand cash and saké from violators
    .
  • The most serious sanctions that could be and
    occasionally were imposed involved complete
    ostracism or ultimately banishment from the
    village.

16
  • Conflict-resolution mechanisms
  • Genuine disagreement about management decisions
    of village headman could occur
  • Mechanisms can exist within village or by appeal
    to external authority

17
Rousseaus noble savages?
  • BP The anthropological literature provides us
    with interesting examples of hunting and fishing
    societies where the agents of ecological
    destruction have a poor understanding of their
    role in this process.

18
  • Ponams (PNG) opposed a government plan aimed at
    the conservation of fish and other marine
    resources because they refused to ascribe
    declining fish catches to a decrease in fish
    population (Carrier 1987)

19
  • Cree (James Bay) acc. Berkes (1987), Cree
    practices violate nearly every conservation-orient
    ed, indirect-effort control measure in the
    repertory of contemporary scientific fisheries
    management. hunters are passive. Any
    management system claiming to maximize
    productivity by manipulating the animals is
    considered arrogant.

20
  • Senegal They do not seriously consider the
    possibility of their being partly responsible for
    overfishing therefore, the idea that they could
    combat environmental degradation by restricting
    their own fishing effort seems alien to most of
    them. The tendency to blame the other for
    stock depletion is typical of almost all
    artisanal fishing communities . (Gaspart and
    Platteau 2001)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)